Research Article Bifurcation and Global Dynamics of a Leslie-Gower Type Competitive System of Rational Difference Equations with Quadratic Terms

Similar documents
Research Article Global Dynamics of a Competitive System of Rational Difference Equations in the Plane

Global Dynamics and Bifurcations of Two Quadratic Fractional Second Order Difference Equations

Basins of Attraction of Period-Two Solutions of Monotone Difference Equations

Global Dynamics of Certain Homogeneous Second-Order Quadratic Fractional Difference Equation

Nonhyperbolic Dynamics for Competitive Systems in the Plane and Global Period-doubling Bifurcations

Bifurcations of Some Planar Discrete Dynamical Systems with Applications

8.1 Bifurcations of Equilibria

Competitive and Cooperative Differential Equations

2.10 Saddles, Nodes, Foci and Centers

Global Stability for Mixed Monotone Systems

arxiv: v1 [math.ds] 11 Feb 2011

Nonlinear dynamics & chaos BECS

A REMARK ON THE GLOBAL DYNAMICS OF COMPETITIVE SYSTEMS ON ORDERED BANACH SPACES

Mathematical Modeling I

Physics: spring-mass system, planet motion, pendulum. Biology: ecology problem, neural conduction, epidemics

Research Article Fixed Point Theorems in Cone Banach Spaces

Local and Global Dynamics of Certain Second-Order Rational Difference Equations Containing Quadratic Terms

Research Article Cyclic Iterative Method for Strictly Pseudononspreading in Hilbert Space

Half of Final Exam Name: Practice Problems October 28, 2014

On the Dynamics of a Rational Difference Equation, Part 1

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

Congurations of periodic orbits for equations with delayed positive feedback

Elements of Applied Bifurcation Theory

MATH 614 Dynamical Systems and Chaos Lecture 3: Classification of fixed points.

Feedback control for a chemostat with two organisms

The Invariant Curve in a Planar System of Difference Equations

11 Chaos in Continuous Dynamical Systems.

ASYMPTOTICALLY STABLE EQUILIBRIA FOR MONOTONE SEMIFLOWS. M.W. Hirsch. (Communicated by Aim Sciences)

Research Article The Stability of Gauss Model Having One-Prey and Two-Predators

Chapter 4. Inverse Function Theorem. 4.1 The Inverse Function Theorem

7 Planar systems of linear ODE

Sequences and Series

Dynamics of the equation complex plane

Introduction to Applied Nonlinear Dynamical Systems and Chaos

In particular, if A is a square matrix and λ is one of its eigenvalues, then we can find a non-zero column vector X with

Towards a theory of ecotone resilience: coastal vegetation on a salinity gradient

HYPERBOLIC SETS WITH NONEMPTY INTERIOR

Research Article Common Fixed Points of Weakly Contractive and Strongly Expansive Mappings in Topological Spaces

Research Article Global Attractivity of a Higher-Order Difference Equation

Research Article Some Fixed-Point Theorems for Multivalued Monotone Mappings in Ordered Uniform Space

Research Article Almost Periodic Solutions of Prey-Predator Discrete Models with Delay

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games

Lecture3 The logistic family.

Dynamics of Modified Leslie-Gower Predator-Prey Model with Predator Harvesting

ON ALLEE EFFECTS IN STRUCTURED POPULATIONS

Department of Mathematics, Faculty of Science, Chiang Mai University, Chiang Mai 50200, Thailand

(x k ) sequence in F, lim x k = x x F. If F : R n R is a function, level sets and sublevel sets of F are any sets of the form (respectively);

1. 4 2y 1 2 = x = x 1 2 x + 1 = x x + 1 = x = 6. w = 2. 5 x

Mathematics 530. Practice Problems. n + 1 }

Summary of topics relevant for the final. p. 1

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

Research Article Attracting Periodic Cycles for an Optimal Fourth-Order Nonlinear Solver

Topological properties

Regular Weakly Star Closed Sets in Generalized Topological Spaces 1

On the Fundamental Bifurcation Theorem for Semelparous Leslie Models

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi

1 Directional Derivatives and Differentiability

Mathematische Annalen

Stable and Unstable Manifolds for Planar Dynamical Systems

Sufficient conditions for a period incrementing big bang bifurcation in one-dimensional maps.

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ.

Research Article On λ-statistically Convergent Double Sequences of Fuzzy Numbers

MATH 5720: Unconstrained Optimization Hung Phan, UMass Lowell September 13, 2018

Research Article Iterative Approximation of a Common Zero of a Countably Infinite Family of m-accretive Operators in Banach Spaces

Global Attractivity of a Higher-Order Nonlinear Difference Equation

Research Article Hybrid Algorithm of Fixed Point for Weak Relatively Nonexpansive Multivalued Mappings and Applications

Lyapunov Stability Theory

Asynchronous and Synchronous Dispersals in Spatially Discrete Population Models

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

ẋ = f(x, y), ẏ = g(x, y), (x, y) D, can only have periodic solutions if (f,g) changes sign in D or if (f,g)=0in D.

Research Article Common Fixed Points for Multimaps in Metric Spaces

Lozi-like maps. M. Misiurewicz and S. Štimac. May 13, 2017

Research Article On Multivalued Nonexpansive Mappings in R-Trees

3 Stability and Lyapunov Functions

Applied Mathematics Letters

Remark on a Couple Coincidence Point in Cone Normed Spaces

Dynamics of a Population Model Controlling the Spread of Plague in Prairie Dogs

Problems for Chapter 3.

Review of Multi-Calculus (Study Guide for Spivak s CHAPTER ONE TO THREE)

SPACES ENDOWED WITH A GRAPH AND APPLICATIONS. Mina Dinarvand. 1. Introduction

Shapley Polygons in 4 4 Games

CENTER MANIFOLD AND NORMAL FORM THEORIES

Research Article Generalized Mann Iterations for Approximating Fixed Points of a Family of Hemicontractions

CHAPTER 3. Gauss map. In this chapter we will study the Gauss map of surfaces in R 3.

Global Attractivity in a Higher Order Nonlinear Difference Equation

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Caristi-type Fixed Point Theorem of Set-Valued Maps in Metric Spaces

1 )(y 0) {1}. Thus, the total count of points in (F 1 (y)) is equal to deg y0

B5.6 Nonlinear Systems

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: COMPACT SETS AND FINITE-DIMENSIONAL SPACES. 1. Compact Sets

Contents. 2 Sequences and Series Approximation by Rational Numbers Sequences Basics on Sequences...

1 Functions and Graphs

Research Article Iterative Approximation of Common Fixed Points of Two Nonself Asymptotically Nonexpansive Mappings

THE ROSENZWEIG-MACARTHUR PREDATOR-PREY MODEL

Hyperbolic Dynamics. Todd Fisher. Department of Mathematics University of Maryland, College Park. Hyperbolic Dynamics p.

convergence theorem in abstract set up. Our proof produces a positive integrable function required unlike other known

A note on the monotonicity of matrix Riccati equations

Persistence and Bifurcation in a Two-Dimensional Discrete System

Transcription:

Hindawi Abstract and Applied Analysis Volume 2017 Article ID 3104512 19 pages https://doi.org/10.1155/2017/3104512 Research Article Bifurcation and Global Dynamics of a Leslie-Gower Type Competitive System of Rational Difference Equations with Quadratic Terms V. HadDiabdiT 1 M. R. S. KulenoviT 2 and E. Pilav 3 1 Division of Mathematics Faculty of Mechanical Engineering University of Sarajevo Bosnia and Herzegovina 2 Department of Mathematics University of Rhode Island Kingston RI 02881-0816 USA 3 Department of Mathematics University of Sarajevo 75 000 Sarajevo Bosnia and Herzegovina Correspondence should be addressed to M. R. S. Kulenović; mkulenovic@mail.uri.edu Received 1 April 2017; Accepted 4 June 2017; Published 2 August 2017 AcademicEditor:PatriciaJ.Y.Wong Copyright 2017 V.Hadžiabdić et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License which permits unrestricted use distribution and reproduction in any medium provided the original work is properly cited. We investigate global dynamics of the following systems of difference equations x n+1 =x n /(A 1 +B 1 x n +C 1 y n ) y n+1 =y 2 n /(A 2 + B 2 x n +C 2 y 2 n ) n = 0 1... where the parameters A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 are positive numbers and the initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers. This system is a version of the Leslie-Gower competition model for two species. We show that this system has rich dynamics which depends on the part of parametric space. 1. Introduction In this paper we study the global dynamics of the following rational system of difference equations: x x n+1 = n A 1 +B 1 x n +C 1 y n y 2 n (1) y n+1 = A 2 +B 2 x n +C 2 yn 2 n=01... where the parameters A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 are positive numbers and initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers. System (1) is a competitive system and our results are based on recent results about competitive systems in the plane; see [1]. System (1) can be used as a mathematical model for competition in population dynamics. System (1) is related to Leslie-Gower competition model x n x n+1 = A 1 +B 1 x n +C 1 y n y y n+1 = n A 2 +B 2 x n +C 2 y n n = 0 1... (2) where the parameters A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 are positive numbers and initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers considered in [2]. System (2) globally exhibits three dynamic scenarios in five parametric regions which are competitive exclusion competitive coexistence and existence of an infinite number of equilibrium solutions; see [1 3]. System (2) does not exhibit the Allee effect which is desirable from modeling point of view. The simplest variation of system (2) which exhibits the Allee effect is probably system x n+1 = x 2 n A 1 +B 1 x 2 n +C 1y n y 2 n y n+1 = A 2 +B 2 x n +C 2 yn 2 n=01... where the parameters A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 are positive numbers and initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers considered in [4]. System (3) has between 1 and 9 equilibrium points and exhibits nine dynamics scenarios part of each is the Allee effect. In the case of the dynamic (3)

2 Abstract and Applied Analysis scenario with nine equilibrium points system (3) exhibits both competitive exclusion and competitive coexistence as well as the Allee effect. Another system with quadratic terms is x 2 n x n+1 = B 1 xn 2 +C 1yn 2 y 2 n y n+1 = A 2 +B 2 xn 2 +C 2yn 2 n=01... where the parameters A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 are positive numbers and initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers such that x 0 +y 0 > 0 considered in [5]. System (4) exhibits seven scenarios part of each is singular Allee s effect which means that the origin as the singular point of this system still has some basin of attraction. First systematic study for a system with quadratic terms was performed in [6] for system x n x n+1 = A 1 +yn 2 y n y n+1 = A 2 +xn 2 n = 0 1... which exhibits nine dynamic scenarios and whose dynamics is very similar to the corresponding system without quadratic terms considered in [7]. In general it seems that an introduction of quadratic terms in equations of the Leslie-Gower model (2) generates the Allee effect. We will test this hypothesis in this paper by introducing the quadratic terms only in the second equation. System (1) can be considered as the competitive version of the decoupled system x n+1 = x n A 1 +B 1 x n y 2 n y n+1 = A 2 +C 2 yn 2 n = 0 1... where the parameters A 1 A 2 B 1 and C 2 are positive numbers and initial conditions x 0 and y 0 are arbitrary nonnegative numbers whose dynamics can be directly obtained from two separate equations. Unlike system (2) which has five regions of parameters with distinct local behavior system (1) has eighteen regions of parameters with distinct local behavior which is caused by the geometry of the problem that is by the geometry of equilibrium curves. More precisely the equilibrium curves of system (2) are lines while the equilibrium curves of system (1) are a line and a parabola. In the case when A 1 >1 all equilibrium points are hyperbolic and all solutions are attracted to the three equilibrium points on the y-axis and we can describe this situation as (4) (5) (6) competitive exclusion case. When A 1 =1 the equilibrium point E 1 is nonhyperbolic and dynamics is analogous to the case when A 1 > 1. In both cases the Allee effect is present. When A 1 <1 there exist 11 regions of parameters with different global dynamics. In nine of these regions the global dynamics is in competitive exclusion case which means that all solutions converge to one of the equilibrium points on the axes and in only two situations we have competitive coexistence case which means that the interior equilibrium points have substantial basin of attraction. In all 11 cases the zero equilibrium has some basin of attraction which is a part of y-axis so we can say that in these cases system (1) exhibits weak Allee s effect. Figure 3 gives the bifurcation diagram showing the transition from different global dynamics situations when A 1 < 1sincethecases A 1 1aresimple and do not need graphical interpretation. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 contains some necessary results on competitive systems in the plane. Section 3 provides some basic information about the number of equilibrium points. Section 4 contains local stability analysis of all equilibrium solutions. Section 5 contains some global results on injectivity of the map associated with system (1). Section 6 gives global dynamics of system (1) in all regions of the parameters. 2. Preliminaries A first-order system of difference equations x n+1 =f(x n y n ) y n+1 =g(x n y n ) n=01... where S R 2 (f g) : S S f g are continuous functions is competitive if f(x y) is nondecreasing in x and nonincreasing in y and g(x y) is nonincreasing in x and nondecreasing in y. Ifbothf and g are nondecreasing in x and ysystem(7)is cooperative. Competitiveandcooperative maps are defined similarly. Strongly competitive systems of difference equations or strongly competitive maps are those for which the functions f and g are coordinate-wise strictly monotone. Competitive and cooperative systems have been investigated by many authors; see [1 3 7 16]. Special attention to discrete competitive and cooperative systems in the plane was given in [1 3 16 17]. One of the reasons for paying special attention to two-dimensional discrete competitive and cooperative systems is their applicability and the fact that many examples of mathematical models in biology and economy which involve competition or cooperation are models which involve two species. Another reason is that the theory of two-dimensional discrete competitive and cooperative systems is very well developed unlike such theory for three-dimensional and higher systems. Part of the reason for this situation is de Mottoni-Schiaffino theorem given below which provides relatively simple scenarios for possible behavior of many two-dimensional discrete competitive and cooperative systems. However this does not mean that one (7)

Abstract and Applied Analysis 3 can not encounter chaos in such systems as has been shown by Smith; see [16]. If k =(uv) R 2 wedenotewithq l (k) l {1234} the four quadrants in R 2 relative to kthatisq 1 (k) ={(xy) R 2 : x u y V} Q 2 (k) = {(xy) R 2 : x u y V} and so on. Define the South-East partial order se on R 2 by (x y) se (s t) if and only if x sand y t. Similarly we define the North-East partial order ne on R 2 by (x y) ne (s t) if and only if x sand y t.fora R 2 and x R 2 define the distance from x to A as dist(x A) fl inf{ x y : y A}.ByintA we denote the interior of a set A. It is easy to show that a map F is competitive if it is nondecreasing with respect to the South-East partial order that is if the following holds: ( x1 y 1) se ( x 2 y 2) F( x1 y 1) se F( x 2 y 2). For standard definitions of attracting fixed point saddle point stable manifold and related notions see [10]. We now state three results for competitive maps in the plane. The following definition is from [16]. Definition 1. Let S be a nonempty subset of R 2.Acompetitive map T:S S is said to satisfy condition (O+)ifforeveryx y in S T(x) ne T(y) implies x ne yandt is said to satisfy condition (O ) ifforeveryx y in S T(x) ne T(y) implies y ne x. The following theorem was proved by de Mottoni- Schiaffino [17] for the Poincaré map of a periodic competitive Lotka-Volterra system of differential equations. Smith generalized the proof to competitive and cooperative maps [13 14]. Theorem 2. Let S be a nonempty subset of R 2.IfT is a competitive map for which (O+) holds then for all x S {T n (x)} is eventually componentwise monotone. If the orbit of x has compact closure then it converges to a fixed point of T. If instead (O ) holds then for all x S {T 2n (x)} is eventually componentwise monotone. If the orbit of x has compact closure in S then its omega limit set is either a period-two orbit or a fixed point. The following result is from [16] with the domain of the map specialized to be the Cartesian product of intervals of real numbers. It gives a sufficient condition for conditions (O+)and(O ). Theorem 3. Let R R 2 be the Cartesian product of two intervals in R. LetT:R R be a C 1 competitive map. If T is injective and det J T (x) > 0 for all x R then T satisfies (O+). IfT is injective and det J T (x) < 0 for all x R then T satisfies (O ). (8) The following result is a direct consequence of the TrichotomyTheoremofDancerandHess(see[18])andishelpful for determining the basins of attraction of the equilibrium points. Corollary 4. If the nonnegative cone of is a generalized quadrant in R n andift has no fixed points in u 1 u 2 other than u 1 and u 2 then the interior of u 1 u 2 is either a subset of the basin of attraction of u 1 orasubsetofthebasinofattraction of u 2. Next result is well known global attractivity result which holds in partially ordered Banach spaces as well; see [18]. Theorem 5. Let T be a monotone map on a closed and bounded rectangular region R R 2.SupposethatT has a unique fixed point e in R.Thene is a global attractor of T on R. The following theorems were proved by Kulenović and Merino [1] for competitive systems in the plane when one oftheeigenvaluesofthelinearizedsystematanequilibrium (hyperbolic or nonhyperbolic) is by absolute value smaller than 1 while the other has an arbitrary value. These results are useful for determining basins of attraction of fixed points of competitive maps. Theorem 6. Let T be a competitive map on a rectangular region R R 2.Letx Rbe a fixed point of T such that Δ fl R int(q 1 (x) Q 3 (x)) is nonempty (i.e. x is not the NW or SE vertex of R)andTis strongly competitive on Δ.Suppose that the following statements are true: (a) The map T has a C 1 extension to a neighborhood of x. (b) The Jacobian J T (x) of T at x has real eigenvalues λ μ such that 0< λ <μwhere λ < 1andtheeigenspace E λ associated with λ is not a coordinate axis. Then there exists a curve C R through x that is invariant and a subset of the basin of attraction of x suchthatc is tangential to the eigenspace E λ at x andcis the graph of a strictly increasing continuous function of the first coordinate on an interval. Any endpoints of C in the interior of R are either fixed points or minimal period-two points. In the latter case the set of endpoints of C is a minimal period-two orbit of T. The situation where the endpoints of C are boundary points of R is of interest. The following result gives a sufficient condition for this case. Theorem 7. For the curve C of Theorem 6 to have endpoints in R it is sufficient that at least one of the following conditions is satisfied (i) The map T has no fixed points or periodic points of minimal period-two in Δ. (ii) The map T has no fixed points in Δ det J T (x) > 0and T(x) = x has no solutions x Δ. (iii) The map T has no points of minimal period-two in Δ det J T (x) < 0andT(x) = x has no solutions x Δ.

4 Abstract and Applied Analysis The next result is useful for determining basins of attraction of fixed points of competitive maps. Theorem 8. (A) Assume the hypotheses of Theorem 6 and let C bethecurvewhoseexistenceisguaranteedbytheorem6.if the endpoints of C belong to RthenC separates R into two connected components namely W fl {x R \ C : y C with x se y} W + fl {x R \ C : y C with y se x} such that the following statements are true: (9) 3. Number of Equilibria In this section we give some basic facts which are used later. Let T be the map associated with system (1) given by T (x y) = (f (x y) g (x y)) x =( A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y y 2 (11) A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 ). Let R = R 2 +. The equilibrium points (x y) of system (1) satisfy equations (i) W is invariant and dist(t n (x) Q 2 (x)) 0 as n for every x W. (ii) W + is invariant and dist(t n (x) Q 4 (x)) 0 as n for every x W +. x A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y = x y 2 A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 = y. (12) ) If in addition to the hypotheses of part (A) x is an interior point of R and T is C 2 and strongly competitive in a neighborhood of x thent has no periodic points in the boundary of Q 1 (x) Q 3 (x) except for x andthefollowing statements are true: (iii) For every x W there exists n 0 N such that T n (x) int Q 2 (x) for n n 0. For x=0we have y=y 2 A 2 y C 2 y 3 (13) from which we obtain three equilibrium points E 1 = (0 0) (iv) For every x W + there exists n 0 N such that T n (x) int Q 4 (x) for n n 0. If T is a map on a set R and if x is a fixed point of Tthe stable set W s (x) of x is the set {x R :T n (x) x} and unstable set W u (x) of x is the set E 2 =(0 1 Δ 1 2C 2 ) E 3 =(0 1+ Δ 1 2C 2 ) (14) {x R : there exists {x n } 0 n= R s.t. T(x n) =x n+1 x 0 =x lim x n n = x}. (10) When T is noninvertible the set W s (x) may not be connected andmadeupofinfinitelymanycurvesorw u (x) may not be a manifold. The following result gives a description of the stable and unstable sets of a saddle point of a competitive map. If the map is a diffeomorphism on RthesetsW s (x) and W u (x) are the stable and unstable manifolds of x. where Δ 1 =1 4A 2 C 2. Assume that x = 0. Then from the first equation of system (12) we have y= A 1 +B 1 x 1 C 1. (15) By substituting this into the second equation we obtain A 1 +B 1 x 1=0 (16) Theorem 9. In addition to the hypotheses of part ) of Theorem 8 suppose that μ > 1 and that the eigenspace E μ associated with μ is not a coordinate axis. If the curve C of Theorem 6 has endpoints in RthenC is the stable set W s (x) of x andtheunstablesetw u (x) of x is a curve in R that is tangential to E μ at x andsuchthatitisthegraphofastrictly decreasing function of the first coordinate on an interval. Any endpoints of W u (x) in R are fixed points of T. or g (x) B 2 1 C 2x 2 +x 1 (2 (A 1 1)C 2 +C 1 )+B 2 C 2 1 ) +(A 1 1) 2 C 2 +(A 1 1)C 1 +A 2 C 2 1 =0 (17)

Abstract and Applied Analysis 5 from which we obtain the other three equilibrium points E 4 =( 1 A 1 B 1 0) E 5 =( 2A 1B 1 C 2 B 2 C 2 1 B 1C 1 +2B 1 C 2 +C 1 Δ 2 2B1 2C 2 Proof. The proof of the statements (i) and (ii) is trivial and we skip it. Now we prove the statement (iii). In view of Descartes rule of signs we obtain that (17) has no positive solutions if A 1 1. Now we suppose that A 1 < 1. One can see that y 5 >0for all values of parameters. We consider two cases: (1) Assume that 2A 1 B 1 C 2 B 2 C 2 1 B 1C 1 +2B 1 C 2 0 (23) E 6 B 1 +B 2 C 1 Δ 2 2B 1 C 2 ) =( 2A 1B 1 C 2 B 2 C 2 1 B 1C 1 +2B 1 C 2 C 1 Δ 2 2B1 2C 2 (18) which is equivalent to Since C 2 C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) 2(1 A. (24) where B 1 +B 2 C 1 + Δ 2 2B 1 C 2 ) Δ 2 = 1 +B 2 C 1 ) 2 4B 1 (A 2 B 1 (A 1 1)B 2 )C 2. (19) Lemma 10. The following hold: (i) The equilibrium points E 2 and E 3 exist if and only if Δ 1 0and E 2 =E 3 if and only if Δ 1 =0. (ii) The equilibrium point E 4 exists if and only if A 1 1 and E 4 =E 1 ifandonlyifa 1 =1. (iii) Assume that Δ 2 0.The equilibrium point E 5 exists if and only if A 1 <1and Δ 2 0 C 2 we have that x 5 0if and only if (25) C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) C 2(1 A 1 )B 2 1 (26) 4B 1 (A 2 B 1 (A 1 1)B 2 ) C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) 2(1 A = 2C 1 +B 1 )((1 A 1 )B 2 C 1 +B 1 ( C 1 +A 1 1)) 4(1 A (A 2 B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2 ) (27) or C 1 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 (20) 0 which is equivalent to C 1 B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2. (28) C 1 > 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2. (21) (iv) Assume that Δ 2 0.The equilibrium point E 6 exists if and only if A 1 <1and From (27) and (28) it follows x 5 0if and only if C 1 B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2 C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) C 2(1 A 1 )B 2 1. (29) C 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 C 2 1 )B 2 + B 1. (22) (2) Assume that 2A 1 B 1 C 2 B 2 C 2 1 B 1C 1 +2B 1 C 2 <0 (30) which is equivalent to C 2 < C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) 2(1 A. (31)

6 Abstract and Applied Analysis (i) A 1 <1 R 1 R 31 풞 3 풞 12 풞32 R 25 풫 1 풞 11 C 2 R 32 (ii) A 1 =1 R 21 풞 22 R 23 C 2 풞 31 R 24 풫 2 R 22 풞 23 C 2 C 1 R 41 풞 4 R 42 (iii) A 1 >1 풞 21 C 1 C 1 Figure 1: Parameter regions in the (C 1 C 2 )-plane. The curves C 21 C 22 andc 23 are defined as part of the parabola C 2 =C 1 (1 A 1 A 2 C 1 )/(1 A 1 ) 2 and the curves C 32 and C 31 are defined as part of the parabola C 2 = /(). Then x 5 0if and only if Δ 2 C 2 1 ( B 1 (2 (A 1 1)C 2 +C 1 ) B 2 C 2 1 )2 = 4B 2 1 C 2 ((A 1 1) 2 C 2 +C 1 (A 2 C 1 +A 1 1)) 0 which is equivalent to Since (32) C 2 C 1 ( A 2 C 1 A 1 +1) 1 ) 2 (33) Δ 2 0 C 2 (34). 4B 1 (A 2 B 1 (A 1 1)B 2 ) C 1 ( A 2 C 1 A 1 +1) 1 ) 2 = ( 1)B 2 C 1 +B 1 ( C 1 A 1 +1)) 2 4(1 A 1 ) 2 B 1 (A 2 B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2 ) then from (33) and Δ 2 0we have Since 0 (35) C 2 C 1 2 C 1 A 1 ) 1 ) 2. (36) C 1 2 C 1 A 1 ) 1 ) 2 C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) 2(1 A = C 1 ( 1 )B 2 C 1 +B 1 ( C 1 +A 1 1)) 2(A 1 1) 2 B 1 (37) we have that (31) and (36) are equivalent to or C 1 > B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2 C 2 C 1 2 C 1 A 1 ) 1 ) 2 C 1 B 1 +(1 A 1 )B 2 C 2 < C 1 2 C 1 +B 1 ) 2(1 A. (38) (39) Now the proof of the statement (iii) follows from (28) (38) and (39). The proof of the statement (iv) is similar and we skip it. We now introduce the following notation for regions in parameter space (C 1 C 2 ) (see Figure 1): R 24 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 <C 2 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 } R 22 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 } R 21 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 > }

Abstract and Applied Analysis 7 R 25 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 1 C 23 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 > 1 A 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 } <C 2 < } R 23 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 A 1 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 <C 2 } R 1 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 <0} C 31 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < = 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 } C 11 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 > 1 A 1 } C 12 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 < 1 A 1 } P 1 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 C 1 = 1 A 1 C 2 = 1 4A 2 } P 2 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 C 1 = 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = B 1 (A 2 B 1 (A 1 1)B 2 ) ((A 1 1)B 2 B 1 ) 2 } R 31 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 =1 Δ 1 <0} R 32 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 =1 Δ 1 >0} C 3 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 =1 Δ 1 =0} R 41 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 >1 Δ 1 <0} R 42 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 >1 Δ 1 >0} C 32 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 1 C 4 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 >1 Δ 1 =0}. (40) > = 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 } C 21 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 } Figure 1 gives a graphical representation of above sets. The following result gives a complete classification for the number of equilibrium solutions of system (1). Proposition 11. Let A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 be positive real numbers. Then the number of positive equilibrium solutions of system(1)withparametersa 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 can be from 1 to 6. The different cases are given in Table 1. Proof. The proof follows from Lemma 10. 4. Linearized Stability Analysis The Jacobian matrix of the map T has the form C 22 ={(C 1 C 2 ):A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 1 J T > 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 } A 1 +yc 1 xc (A =( 1 +xb 1 +yc 1 ) 2 1 (A 1 +xb 1 +yc 1 ) 2 y 2 ). B 2 2y (A 2 +xb 2 ) (A 2 +xb 2 +y 2 C 2 ) 2 (A 2 +xb 2 +y 2 C 2 ) 2 (41)

8 Abstract and Applied Analysis Table 1: The criteria for the existence of the equilibrium points. Case Equilibria Region The criteria for the existence (i) E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 E 5 E 6 R 24 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 <C 2 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < (ii) E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 E 5 =E 6 C 1 )B 2 + B 1 31 C 2 = (iii) E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 E 5 R 22 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 (iv) E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 R 21 R 25 C 32 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 > or A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 2A 1 > 2 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 (v) E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 R 23 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 A 1 (vi) E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 6 E 4 E 5 C 21 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < (vii) E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 5 =E 6 E 4 P 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 C 1 )B 2 + B 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 1 ) 2 C 1 )B 2 + B 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 1 ) 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 2A 1 > (viii) E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 5 E 4 C 2 1 )B 2 + B 1 22 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 (ix) E 1 E 3 E 2 =E 5 E 4 C 23 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 A 1 C = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 2 1 ) 2 (x) E 1 E 2 =E 3 =E 5 E 4 P 1 A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 = 1 A 1 C = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 2 1 ) 2 (xi) E 1 E 2 =E 3 E 4 C 11 C 12 A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 = 1 A 1 (xii) E 1 E 4 R 1 A 1 <1 Δ 1 <0 (xiii) E 1 =E 4 E 2 E 3 R 32 A 1 =1 Δ 1 >0 (xiv) E 1 =E 4 E 2 =E 3 C 3 A 1 =1 Δ 1 =0 (xv) E 1 =E 4 R 31 A 1 =1 Δ 1 <0 (xvi) E 1 E 2 E 3 R 42 A 1 >1 Δ 1 >0 (xvii) E 1 E 2 =E 3 C 4 A 1 >1 Δ 1 =0 (xviii) E 1 R 41 A 1 >1 Δ 1 <0 The determinant of (41) at the equilibrium point is given by andthetraceof(41)attheequilibriumpointisgivenby det J T (x y) = y(2a 1 (A 2 +B 2 x) + y( +B 2 x) C 1 ) (A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y) 2 (A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 ) 2 (42) tr J T (x y) = A 1 + yc 1 (A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y) 2 + 2y(A 2 +B 2 x) (A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 ) 2. (43)

Abstract and Applied Analysis 9 The characteristic equation has the form λ 2 A λ( 1 + yc 1 (A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y) 2 + 2y(A 2 +B 2 x) (A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 ) 2 ) + y(2a 1 (A 2 +B 2 x) + y( +B 2 x) C 1 ) (A 1 +B 1 x+c 1 y) 2 (A 2 +B 2 x+c 2 y 2 ) 2 =0. Lemma 12. The following statements hold: (a) E 1 is locally asymptotically stable if A 1 >1. (b) E 1 is a saddle point if A 1 <1. (c) E 1 is a nonhyperbolic equilibrium point if A 1 =1. (44) Since f y (E i)<0 i=56wegetf x (E i)<1 i = 5 6. Similarly one can see that x g (y 6 )=1 g y (E 6) g x (E 6) 4B 1 C 2 (A 2 B 1 (A 1 1)B 2 )+B 2 C 1 = B 1 B 2 <0. Since g x (E 6)<0wegetg y (E 6)<1.Further x(y)= 1 A 1 C 1 y B 1 y A 2 C 2 y 2 B 2 (48) Proof. We have that for the equilibrium point E 1 trj T (E 1 )= 1/A 1 and det J T (E 1 )=0. The characteristic equation of (50) at E 1 has the form λ 2 (1/A 1 )λ = 0 from which the proof follows. Lemma 13. The following statements hold: (a) E 4 is locally asymptotically stable if A 1 <1. (b) E 4 is a nonhyperbolic equilibrium point if A 1 =1. Proof. We have that for the equilibrium point E 4 trj T (E 4 )= A 1 and det J T (E 4 )=0. The characteristic equation of (50) at E 4 has the form λ 2 A 1 λ=0 from which the proof follows. The equilibrium points E 5 and E 6 are intersection points of the curves x f (y) = 1 A 1 C 1 y B 1 x g (y) = y A 2 C 2 y 2 B 2. (45) Let x(y) = x f (y) x g (y) for y [(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 (1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 ]. Lemma 14. Let T = (f g) be the map defined by (11). Then f x (E 5)<1 f x (E 6)<1 g y (E 6)<1.Let f(y)=b 1 C 2 y 2 2 C 1 +B 1 )y+a 2 B 1 +B 2 1 ). (46) Then y 5 and y 6 are zeros of f(y) and sign( x(y)) = sign( f(y)) for y [(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 (1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 ]. Proof. The first derivative of x f (y 6 ) is given by x f (y i )= f y (E i) 1 f x (E i) = C 1 B 1 <0 i=56. (47) = B 1C 2 y 2 2 C 1 +B 1 )y+a 2 B 1 A 1 B 2 +B 2 B 1 B 2 = f(y) B 1 B 2 from which the proof follows. Lemma 15. Let T be the map associated with system (1) and b i (49) J T (x i y i )=( a i ) (50) c i d i be the Jacobian matrix of T at fixed point E i (i = 5 6). Then the Jacobian matrix (50) has real and distinct eigenvalues λ 1 and λ 2 such that 0<λ 1 λ 2. Furthermore the following hold: sign ( x (y 6 )) = sign (1 λ (6) 2 ) λ(6) 2 <1 (51) sign ( x (y 5 )) = sign (1 λ (5) 2 )(1 λ(5) 2 ). (52) Proof. Implicit differentiation of the equations defining C f and C g at E i gives x f (y i )= f y (E i) 1 f x (E i) x g (y i )=1 g y (E i) gx (E. i) (53) Characteristic equations associated with the Jacobian matrix of T at E i are given by p (λ) =λ 2 [f x (E i)+g y (E i)] λ +[f x (E i)g y (E i) f y (E i)g x (E i)] =λ 2 (a i +d i )λ+(a i d i b i c i ). (54)

10 Abstract and Applied Analysis Since the map T is competitive then the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix of the map T attheequilibriume i are real and distinct and furthermore 0<λ (i). By (53) we have x (y i )=x f (y i ) x g (y i ) = f y (E i) 1 fx (E i) 1 g y (E i) gx (E i) = b i 1 a i 1 d i c i 1 <λ(i) 2 = 1 + (a i +d i ) (a i d i b i c i ) c i (1 a i ) = (1 λ(i) 1 )(1 λ(i) c i (a i 1) 2 ). = p (1) c i (1 a i ) (55) In view of Lemma 14 and from tr J T (E 6 )=a 6 +d 6 =f x (E 6)+ g y (E 6) = λ (6) 1 +λ (6) 2 < 2 we get λ (6) 1 < 1. The map T is competitive which implies c 6 = g x (E 6) < 0. In view of Lemma 14 we get a 6 = f x (E 6) < 1 from which it follows (51). Similarly from c 5 =g x (E 5)<0and a 5 =f x (E 5)<1we obtain (52). The following lemma describes the local stability of the equilibrium points E 5 and E 6. Lemma 16. Assume that A 1 < 1 and Δ 2 0.Thenthe following hold: (i) If Δ 2 >0and E 6 exists then it is locally asymptotically stable. (ii) If Δ 2 >0and E 5 exists then it is a saddle point. (iii) If Δ 2 = 0 then E 5 = E 6. Furthermore if E 5 = E 6 exists then it is nonhyperbolic equilibrium point. The eigenvalues of J T (E 5 =E 6 ) are given by λ 1 =1and λ 2 <1. Proof. Assuming that Δ 2 > 0theny 5 and y 6 are zeros of multiplicity one of f(y)=b 1 C 2 y 2 2 C 1 +B 1 )y+a 2 B 1 +B 2 1 ) (56) and y 6 > y 5 >0.Fromthiswehave f(y) > 0 for y (0 y 5 ) (y 6 + )and f(y) < 0 for y (y 5 y 5 ). ByLemmas6and7from[19]theequilibriumcurves x f (y) and x g (y) intersect transversally at E 5 and E 6 thatis x (y i ) = 0 i = 5 6. By this and Lemma 14 and by continuity of function x(y) there exists a neighborhood U (i) of y y i i such that x (y) > 0 for y U y6 and x (y) < 0 for y U (5).This y 5 implies that x (y 6 )>0and x (y 5 )<0.ByLemma15wehave that E 6 is locally asymptotically stable and E 5 is a saddle point whenever equilibrium points E 5 and E 6 exist. Assume that Δ 2 = 0. Then y 5 = y 6 is zero of f(y) of multiplicity two. In view of Lemmas 6 and 7 from [19] we have that x (y 5 )=0.The rest of the proof follows from the proof of Lemma 15. Lemma 17. Assume that Δ 1 0. The following statements are true: (a) E 2 is a saddle point if Δ 1 >0andA 1 1or A 1 <1 and C 1 >(1 A 1 )(1 + 1 4A 2 C 2 )/. (b) E 2 is a repeller if Δ 1 >0 A 1 <1andC 1 <(1 A 1 )(1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 )/. (c) E 2 is a nonhyperbolic equilibrium point if Δ 1 =0or Δ 1 >0 A 1 <1 C 1 = 1)(1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 ). If Δ 1 =0then the eigenvalues of J T (E 2 ) are given by λ 1 =1 λ 2 = with corresponding eigenvectors k 1 = (0 1) T (57) 1 (58) C 1 +A 1 k 2 =( 2A T 2C 1 +A 1 1 B 2 ( C 1 +A 1 ) 1). (59) If (57) holds then the eigenvalues of J T (E 2 ) are given by λ 1 =1 λ 2 =1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 >1 with corresponding eigenvectors Proof. One can see that k 1 =( 1 4A T 2C 2 1) B 2 k 2 = (0 1) T. 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 ) = 2(1 A 1) 1 4A 2 C 2 C 2 +C 1 (1 4A 2 C 2 1 4A 2 C 2 ) 2A 1 C 2 +C 1 (1 1 4A 2 C 2 ) 1 det J T (E 2 ) = C 1 (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )+2C 2 (A 1 1 1 4A 2 C 2 ). 2A 1 C 2 +C 1 (1 1 4A 2 C 2 ) (60) (61) (62)

Abstract and Applied Analysis 11 (a) Since det J T (E 2 )>0and tr J T (E 2 )>0theequilibrium E 2 is a saddle point if and only if 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 ) < 0. If A 1 1 it is obvious that 1+ det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 )<0.Assume that A 1 <1.Then 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 )<0if and only if C 1 > 2(1 A 1)C 2 1 4A 2 C 2 4A 2 C 2 1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 = 1)( 1 4A 2 C 2 +1) from which the proof of the statement follows. (63) (b) Since det J T (E 2 ) > 0 and tr J T (E 2 ) > 0 the equilibrium E 2 is repeller if and only if 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 )>0and 1 det J T (E 2 )<0.The proof of the statement follows from the facts 1 det J T (E 2 )<0 C 1 < 2C 2 ( 1 4A 2 C 2 A 1 +1) 1 1 4A 2 C 2 2(1 A 1 )C 2 1 4A 2 C 2 4A 2 C 2 1+ 1 4A 2 C 2 2C 2 ( 1 4A 2 C 2 A 1 +1) 1 1 4A 2 C 2 = 4A 2C 2 + 1 4A 2 C 2 +1 <0. (64) (c) Since det J T (E 2 )>0and tr J T (E 2 )>0theequilibrium E 2 is nonhyperbolic if and only if 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 ) = 0 or det J T (E 2 ) = 1 and tr J T (E 2 ) 2. From the proof of the statements (a) and (b) if Δ 1 =0 or Δ 1 >0 A 1 <1 C 1 = 1)( 1 4A 2 C 2 +1) (65) we obtain 1+det J T (E 2 ) tr J T (E 2 )=0.Now assume that Δ 1 >0and det J T (E 2 )=1 C 1 = 2C 2 ( 1 4A 2 C 2 A 1 +1) 1 1 4A 2 C 2. (66) This implies tr J T (E 2 ) 2 = (1 4A 2 C 2 )/ ( 1 4A 2 C 2 +1) > 0.The rest of the proof follows fromthefactthatifδ 1 =0then 1 0 J T (E 2 )=( A 1 + C 1 ) (67) 0 1 and if (57) holds then J T (E 2 )=( 1 0 ). (68) 0 1 4A 2 C 2 +1 Lemma 18. Assume that Δ 1 0. The following statements are true: (a) E 3 is locally asymptotically stable if Δ 1 >0andA 1 1 or A 1 <1and C 1 >(1 A 1 )(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/. (b) E 3 is a saddle point if Δ 1 > 0andA 1 < 1 C 1 < 1 )(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/. (c) E 3 is a nonhyperbolic equilibrium point if Δ 1 =0or Δ 1 >0 A 1 <1 C 1 = 1)(1 1 4A 2 C 2 ). (69) If Δ 1 =0then the eigenvalues of J T (E 3 ) are given by λ 1 =1 1 (70) λ 2 = C 1 +A 1 with corresponding eigenvectors k 1 = (0 1) T k 2 =( 2A T (71) 2C 1 +A 1 1 B 2 ( C 1 +A 1 ) 1). If (57) holds then the eigenvalues of J T (E 3 ) are given by λ 1 =1 (72) λ 2 =1 1 4A 2 C 2 <1 with corresponding eigenvectors k 1 =( 1 4A T 2C 2 1) B 2 (73) k 2 = (0 1) T. Proof. Sincetheproofofthislemmaissimilartotheproofof Lemma 17 it is omitted. We summarize results about local stability in the following theorem. Theorem 19. Let A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 C 1 andc 2 be positive real numbers. Then local stability of the equilibrium points for different parameter regions is given by Table 2. Proof. The proof follows from Theorem 8 and Lemmas 17 and 18. Figure 2 illustrates visually local stability of all equilibrium points of system (1).

12 Abstract and Applied Analysis Table2:Thelocalstabilityoftheequilibriumpoints. Case The local stability Parameter region (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) Saddle: E 1 E 3 E 5 ;LAS:E 4 E 6 ; repeller: E 2 Saddle: E 1 E 3 ;LAS:E 4 ; nonhyperbolic: E 5 =E 6 ; repeller: E 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 <C 2 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = Saddle: E 1 E 5 ;LAS:E 3 E 4 ; repeller: E 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 Saddle: E 1 E 3 ;LAS:E 4 ; repeller: E 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 > (v) Saddle: E 1 E 2 ;LAS:E 3 E 4 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 A 1 or A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 2A 1 > 2 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x) Saddle: E 1 E 5 ;LAS:E 4 ; repeller: E 2 Nonhyperbolic: E 3 =E 6 ; Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 4 ;repeller: E 2 Nonhyperbolic: E 3 =E 5 =E 6 ; A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 = A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 C 1 )B 2 + B 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 1 ) 2 Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 4 ;repeller: 1 A E 2 A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 >C 2A 1 > C Nonhyperbolic: E 3 =E 2 1 )B 2 + B 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 1 ) 2 5 1 A A Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 3 E 4 ; 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 nonhyperbolic: E 2 =E 5 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 4 ; A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 = 1 A 1 C nonhyperbolic: E 2 =E 3 =E 5 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 2 1 ) 2 (xi) Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 4 ; nonhyperbolic: E 2 =E 3 A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 = 1 A 1 (xii) Saddle: E 1 ;LAS:E 4 A 1 <1 Δ 1 <0 (xiii) Saddle: E 2 ;LAS:E 3 ; nonhyperbolic: E 1 =E 4 A 1 =1 Δ 1 >0 (xiv) Nonhyperbolic: E 1 =E 4 E 2 =E 3 A 1 =1 Δ 1 =0 (xv) Nonhyperbolic: E 1 =E 4 A 1 =1 Δ 1 <0 (xvi) Saddle: E 1 E 3 ;LAS:E 2 ; A 1 >1 Δ 1 >0 (xvii) LAS: E 1 ; nonhyperbolic: E 2 =E 3 A 1 >1 Δ 1 =0 (xviii) LAS: E 1 A 1 >1 Δ 1 <0

Abstract and Applied Analysis 13 (i) A 1 <1 R 31 풞 12 R 1 풞 11 풞 3 풫 1 C 2 (ii) A 1 =1 R 21 R 25 풞 32 풞 22 R 32 C 2 풫 2 C 1 R 23 R 41 풞 31 R 24 R 22 풞 23 C 2 R 42 풞 4 (iii) A 1 >1 풞 21 C 1 C 1 Figure 2: Equilibria in different parameter regions for the number of equilibria of system (1) when A 1 A 2 B 1 andb 2 arefixedpositivereal numbers as given by Proposition 11. Each circle in the parameters (C 1 C 2 )-plane indicates the existence of an isolated equilibrium point of system (1) in the nonnegative quadrant of the xy-plane. Local stability character of equilibria as given in Theorem 19 is indicated as follows: locally asymptotically stable equilibrium; saddle; repelling equilibrium point: two-colored circle semistable nonhyperbolic equilibrium. 5. Injectivity and Convergence to Equilibrium Points In this section we prove some global properties of the map T such as injectivity and (O+) propertyandgiveglobalbehavior on the coordinate axes. Lemma 20. The map T is injective. Proof. Assume that T(x 1 y 1 )=T(x 2 y 2 ). Then we have Equation (74) is equivalent to A 1 x 1 A 1 x 2 C 1 x 2 y 1 +C 1 x 1 y 2 =0 (75) A 2 y 2 1 +B 2 x 2 y 2 1 A 2 y 2 2 B 2 x 1 y 2 2 =0. (76) Equation (75) implies A ( 1 x 1 A 1 x 2 C 1 x 2 y 1 +C 1 x 1 y 2 (A 1 +B 1 x 1 +C 1 y 1 )(A 1 +B 1 x 2 +C 1 y 2 ) A 2 y 1 2 +B 2 x 2 y 1 2 A 2 y 2 2 B 2 x 1 y 2 2 (A 2 +B 2 x 1 +C 2 y 1 2 )(A 2 +B 2 x 2 +C 2 y 2 2 ) ) = (0 0). (74) By substituting this into (76) we obtain x 1 = A 1x 2 +C 1 x 2 y 1 A 1 +C 1 y 2. (77) (y 1 y 2 )(A 1 A 2 y 1 +A 1 B 2 x 2 y 1 +A 1 A 2 y 2 +A 1 B 2 x 2 y 2 +A 2 C 1 y 1 y 2 +B 2 C 1 x 2 y 1 y 2 +A 2 C 1 y 2 2 ) A 1 +C 1 y 2 =0 (78) from which it follows that y 1 =y 2.From(77)wehavex 1 = x 2 which complete the proof. The global behavior of T on the coordinate axes is described with the following result. Lemma 21. The following statements hold: (i) If Δ 1 0 and (x n y n ) = T n (0 y 0 ) then x n = 0 and (x n y n ) E 3 for y 0 ((1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/ 2C 2 ) and (x n y n ) E 1 for y 0 (0 (1 + 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 ). (ii) If Δ 1 <0and (x n y n )=T n (0 y 0 ) then x n =0and (x n y n ) E 1 for y 0 (0 ). (iii) If A 1 <1and (x n y n )=Tn (x 0 0) then y n =0and (x n y n ) E 4 for x 0 (0 ). (iv) If A 1 1and (x n y n )=Tn (x 0 0) then y n =0and (x n y n ) E 1 for x 0 (0 ). (v) T([0 ) [0 )) [0 1/B 1 ] [01/C 2 ].

14 Abstract and Applied Analysis Proof. (i) From (11) it is easy to see that if x 0 =0then x n =0for n>0.since T(0y 0 ) (0y 0 )=(0 y 0 (C 2 y 2 0 y 0 +A 2 ) A 2 +C 2 y0 2 ) (79) we obtain that (0 y 0 ) se T(0y 0 ) for y 0 (0 1 1 4A 2C 2 ) ( 1+ 1 4A 2C 2 ) 2C 2 2C 2 (80) T(0y 0 ) se (0 y 0 ) for y 0 ( 1 1 4A 2C 2 2C 2 1+ 1 4A 2C 2 2C 2 ). Take y 0 > (1 + 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2. Then T n (0 y 0 ) se T n+1 (0 y 0 ) se E 3. Since T n (0 y 0 ) se E 3 se E 2 se E 1 we obtain T n (0 y 0 ) E 3 as n. Similarly if y 0 ((1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 (1 + 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 ) then E 3 se T n+1 (0 y 0 ) se T n (0 y 0 ) se E 2 se E 1 which implies T n (0 y 0 ) E 3 as n. If y 0 < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/2C 2 then E 3 se E 2 se T n (0 y 0 ) se T n+1 (0 y 0 ) se E 1 which implies T n (0 y 0 ) E 1 as n. (ii) If Δ 1 < 0 then T has only equilibrium E 1 on yaxis and T(0 y 0 ) se (0 y 0 ) for all y 0 0.Since T is monotone map we get T n (0 y 0 ) se T n+1 (0 y 0 ) se E 1 which implies T n (0 y 0 ) E 1 as n from which the proof follows. (iii) The proof of the statements (iii) and (iv) is similar to the proof of statements (i) and (ii) and follows from the fact that T(x 0 0) (x 0 0)=( x 0 (A 1 +B 1 x 0 1) 0) (81) A 1 +B 1 x 0 and will be omitted. (v) The proof follows from the facts that f(x y) 1/B 1 and g(x y) 1/C 2. Lemma 22. Let M(t) (t 1 B 1 t)/c 1 ).ThenM(x 6 )= E 6 M(x 5 )=E 5 andm(x 4 )=E 4 and the following hold: (i) If Δ 2 0 then M(t) se T(M(t)) for t (0x 6 ) (x 5 x 4 ) and T(M(t)) se M(t) for t (x 6 x 5 ). (ii) If Δ 2 <0then M(t) se T(M(t)) for t (0x 4 ) and T(M(t)) se M(t) for t (x 6 x 5 ). Proof. The proof follows from the fact T (M (t)) M(t) (A =(0 1 +B 1 t 1) g (x) C1 3 (A 2 +B 2 t) + C 2 C 1 (A 1 +B 1 t 1) 2 ) (82) where g(x) is given by (17) and g(x 5 )= g(x 6 )=0and x 4 = 1 )/B 1. Theorem 23. Every solution of system (1) converges to an equilibrium point. Proof. The map T associated with the system is injective. Relation (42) implies that determinant of Jacobian (41) is positive for all x [0 ) [0 ). By using Lemma 20 we have that condition (O+) of Theorem 3 is satisfied for the map T (T is competitive). Theorem 2 implies that T n (x) is eventually componentwise monotone for all x [0 ) 2.The statement (v) of Lemma 21 implies that every solution enters in compact set [0 1/B 1 ] [01/C 2 ] from which the proof follows. Remark 24. In view of Theorem 23 the main objective in determining the global dynamics of system (1) is to characterize the basins of attractions of all equilibrium points. As wewillseeintheorem25theboundariesofthesebasins of attractions will be the global stable manifolds of the saddle or nonhyperbolic equilibrium points whose existence is guaranteed by Theorems 7 8 and 9. 6. Global Behavior In this section we give results which precisely describe global dynamics of system (1) including precise characterization of basins of attraction of different equilibrium points. The main result of this paper is the following. Theorem 25. The global behavior of system (1) is given by Table 3. See Figure 3 for visual illustration of dynamic scenarios. Proof. We will prove statements (i) (x) listed in the second column of Table 3 in the given order. The proof of other statements is similar. Let R = [0 ) [0 ). (i) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) R 24.ByProposition11inQ 1 (0 0) there exist six equilibria E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 E 5 and E 6.ByTheorem19equilibriaE 4 and E 5 are locally asymptotically stable; E 3 E 4 ande 5 are the saddle points and E 2 is repeller. In view of (41) the map T is competitive on R and strongly competitive on int(r). It follows from the Perron-Frobenius Theorem and a change of variables [16] that at each point thejacobianmatrixofastronglycompetitivemaphas two real and distinct eigenvalues the larger one in absolute value being positive and that corresponding eigenvectors may be chosen to point in the direction of the second and first quadrant respectively. Also one can show that if the map is strongly competitive then no eigenvector is aligned with a coordinate axis. Hence all conditions of Theorems 7 8 and 9 are satisfied which yields the existence of the global stable manifold W s (E 5 )withendpointatpointe 2 whichis graph of an increasing function. Let W ={(xy) (x y) se ( x 0 y 0 ) for some ( x 0 y 0 ) W s (E 5 )} and W + = {(x y) ( x 1 y 1 ) se (x y) for some ( x 1 y 1 ) W s (E 5 )}. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have W s (E 1 ) = {(0y) : 0

Abstract and Applied Analysis 15 Table 3: The global behavior of system (1). Case Parameter region Global behavior (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) R 24 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 < C 31 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = R 22 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 < C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 R 21 R 25 C 32 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 > or A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 1 A 1 >C 2A 1 > 2 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 < R 23 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 > 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) <C 1 ) 2 2 < C 21 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 < 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 P 2 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 1 = 1 )B 2 + B 1 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 There exist six equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 E 5 ande 6 wheree 4 and E 5 are locally asymptotically stable E 3 E 4 ande 6 are saddle points and E 2 is repeller. The stable manifold W s (E 6 ) of the saddle point E 6 is an increasing separatrix with endpoint at E 2 and solutions with initial point above the W s (E 6 ) converge to E 5 while solutions with initial point below the W s (E 6 ) converge to E 4. All orbits that start on W s (E 6 ) are attracted to E 6. The basins of attraction of E 1 and E 3 are respectively B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and B(E 3 ) = {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} There exist five equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 ande 5 =E 6 where E 4 is locally asymptotically stable E 1 and E 3 are saddle points E 2 is repeller and E 5 =E 6 is nonhyperbolic. There exists a continuous increasing curve C with endpoint at E 2 which is a subset of the basin of attraction of E 5 =E 6. All solutions with initial point above C converge to E 5 =E 6 while solutions with initial point below C converge to E 4. The basins of attraction of E 1 and E 3 are respectively B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and B(E 3 ) = {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} There exist five equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 ande 5 wheree 3 and E 4 are locally asymptotically stable E 1 and E 5 are saddle points and E 2 is repeller. The stable manifold W s (E 5 ) of the saddle point E 5 is an increasing separatrix with endpoint at E 2 and solutions with initial point above W s (E 5 ) converge to E 3 while solutions with initial point below W s (E 5 ) converge to E 4.AllorbitsthatstartonW s (E 5 ) are attracted to E 5. The basin of attraction of E 1 is B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} There exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 ande 4 wheree 4 is globally asymptotically stable E 1 and E 3 are saddle points and E 2 is a repeller. The basins of attraction of E 1 E 3 ande 4 are respectively B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} B(E 3 ) = {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}and B(E 4 ) = (0 ) [0 ). There exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 ande 4 wheree 3 and E 4 are locally asymptotically stable and E 1 and E 2 are saddle points. The stable manifold W s (E 2 ) of the saddle point E 2 is an increasing separatrix and solutions with initial point above W s (E 1 ) converge to E 3 while solutions with initial point below W s (E 2 ) converge to E 4. All orbits that start on W s (E 2 ) are attracted to E 2. Thebasinofattraction of E 1 is given by B(E 1 )={(0y):0 y<(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. There exist five equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 6 E 4 ande 5 where E 4 is locally asymptotically stable E 1 and E 5 are saddle points E 3 =E 6 is nonhyperbolic and E 2 is a repeller. The stable manifold W s (E 5 ) of the saddle point E 5 is an increasing separatrix with endpoint at E 2 and solutions with initial point above W s (E 5 ) converge to E 3 =E 6 while solutions with initial point below W s (E 5 ) converge to E 4. All orbits that start on W s (E 5 ) are attracted to E 5. The basinofattractionofe 1 is given by B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. There exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 5 =E 6 ande 4 where E 4 is locally asymptotically stable E 1 is a saddle point E 3 =E 5 =E 6 is nonhyperbolic and E 2 is a repeller. There exists a strictly increasing curve C with endpoint at E 3 =E 5 =E 6 which is thesubsetofthebasinofattractionofe 3 =E 5 =E 6. All solutions with initial point above C converge to E 3 =E 5 =E 6 while solutions with initial point below C converge to E 4. The basin of attraction of E 1 is given by B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}.

16 Abstract and Applied Analysis Table 3: Continued. Case Parameter region Global behavior (viii) C 22 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 ) 2 1 A 1 >C 2A 1 > 2 1 )B 2 + B 1 There exist five equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 =E 5 ande 4 wheree 4 is locally asymptotically stable E 1 is a saddle point E 3 =E 5 is nonhyperbolic and E 2 is a repeller. The basins of attraction of E 1 and E 3 are given by B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and B(E 3 ) = {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and the basin of attraction of E 4 is B(E 4 ) = {(x y) : x > 0 y 0}. (ix) C 23 :A 1 <1 Δ 1 >0 C 2 = C 1 1 A 2 C 1 ) 1 A 1 <C 1 ) 2 2A 1 2 (x) A 1 <1 Δ 1 =0 C 1 = 1 A 1 (xi) A 1 <1 Δ 1 <0 (xii) A 1 =1 Δ 1 >0 (xiii) A 1 =1 Δ 1 =0 (xiv) A 1 =1 Δ 1 <0 (xv) A 1 >1 Δ 1 >0 (xvi) A 1 >1 Δ 1 <0 (xvii) A 1 >1 Δ 1 =0 There exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 3 E 2 =E 5 ande 4 wheree 3 and E 4 are locally asymptotically stable E 1 is a saddle point and E 2 =E 5 is nonhyperbolic. There exist continuous increasing curves C 1 and C 2 with endpoint at E 2 =E 5 which are the subsets of the basinofattractionofe 2 =E 5. Further all solutions with initial point above C 2 converge to E 3 and all solutions with initial point above C 1 and below C 2 converge to E 2 while solutions with initial point below C 1 converge to E 4. The basin of attraction of E 1 is B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. There exist three equilibrium points E 1 E 2 =E 3 ande 4 wheree 4 is locally asymptotically stable E 1 is a saddle point and E 2 =E 3 is nonhyperbolic. There exists a continuous increasing curve C with endpoint at E 2 =E 3 which is a subset of the basin of attraction of E 2 =E 3. All solutions with initial point above C converge to E 2 =E 3 while solutions with initial point below C converge to E 4. The basin of attraction of E 1 is given by B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. There exist two equilibrium points E 1 which is a saddle point and E 4 which is globally asymptotically stable where B(E 4 ) = (0 ) [0 ) and B(E 1 )={(0y):y 0}. There exist three equilibrium points E 1 =E 4 E 2 ande 3 where E 1 =E 4 is nonhyperbolic E 3 is locally asymptotically stable and E 2 is asaddlepoint.thestablemanifoldw s (E 2 ) ofthesaddlepointe 2 is an increasing separatrix with endpoint at E 2 and solutions with initial point above W s (E 2 ) converge to E 3 while solutions with initial point below W s (E 2 ) converge to E 4. All orbits that start on W s (E 2 ) are attracted to E 2. ThebasinofattractionofE 1 is given by B(E 1 ) = {(0 y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. There exist two equilibrium points E 1 =E 4 and E 2 =E 3 which are nonhyperbolic. There exists a continuous increasing curve C with endpoint at E 2 =E 3 which is a subset of the basin of attraction of E 2 =E 3. All solutions with initial point above C converge to E 2 =E 3 while solutions with initial point below C converge to E 1 =E 4. There exists one equilibrium point E 1 =E 4 which is nonhyperbolic and global attractor. The basin of attraction of E 1 is B(E 1 ) = [0 ) [0 ) There exist three equilibrium points E 1 E 2 ande 3 wheree 1 and E 3 are locally asymptotically stable and E 2 isasaddlepoint.thestable manifold W s (E 2 ) of the saddle point E 2 is an increasing separatrix with endpoint at E 2 and solutions with initial point above W s (E 2 ) converge to E 3 while solutions with initial point below W s (E 2 ) converge to E 1. All orbits that start on W s (E 2 ) are attracted to E 2. There exists one equilibrium point E 1 which is globally asymptotically stable. The basin of attraction of E 1 is B(E 1 ) = [0 ) [0 ) There exist two equilibrium points E 1 and E 2 =E 3 wheree 1 is locally asymptotically stable and E 2 =E 3 is nonhyperbolic. There exists a continuous increasing curve C with endpoint at E 2 =E 3 which is a subset of the basin of attraction of E 2 =E 3. All solutions with initial point above C converge to E 2 =E 3 while solutions with initial point below C converge to E 1.

Abstract and Applied Analysis 17 E 3 =E 5 E 2 E 3 E 1 (viii) E 4 E 1 (xii) E 4 R 1 E 2 =E 3 E 2 12 32 R 25 1 11 E 1 (iv) E 4 R 21 22 R 23 E 1 (xi) E4 E 3 E 5 =E 6 C 2 31 2 R 22 23 E 3 R 24 s E 2 E 2 21 E 1 (ii) E 4 C 1 E 1 (v) E 4 E 3 E 6 E 3 E 3 =E 6 E 2 E 5 s E s E 5 5 E E 2 2 s (E 5 ) E 2 =E 5 2 1 E 1 E4 E 1 E E4 1 E E 1 E 4 4 (i) (vi) (iii) (ix) (i) A 1 <1 Figure 3: Parameter regions in terms of parameters C 1 and C 2 and corresponding dynamic scenarios for system (1) if A 1 <1. y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and W s (E 3 ) = {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. Take (x 0 y 0 ) W int(q 1 (0 0)). ByTheorem8and Lemma 21 we have that there exists n 0 > 0 such that T n (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 3 ) Q 2 (E 5 )) n > n 0. In view of Corollary 4 [[E 1 E 6 ]] B(E 6 ) and [[E 6 E 5 ]] B(E 6 ). Since T is competitive this implies int(q 4 (E 3 ) Q 2 (E 5 )) = [[E 1 E 5 ]] B(E 6 ). Take (x 0 y 0 ) W + int(q 1 (0 0)). By Theorem 8 and Lemma 21 we have that there exists n 0 >0such that T n (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 5 ) Q 2 (E 4 )) n>n 0.Since T is competitive in view of Corollary 4 int(q 4 (E 5 ) Q 2 (E 4 )) = [[E 5 E 4 ]] B(E 4 ).Thiscompletesthe proof of statement (i). (ii) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) C 31. By Proposition 11 in Q 1 (0 0) there exist five equilibria E 1 E 2 E 3 E 4 ande 5 =E 6. By Theorem 19 E 1 and E 3 are the saddle points E 2 is repeller and E 5 =E 6 is nonhyperbolic. Similarly as in the proof of the statement (i) all conditions of Theorems 7 8 and 9 are satisfied which yields the existence of the invariant curve C with one endpoint at E 2 and which is passing through E 5 =E 6 anditis graph of an increasing function. Let W ={(xy) (x y) se ( x 0 y 0 ) for some ( x 0 y 0 ) C} and W + = {(x y) ( x 1 y 1 ) se (x y) for some ( x 1 y 1 ) C}. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have W s (E 1 ) = {(0y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and W s (E 3 ) = {(0y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. Take (x 0 y 0 ) W int(q 1 (0 0)). By Theorem 8 we have that there exists n 0 >0such that T n (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 3 ) Q 2 (E 5 = E 6 )) n > n 0. In view of Corollary 4 int(q 4 (E 3 ) Q 2 (E 5 = E 6 )) = [[E 1 E 5 = E 6 ]] B(E 5 = E 6 ). Take (x 0 y 0 ) W + int(q 1 (0 0)). ByTheorem8 and Lemma 21 we have that there exists n 0 >0such that T n (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 5 ) Q 2 (E 4 )) n>n 0.Since

18 Abstract and Applied Analysis T is competitive in view of Corollary 4 int(q 4 (E 5 ) Q 2 (E 4 )) = [[E 5 E 4 ]] B(E 4 ).Thiscompletesthe proof of statement (ii) (iii) The proof is similar to the proof of case (i) and we skip it. (iv) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) R 21 R 25 C 32. By Proposition 11 in Q 1 (0 0) there exist four equilibria E 1 E 2 E 3 ande 4.ByTheorem19E 1 and E 3 are saddle points; E 2 is repeller; E 4 is locally asymptotically stable. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have B(E 1 )=W s (E 1 )={(0y): 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and B(E 3 ) = W s (E 3 )={(0y):y>(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. Since by Theorem 23 every solution of system (1) converges to an equilibrium point we have that B(E 4 ) = (0 ) [0 ). (v) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) R 23. By Proposition 11 in Q 1 (0 0) there exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 2 E 3 ande 4. By Theorem 19 E 1 and E 2 are the saddle points; E 3 and E 4 are locally asymptotically stable. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have B(E 1 ) = W s (E 1 ) = {(0y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and{(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} B(E 3 ) and {(x0):x>0} B(E 4 ). Similarly as in the proof of case (i) all conditions of Theorems 7 8 and 9 are satisfied which yields the existence of the global stable manifold W s (E 2 ) which is a graph of an increasing function. The rest of the proof follows from the facts that W ={(xy) (x y) se ( x 0 y 0 ) for some ( x 0 y 0 ) W s (E 2 )} and W + = {(x y) ( x 1 y 1 ) se (x y) for some ( x 1 y 1 ) W s (E 2 )} are invariant sets E 4 W E 3 W + uniqueness of the global stable manifold W s (E 2 ) and Theorem 23. (vi) The proof is similar to the proof of case (i) and we skip it. (vii) The proof is the same as the proof of case (viii) and we skip it. (viii) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) C 22. By Proposition 11 in Q 1 (0 0) there exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 3 = E 5 E 2 ande 4.ByTheorem19wehavethatE 4 is locally asymptotically stable; E 1 is a saddle point; E 3 = E 5 is nonhyperbolic; and E 2 is repeller. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have B(E 1 ) = W s (E 1 ) = {(0y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. Inviewof Lemma 18 for E 3 =E 5 we have that the eigenspace E λ 2 associated with λ 2 is a coordinate axis so we can not use Theorem 6. By Lemma 21 we obtain {(0 y) : y > (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} B(E 3 = E 5 ). Similarly as in the proof of Theorem 8 (see [1] for more details) one can prove that for every x int(q 1 (E 3 )) there exists n 0 N such that T n (x) int(q 4 (E 3 )) for n n 0.ByLemmas21 and 22 for (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 3 )) there exists t 0 and t 0 such that E 3 se M(t 0 ) se (x 0 y 0 ) se (t 0 0).Since E 3 se T n (M(t 0 )) se T n+1 (M(t 0 )) E 4 we have that T n (M(t 0 )) E 4. Since T n (t 0 0) E 4 we obtain T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 4. This implies int(q 4 (E 3 )) B(E 4 ) which completes the proof. (ix) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) C 23. By Proposition 11 there exist four equilibrium points E 1 E 2 = E 5 E 3 and E 4.ByTheorem19wehavethatE 3 and E 4 are locally asymptotically stable; E 1 is a saddle point; E 2 =E 5 is nonhyperbolic. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have B(E 1 )=W s (E 1 )= {(0y):0 y<(1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. Inview of Lemma 18 for E 3 wehavethatλ 1 =1and λ 2 >1 so we can not use Theorem 6. By Lemmas 21 and 22 for (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 3 )) there exists t 0 and t 0 such that E 3 se M(t 0 ) se (x 0 y 0 ) se (t 0 0). Since E 3 se T n (M(t 0 )) se T n+1 (M(t 0 )) E 4 we have that T n (M(t 0 )) E 4.SinceT n (t 0 0) E 4 we obtain T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 4. This implies int(q 4 (E 3 )) B(E 4 ). Let C 1 denote the boundary of B(E 4 ) considered as a subset of int(q 1 (E 2 )) and let C 2 denote the boundary of B(E 3 ) considered as a subset of int(q 1 (E 2 )). It is easy to see by using Lemmas 21 and 22 that E 2 C 1 C 2. Since T(int(R)) int(r) following the proof of Claims 1 and 2 [20] one can see that T(C i ) C i and T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 2 C i for (x 0 y 0 ) C i for i=12.furtherc i are graphs of the continuous strictly increasing functions. If (x 0 y 0 ) is point above the curve C 1 and below the curve C 2 then there exists (x 0 y 0 ) C 1 and (x 0 y 0 ) C 2 such that (x 0 y 0 ) se (x 0 y 0 ) se (x 0 y 0 ). Since T n (x 0 y 0 ) se T n (x 0 y 0 ) se T n (x 0 y 0 ) and T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 2 and T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 2 as n we have T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 2 as n. (x) Suppose (C 1 C 2 ) C 23. By Proposition 11 in Q 1 (0 0) there exist three equilibrium points E 1 E 2 = E 3 and E 4.ByTheorem19E 2 = E 3 is nonhyperbolic E 1 is a saddle point and E 4 is locally asymptotically stable. By Lemma 21 and uniqueness of the global stable manifold we have B(E 1 )=W s (E 1 )={(0y): 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )}. In view of Lemma 18 we have that λ 1 =1and λ 2 <1if C 1 > 1 )/( ) and λ 2 >1if C 1 <(1 A 1 )/( ) so we can use Theorem 6 if C 1 >(1 A 1 )/( ).In this case there exists strictly increasing curve C with endpoint at E 2 = E 3. The rest of the proof follows from Theorems 7 8 and 9 and Lemma 21. Now we assume that C 1 < 1 )/( ).ByLemmas21 and 22 for (x 0 y 0 ) int(q 4 (E 3 )) there exists t 0 and t 0 such that E 3 se M(t 0 ) se (x 0 y 0 ) se (t 0 0).Since E 3 se T n (M(t 0 )) se T n+1 (M(t 0 )) E 4 we have that T n (M(t 0 )) E 4.SinceT n (t 0 0) E 4 we obtain T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 4. This implies int(q 4 (E 3 )) B(E 4 ). Let C denote the boundary of B(E 4 ) considered as asubsetofq 1 (E 3 ). It is easy to see by using Lemmas 21 and 22 that E 3 C. SinceT(int(R)) int(r) following the proof of Claims 1 and 2 [20] one can see that T(C) C. Further C is graph of strictly

Abstract and Applied Analysis 19 increasing function. By Theorem 23 if (x 0 y 0 ) C then T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 3 C. If (x 0 y 0 ) is point above the curve C then there exists (x 0 y 0 ) and y 0 > y 3 such that (0 y 0 ) se (x 0 y) se (x 0 y 0 ). Since T n (0 y 0 ) se T n (x 0 y 0 ) se T n (x 0 y 0 ) Tn (0 y 0 ) E 3 andt n (x 0 y 0 ) E 3 as n we have T n (x 0 y 0 ) E 3 as n. Based on a series of numerical simulations we propose the following conjectures. Conjecture 26. Suppose that all assumptions of the statement (ix) of Theorem 25 are satisfied; then the following holds: B (E 2 )=C 1 = C 2. (83) Conjecture 27. Assume that C 1 C 2 P 1. There exist three equilibrium points E 1 E 3 = E 2 = E 5 ande 4 wheree 4 is locally asymptotically stable; E 1 is a saddle point; and E 3 = E 2 =E 5 is nonhyperbolic. The basins of attraction of E 1 and E 3 = E 2 = E 5 are given by B(E 1 ) = {(0y) : 0 y < (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} and B(E 3 )={(0y):y> (1 1 4A 2 C 2 )/( )} andthebasinofattractionofe 4 is B(E 4 )={(xy):x>0 y 0}. Conflicts of Interest The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper. References [1] M. R. Kulenović and O. Merino Invariant manifolds for competitive discrete systems in the plane International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos in Applied Sciences and Engineering vol. 20 no. 8 pp. 2471 2486 2010. [2] J. M. Cushing S. Levarge N. Chitnis and S. M. Henson Some discrete competition models and the competitive exclusion principle Journal of Difference Equations and Applicationsvol. 10 no. 13 15 pp. 1139 1151 2004. [3] M. R.Kulenović and O. Merino Competitive-exclusion versus competitive-coexistence for systems in the plane Discrete and Continuous Dynamical Systems. Series B. A Journal Bridging Mathematics and Sciencesvol.6no.5pp.1141 11562006. [4] A. Brett and M. R. Kulenovic Two species competitive model with the Allee effect Advances in Difference Equations vol. 2014 article 307 2014. [5]A.BrettandM.R.Kulenović Basins of attraction for twospecies competitive model with quadratic terms and the singular Allee effect Discrete Dynamics in Nature and SocietyArticle ID 847360 16 pages 2015. [6] D. Burgić M. R. Kulenović and M. Nurkanović Global dynamics of a rational system of difference equations in the plane Communications on Applied Nonlinear Analysis vol.15 no. 1 pp. 71 84 2008. [7] D. Clark and M. R. Kulenović A coupled system of rational difference equations Computers & Mathematics with Applicationsvol.43no.6-7pp.849 8672002. [8] J.E.FrankeandA.-A.Yakubu Mutualexclusionversuscoexistence for discrete competitive systems Journal of Mathematical Biologyvol.30no.2pp.161 1681991. [9] J. E. Franke and A.-A. Yakubu Geometry of exclusion principles in discrete systems Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applicationsvol.168no.2pp.385 4001992. [10] M. W. Hirsch and H. Smith Chapter 4 Monotone Dynamical Systems Handbook of Differential Equations: Ordinary Differential Equationsvol.2pp.239 3572006. [11] S. Kalabušić M. R. Kulenović and E. Pilav Multiple attractors for a competitive system of rational difference equations in the plane Abstract and Applied Analysis vol.2011articleid 295308 35 pages 2011. [12] R. M. May and W. J. Leonard Nonlinear aspects of competition between three species SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics vol. 29 no. 2 pp. 243 253 1975. [13] H. L. Smith Invariant curves for mappings SIAM Journal on Mathematical Analysisvol.17no.5pp.1053 10671986. [14] H. L. Smith Periodic competitive differential equations and the discrete dynamics of competitive maps Journal of Differential Equationsvol.64no.2pp.165 1941986. [15] H. L. Smith Periodic solutions of periodic competitive and cooperative systems SIAMJournalonMathematicalAnalysis vol. 17 no. 6 pp. 1289 1318 1986. [16] H. L. Smith Planar competitive and cooperative difference equations Journal of Difference Equations and Applicationsvol. 3 no. 5-6 pp. 335 357 1998. [17] P. de Mottoni and A. Schiaffino Competition systems with periodic coefficients: a geometric approach Journal of Mathematical Biology vol. 11 no. 3 pp. 319 335 1981. [18] P. Hess Periodic-Parabolic Boundary Value Problems and Positivity vol.247ofpitman Research Notes in Mathematics Series Longman Scientific & Technical Harlow UK 1991. [19] S. Basu and O. Merino On the global behavior of solutions to a planar system of difference equations Communications on Applied Nonlinear Analysisvol.16no.1pp.89 1012009. [20] V. Hadžiabdić M. R. Kulenović and E. Pilav Dynamics of a two-dimensional competitive system of rational difference equations with quadratic terms Advances in Difference Equationsvol.301p.322014.

Advances in Operations Research Advances in Decision Sciences Journal of Applied Mathematics Algebra Journal of Probability and Statistics The Scientific World Journal International Journal of Differential Equations Submit your manuscripts at https://www.hindawi.com International Journal of Advances in Combinatorics Mathematical Physics Journal of Complex Analysis International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences Mathematical Problems in Engineering Journal of Mathematics #HRBQDSDĮ@SGDL@SHBR Journal of Volume 201 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Journal of Function Spaces Abstract and Applied Analysis International Journal of Journal of Stochastic Analysis Optimization