A model for competitive markets

Similar documents
Study Unit 3 : Linear algebra

Solving Linear and Rational Inequalities Algebraically. Definition 22.1 Two inequalities are equivalent if they have the same solution set.

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation

Fundamentals of Operations Research. Prof. G. Srinivasan. Indian Institute of Technology Madras. Lecture No. # 15

II. Analysis of Linear Programming Solutions

EconS Vertical Integration

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

Solving Polynomial and Rational Inequalities Algebraically. Approximating Solutions to Inequalities Graphically

2. Find the intervals where function is increasing and decreasing. Then find all relative extrema.

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Economics 205, Fall 2002: Final Examination, Possible Answers

Adding Production to the Theory

Name: Section Registered In:

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

1 General Equilibrium

CLASS NOTES: BUSINESS CALCULUS

Math 1314 ONLINE Lesson 12

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

MTH 2032 Semester II

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Lesson 3-1: Solving Linear Systems by Graphing

Learning Log Title: CHAPTER 6: SOLVING INEQUALITIES AND EQUATIONS. Date: Lesson: Chapter 6: Solving Inequalities and Equations

22: Applications of Differential Calculus

Algebra IA Final Review

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Math 141:512. Practice Exam 1 (extra credit) Due: February 6, 2019

AMS-MAA-MER Special Session: David Bressoud Macalester College, St. Paul, MN New Orleans, January 8, 2007

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Math 3 Variable Manipulation Part 7 Absolute Value & Inequalities

Algebra 2 Pre AP Chapters 2 & 12 Review Worksheet

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Lecture 7: General Equilibrium - Existence, Uniqueness, Stability

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016

Chapter 4. Systems of Linear Equations; Matrices. Opening Example. Section 1 Review: Systems of Linear Equations in Two Variables

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0}

Unitary Dynamics and Quantum Circuits

Simon Fraser University, Department of Economics, Econ 201, Prof. Karaivanov FINAL EXAM Answer key

MAT 111 Final Exam Fall 2013 Name: If solving graphically, sketch a graph and label the solution.

SHORT INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING. 1. Example

Calculus III (MAC )

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

The Growth of Functions. A Practical Introduction with as Little Theory as possible

UNIVERSITY OF KWA-ZULU NATAL

Vector fields Lecture 2

IBM Research Report. Equilibrium in Prediction Markets with Buyers and Sellers

Contents CONTENTS 1. 1 Straight Lines and Linear Equations 1. 2 Systems of Equations 6. 3 Applications to Business Analysis 11.

The University of Melbourne BHP Billiton School Mathematics Competition 2007 INTERMEDIATE DIVISION SOLUTIONS

Lecture Notes for January 23, 2012: Existence of general equilibrium in an economy with an excess demand function

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Knowing when you'll be done

High School Math Contest. Level 3 Exam. Lenoir-Rhyne University Donald and Helen Schort School of Mathematics and Computing Sciences

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 3: Preferences and Choice. Today s Aims. The Story So Far. A Short Diversion: Proofs

UNIT 2: REASONING WITH LINEAR EQUATIONS AND INEQUALITIES. Solving Equations and Inequalities in One Variable

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

18.01 Single Variable Calculus Fall 2006

MTH Linear Algebra. Study Guide. Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Numerical illustration

Mathematical Methods and Economic Theory

Competitive Equilibrium

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Product differences and prices

Math 122 Fall Handout 11: Summary of Euler s Method, Slope Fields and Symbolic Solutions of Differential Equations

Economics 203: Intermediate Microeconomics. Calculus Review. A function f, is a rule assigning a value y for each value x.

8. Qualitative analysis of autonomous equations on the line/population dynamics models, phase line, and stability of equilibrium points (corresponds

(2) Let f(x) = 5x. (3) Say f (x) and f (x) have the following graphs. Sketch a graph of f(x). The graph of f (x) is: 3x 5

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

FLC Ch 1-3 (except 1.4, 3.1, 3.2) Sec 1.2: Graphs of Equations in Two Variables; Intercepts, Symmetry

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

MATH 162. Midterm 2 ANSWERS November 18, 2005

3. (1.2.13, 19, 31) Find the given limit. If necessary, state that the limit does not exist.

Introduction to linear programming using LEGO.

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

1 a) Remember, the negative in the front and the negative in the exponent have nothing to do w/ 1 each other. Answer: 3/ 2 3/ 4. 8x y.

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model : USA

Designing Information Devices and Systems I Fall 2018 Lecture Notes Note 21

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Pre-Leaving Certificate Examination, 2017 Triailscrúdú na hardteistiméireachta, Mathematics. Paper 1. Higher Level. 2½ hours.

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES

N/4 + N/2 + N = 2N 2.

Richard DiSalvo. Dr. Elmer. Mathematical Foundations of Economics. Fall/Spring,

PERIODICITY AND CHAOS ON A MODIFIED SAMUELSON MODEL

THE REPRESENTATION THEORY, GEOMETRY, AND COMBINATORICS OF BRANCHED COVERS

Increasing/Decreasing Test. Extreme Values and The First Derivative Test.

Transcription:

A model for competitive markets Manuela Girotti MATH 345 Differential Equations Contents 1 Competitive markets 1 1.1 Competitive market with only one good......................... 2 1.2 Competitive market with N goods............................ 4 2 Stability of the competitive market 6 In these notes we will present a simple, but remarkable model for the dynamics of prices under the law of supply and demand. We will show that under reasonable hypotheses for a competitive market, if there exists an equilibrium scenario, then this scenario is stable and asymptotically stable in the large time limit). This is a well-known result due to Arrow, Block and Hurwicz. These notes are mostly based on M. Girotti s personal notes from the course Fisica Matematica I given by Prof. Dario Bamusi at Università degli Studi di Milano in far 2007 and on the seminal paper [1]. 1 Competitive markets Let s consider a market where there is a certain number of individuals who trades i.e. buys and sells) N goods among themselves. Each good will have a certain price which can vary in time: p i = p i t), for i = 1,..., N. Hypothesis 1 Competitivity): we are assuming we are studying a capitalistic market, where nothing is given for free. Therefore, the prices will never be equal to zero: p i t) > 0 i = 1,..., N, t R. We can collect the prices of all the goods under consideration in a price vector p =.. Each person in the market is both buying and selling all the goods; in particular, the j-th person will have a demand of the j-th good equal to some value d ij and he/she will have a supply of the same good equal to another value s ij : 1 p N

d ij = d ij p) s ij = s ij p) demand of the i-th good by the j-th person supply of the i-th good by the j-th person All these values are clearly dependent on the prices of the goods themselves how expensive or how cheap they are). We can collect all these values in a demand table as well as in a supply table as shown in Figure 1. The total demand of the i-th good will them be the sum over i-th row of the demand table : m d i p) = similarly the total supply of the i-th good will be the sum over the i-th row of the supply table : m s i p) = j=1 j=1 d ij s ij Person 1 Person 2... Person m good #1 d 11 d 12... d 1m good #2 d 21 d 22... d 2m.... good #N d N1 d N2... d Nm Figure 1: An example of a Demand Table with m people and N goods. The total demand of each good is equal to the sum over the corresponding row. Our capitalistic market will clearly be based on the Law of Supply and Demand: if there is more demand of one item than its supply, its price will then increase. Vice versa, if there is more supply than demand, the price of the good will decrease. Let F i p) = d i p) s i p) a function that keeps track of the surplus of demand for the good number i. Then, according to the Law of Supply and Demand, the variation of price of that good will be dictated by how much excess or shortage) of demand we have at any time: p i = F i p). It is easy to notice that if there is an excess in demand and not enough supply, then F i p) > 0 and the price of the i-th good grows; on the other hand, if there is a lot of supply and not much demand, then F i p) < 0 and the price the good decreases. 1.1 Competitive market with only one good Let s consider this toy model where there are a certain number of people trading only one good say, strawberries) at price p = pt). The price equation is p = F p) = dp) sp) 2

First of all, we can notice that the equation is a separable ODE, therefore a solution can easily be found, once the functions dp) and sp) are explicit: pt) dp dp) sp) = dt = t t 0 pt 0 ) On the other hand, regardless of whether we know how dp) and sp) look like, we can still qualitatively analyze this equation. The function y = dp) is called demand curve. Under the law of Supply and Demand it is reasonable to assume that the function has the following properties: dp) 0 for all prices p R + ; at most, the demand could be equal to zero, but it cannot be negative; d0) > 0, the demand for some free goods is always high!); the demand dp) is decreasing as the price p is increasing. The function y = sp) is called supply curve. We can also assume similar properties for such a function: sp) 0 for all prices p R + ; at most, the supplly could be equal to zero; s0) = 0, we assumed no giveaways nobody wants to give goods for free); the supply sp) is increasing as the price p is increasing because there would be less people willing to buy). Collecting all these information, we can give a rough sketch of how these functions could look like as in Figure 2. sp) dp) p 0 p Figure 2: The demand and supply curves. It is clear from the behaviour of the functions that p 0 is a attractive equilibrium point. Since dp) is a decreasing function ond sp) is increasing, there exists at least one point p 0 where the two curves cross each other: dp 0 ) = sp 0 ), meaning F p 0 ) = dp 0 ) sp 0 ) = 0. 3

This means that pt) = p 0 is an equilibrium pointequilibrium solution) for the differential equation p = F p). Let s analyze the stability of p 0 : for p < p 0 we have that F p) = dp) sp) > 0, by simply looking at the graph, and for p > p 0 F p) < 0. This means that for the values of p before p 0 the dynamics is moving forward and then p > p 0 the dynamics is moving backwards see Figure 2): p 0 is a stable and asymptotically stable equilibrium point. 1.2 Competitive market with N goods For a more general scenario, we need to introduce some extra hypotheses and constraints that will still be derived using common sense, while trying to keep the model relatively simple. Since we are considering N goods, each good s price will have its own differential equation to satisfy, but the function F which measures the excess of demand will now depend on the prices of all the goods: F i = F i,,..., p N ) for each good i = 1,..., N. Therefore we have a system of N equation for the unknown functions t),..., p N t). We can write it in a compact form as p = Fp). Hypothesis 2 Budget Constraints). We are assuming that nobody can cheat, claiming he/she has more money than what he/she actually has, and nobody loans money to other people. In this setting, each individual j has some amount of items of each good s ij p) that he/she can sell at price p i, for each good i = 1,..., N. The total virtual) amount of money that the individual j can gain is then b j = s ij p)p i the total budget. Hypothesis 3 Maximal Satisfaction). We are further assuming that each person spends all the budget that he/she has immediately! we are not allowing savings) This means that the total expenses of the j person e j = d ij p)p i will be exactly equal to the total budget: e j = b j. This implies that for each j 0 = e j b j = d ij p)p i s ij p)p i = [d ij p) s ij p)] p i = F i p)p i. This relation is known under the name of Walras Law: p Fp) = 0 4

Hypothesis 4 Homogeneity). It is reasonable to assume changing the currency used in the trading doesn t affect the behaviour of the market as a first approximation of the model). In mathematics terms, we require the function Fp) to be homogeneous: Fλp) = Fp) λ R +. Hypothesis 5 Gross Substitutability). Roughly speaking, we are assuming that if all the prices are fixed except the price of one good, say the k-th good, then the demand of all the other goods different from the k-th one will increases: F i p k p) > 0 i k You can imagine a case where you would like to buy strawberries, but their price increased since last time you did the groceries and now they re too expensive. So, instead, you decide to buy apples because their price is still the same as last time, and maybe a couple of onions. Then, the demand of both the apples and the onions increases! The following results hold. Proposition 1. Given a competitive market p = Fp). and under the Hypotheses 4 and 5 above, if there exists an equilibrium point π i.e. Fπ) = 0), then it is unique up to a scaling factor λπ, λ R + ). Proposition 2. Given a competitive market p = Fp). and under the assumption that Walras Law holds, then p = N is a constant of motion. We will not give the proof of Proposition 1. The proof of Proposition 2 on the other hand is very simple. Proof. We simply need to show that the quantity pt) does not depend on time. For simplicity, we can consider the norm squared and calculate its time derivative: d p 2) = d N ) i = 2p i p i = 2 p i F i p) = 0 dt dt where the last equality is due to Walras Law. An important consequence of Proposition 2 is the following: once we fix the initial condition p0) = p 0, the price dynamics pt) happens the positive portion of the) sphere in R N with radius p 0, because the norm is a conserved quantity and it is the same for all times see Figures 3 and 4). i 5

pt) p 0 Figure 3: A market with N = 2 goods: the dynamics happens on a quarter of a circle. p 3 pt) p 0 Figure 4: A market with N = 3 goods: the dynamics happens on the positive portion of a 3Dsphere. 2 Stability of the competitive market Theorem 3 Arrow-Block-Hurwicz, 1959). Consider the price law and assume that the following hypotheses hold: 1. Walras Law: N F ip)p i = 0; p = Fp) 2. Homogeneity: F i λp) = F i p) for all i = 1,..., N; 3. Gross Substitutability: F i p k p) > 0 for all i k, i, k = 1,..., N. If there exists an equilibrium point π R N + such that Fπ) = 0 then, π is attractive i.e. the constant solution pt) = π t R + is asymptotically stable). A striking consequence of this theorem is the following: 6

in a competitive market, if there exists some equilibrium value for the prices of the goods we are considering, then the prices will converge to that equilibrium value in the long run, implying that there will be a stable balance of supply and demand. The proof is very simple and it just requires the use of some intuitive tools in linear algebra and basic calculus. Proof. Let p 0 R N be the initial condition of our Cauchy problem: { p = Fp) p0) = p 0 and let π R N be an equilibrium point of the system i.e. Fπ) = 0). We can assume, thanks to homogeneity, that π = p 0. We consider now the solution pt) of the above Cauchy problem with initial condition p0) = p 0 and we want to study the distance between the solution pt) and the equilibrium point π: dist 2 pt), π) = pt) π 2 0. Our goal is to prove that as t +, this quantity tends to zero, implying that the solution pt) converges to the equilibrium solution π. We then study its derivative: d pt) π 2) = d N ) p i t) π i ) 2 = 2 p i t) π i ) p i = 2 p i t) π i ) F i p) dt dt = 2 p i F i p) 2 π i F i p) = 2π F i p)π i where in the last equality we used Walras Law. It is clear that if we manage to prove that if d dt pt) π 2) < 0, then the function pt) π 2 decreases with time and, since it is a non-negative function by construction, it necessarily follows that pt) π 2 0 as t +. To get what we want, we will use the following Lemma 4. In the same hypotheses of the theorem above, we have F i p)π i > 0 Proof. We will only give a proof in the case of N = 2 goods. The proof for general N is more complicated to visualize, but it follows the same idea. Set [ ] [ ] α p1 π = and p = β 7

where α, β,, 0 and p is another solution, different from π and by homogeneity) also not proportional to π: p λπ for any λ R \ 0. However, we can still assume that both vectors have the same norm the same length): p = π. This implies that α β meaning that the slope of the two vectors are different. Suppose that < α β > α β the case where follows the same argument), meaning that the slope of p is bigger than the slope of π, as in Figure 5. p π By Walras Law, Figure 5: The case < α β. p Fp) = F 1 p) + F 2 p) = 0 meaning that the vector p and the vector Fp) are orthogonal. Moreover, the vector Fp) lies in the fourth quadrant: indeed, consider the vector v = µp with µ = β [ ] [ ] β µp1 v = = p [ ] p2 1 α < = π µ β β where the inequality is given by the fact that the second component is unchanged and for the first component we used the hypothesis < α β. By Gross Substitutability, we have that F 2 > 0 meaning that F 2 p) increases if the first component of p increases. Therefore, [ ]) β [ ]) F 2 p) = F 2 µp) = F 2 α < F 2 = F β β 2 π) = 0 8

where we used Homogeneity in the first equality and the fact that π is an equilibrium point in the last equality. This shows that the second component of the vector Fp) is negative, therefore the vector itself must be in the fourth quadrant see Figure 6). p π Fp) Figure 6: The location of the vector Fp) in the case < α β. Now, collecting all these observation, we have: 2 F i p)π i = π Fp) = π Fp) cosθ) > 0 because θ is the angle between the two vectors and Fp) is in the fourth quadrant while π is in the first one thus, θ [0, π 2 ) is an acute angle). Finally, using the Lemma we just proved, it is clear that d pt) π 2) < 0. dt Therefore, the function pt) π 2 decreases with time and pt) π 2 0 as t +, meaning that π is an asymptotically stable equilibrium solution: pt) π as t +. References [1] K.J. Arrow, H.D. Block, and L. Hurwicz. On the stability of the competitive equilibrium, II. Econometrica, 271):82 109, 1959. 9