Problem Set 2 Solutions

Similar documents
The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

Midterm Exam - Solutions

The Necessity of the Transversality Condition at Infinity: A (Very) Special Case

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES

Constrained Optimization

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Modern Optimization Theory: Concave Programming

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

The Inconsistent Neoclassical Theory of the Firm and Its Remedy

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Constrained maxima and Lagrangean saddlepoints

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Nonlinear Programming and the Kuhn-Tucker Conditions

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Homework 3 Suggested Answers

In view of (31), the second of these is equal to the identity I on E m, while this, in view of (30), implies that the first can be written

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

ECONOMETRIC THEORY. MODULE VI Lecture 19 Regression Analysis Under Linear Restrictions

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

Finite Dimensional Optimization Part I: The KKT Theorem 1

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

First Welfare Theorem

Mathematical Preliminaries

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Econ 508-A FINITE DIMENSIONAL OPTIMIZATION - NECESSARY CONDITIONS. Carmen Astorne-Figari Washington University in St. Louis.

Problem Set 9 Solutions. (a) Using the guess that the value function for this problem depends only on y t and not ε t and takes the specific form

Solutions. F x = 2x 3λ = 0 F y = 2y 5λ = 0. λ = 2x 3 = 2y 5 = x = 3y 5. 2y 1/3 z 1/6 x 1/2 = 5x1/2 z 1/6. 3y 2/3 = 10x1/2 y 1/3

Volume 30, Issue 3. Ramsey Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth: A Comment. Jenn-hong Tang Department of Economics, National Tsing-Hua University

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

ECONOMIC OPTIMALITY. Date: October 10, 2005.

1.3 The Indirect Utility Function

1.4 FOUNDATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION

The Real Business Cycle Model

Mathematical Foundations -1- Supporting hyperplanes. SUPPORTING HYPERPLANES Key Ideas: Bounding hyperplane for a convex set, supporting hyperplane

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Problem Set #5

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Mathematical Preliminaries for Microeconomics: Exercises

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2002

Consider this problem. A person s utility function depends on consumption and leisure. Of his market time (the complement to leisure), h t

Introductory Microeconomics

Aggregate Production Function. Production. Mark Huggett. Georgetown University. January 11, 2018

Constrained optimization.

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION. Contents

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

FIN 550 Practice Exam Answers. A. Linear programs typically have interior solutions.

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

ECON Answers Homework #4. = 0 6q q 2 = 0 q 3 9q = 0 q = 12. = 9q 2 108q AC(12) = 3(12) = 500

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Problem Set 3

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Proportional Response as Iterated Cobb-Douglas

Euler s Theorem for Homogeneous Functions

Modelling Production

a. This is an inequality constrained maximization problem. The Lagrangian is µ 1 q 1 = 0 µ 2 q 2 = 0 1 (q 1 ) φ φ c 2 (q 2) p 1 c 1(q 1 ) = 0

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Final Exam. Economics 720: Mathematics for Economists. Fall 1999

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

The Heckscher-Ohlin model: Mathematical treatment*

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Elasticities as differentials; the elasticity of substitution

Boston College. Math Review Session (2nd part) Lecture Notes August,2007. Nadezhda Karamcheva www2.bc.

Outline. Roadmap for the NPP segment: 1 Preliminaries: role of convexity. 2 Existence of a solution

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

CES functions and Dixit-Stiglitz Formulation

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

8.1. Prot maximization, cost minimization and function cost. December 12, The production function has decreasing returns to scale.

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981).

Transcription:

EC 720 - Math for Economists Samson Alva Department of Economics Boston College October 4 2011 1. Profit Maximization Problem Set 2 Solutions (a) The Lagrangian for this problem is L(y k l λ) = py rk wl λ(y k a l b ). (b) The NDCQ is satisfied since the constraint function g(k l) k a l b y has no maximum i.e. Dg 0 for any (k l). According to the Kuhn-Tucker theorem the values y k l that solve the firm s problem together with the associated value λ for the multiplier must satisfy the first-order conditions the constraint the nonnegativity condition L 1 (y k l λ ) = p λ = 0 L 2 (y k l λ ) = r + aλ (k ) a 1 (l ) b = 0 L 3 (y k l λ ) = w + bλ (k ) a (l ) b 1 = 0 L 4 (y k l λ ) = (k ) a (l ) b y 0 λ 0 the complementary slackness condition λ [(y k ) a (l ) b ] = 0. (c) The first-order condition for y reveals that λ > 0 whenever p > 0. Assuming that this is the case the complementary slackness condition requires the constraint to hold as an equality. Hence the first-order conditions can be used together with the binding constraint to solve for y k l λ in terms of the model s parameters a b p r w: y = k = ( (a ( (a r ) a ( b w r ) 1 b ( b w 1 ) b p a+b ) 1 1 a b ) b p) 1 1 a b

l = ( (a r ) a ( b w λ = p. ) 1 a p) 1 1 a b (d) The solutions from above imply that: i. The optimal y k l all rise when the output price p rises holding all other parameters fixed. ii. The optimal y k l all fall when the rental rate for capital r rises holding all other parameters fixed. iii. The optimal y k l all fall when the wage rate w rises holding all other parameters fixed. iv. The optimal y k l all remain unchanged when p r w all double at the same time. 2. Cobb-Douglas Utility Maximization (a) The Lagrangian for the consumer s problem is L(c 1 c 2 λ) = c a 1c 1 a 2 λ( c 1 + c 2 I). (b) The NDCQ is satisfied since we have a non-degenerate linear constraint. According to the Kuhn-Tucker theorem the values c 1 c 2 that solve the consumer s problem together with the associated value λ for the multiplier must satisfy the first-order conditions the constraint the nonnegativity condition L 1 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = a(c 1) a 1 (c 2) 1 a λ = 0 L 2 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = (1 a)(c 1) a (c 2) a λ = 0 L 3 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = I c 1 c 2 0 λ 0 the complementary slackness condition λ ( c 1 + c 2 I) = 0. (c) The first-order conditions for c 1 c 2 reveal that λ > 0 if the prices are both strictly positive a condition that must hold for the problem to have a well-defined solution in the first place. Assuming that this is the case the complementary slackness conditions requires the constraint to hold as an equality. Hence the first-order order conditions can be used together with the binding 2

constraint to solve for c 1 c 2 λ in terms of the model s parameters I a: c 1 = ai c 2 = (1 a)i ( ) a ( ) 1 a a 1 a λ =. (d) The solutions for c 1 c 2 shown above imply that the consumer spends the fraction a of his or her income on good 1 the remaining fraction 1 a of his or her income on good 2. Hence one could estimate a directly from the observation on the fraction of income spent on good 1. (e) The Lagrangian for the consumer s problem is now L(c 1 c 2 λ) = a ln(c 1 ) + (1 a) ln(c 2 ) λ( c 1 + c 2 I). Once again we have that NDCQ is satisfied. According to the Kuhn-Tucker theorem the values c 1 c 2 that solve the consumer s problem together with the associated value λ for the multiplier must satisfy the first-order conditions the constraint the nonnegativity condition L 1 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = a c 1 λ = 0 L 2 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = 1 a c 2 λ = 0 L 3 (c 1 c 2 λ ) = I c 1 c 2 0 λ 0 the complementary slackness condition λ ( c 1 + c 2 I) = 0. As before the first-order conditions for c 1 c 2 reveal that λ > 0 if the prices are both strictly positive again a condition that must hold if the problem is to have a well-defined solution in the first place. Assuming that this is the case the complementary slackness conditions requires the constraint to hold as an equality. Hence the first-order order conditions can be used together with the binding constraint to solve for c 1 c 2 λ in terms of the model s parameters I a: c 1 = ai 3

c 2 = (1 a)i λ = 1 I. The solutions for c 1 c 2 shown above continue to imply that the consumer spends the fraction a of his or her income on good 1 the remaining fraction 1 a of his or her income on good 2. This is because the two utility functions from this problem the previous one represent the same underlying preference ordering. Hence one could again estimate a directly from the observation on the fraction of income spent on good 1. 3. Utility Maximization - Second-Order Conditions (a) We know from above that c 2 = c 1 = ai (1 a)i λ = 1 I. (b) Following the pattern shown in the theorem the bordered Hessian matrix H is 0 H = a/c 2 1 0 0 (1 a)/c 2 2 therefore H π (1 a) = 1 + ap2 2 > 0. c 2 2 c 2 1 Also the permuted bordered Hessian matrix H π is 0 H π = (1 a)/c 2 2 0 0 a/c 2 1 therefore H π = ap2 2 + (1 a)p2 1 c 2 1 c 2 2 so our solutions satisfy the SONC. (c) To check the SOSC we need H to have a strictly positive determinant which we know from part b) is true. Thus our solution satisfies the SOSC. 4. The Constraint Qualification 4 > 0

(a) Since the utility function is strictly increasing it will always be optimal for the consumer to spend all of his or her income on the single good. Hence c = I/p. (b) With the Lagrangian defined as the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are L(c λ) = U(c) λ(pc I) L 1 (c λ ) = U (c ) λ p = 0 L 2 (c λ ) = I pc 0 λ 0 λ (I pc ) = 0. Since U (c) > 0 for all values of c the first-order condition requires λ > 0 which then implies via the complementary slackness condition that c = I/p. Substituting this result back into the first-order condition yields the solution λ = U (I/P ). (c) With the Lagrangian defined as the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are L(c λ) = U(c) λ(pc I) 3 L 1 (c λ ) = U (c ) 3pλ (pc I) 2 = 0 L 2 (c λ ) = (I pc ) 3 0 λ 0 λ (I pc ) 3 = 0. But substituting the value of c = I/p found above into the new first-order condition yields U (I/P ) 3pλ (I I) 2 = U (I/P ) = 0 which cannot hold if U (c) > 0 for all values of c. What has gone wrong is that with the constraint written in an unnecessarily complicated way the constraint qualification which requires that fails to hold. 5. Perfect Substitutes 3(I pc ) 2 0 5

(a) The solution is for the consumer to spend all of his or her income on the good with the lowest price: c 1 = I/ c 2 = 0 if < c 1 = 0 c 2 = I/ if >. If = then any values of c 1 c 2 satisfying the budget constraint with equality will be optimal. (b) According to the Kuhn-Tucker theorem the values of c 1 c 2 that solve the consumer s problem together with the associated values of λ µ 1 µ 2 must satisfy the first-order conditions L 1 (c 1 c 2 λ µ 1 µ 2) = 1 λ + µ 1 = 0 the constraints L 2 (c 1 c 2 λ µ 1 µ 2) = 1 λ + µ 2 = 0 L 3 (c 1 c 2 λ µ 1 µ 2) = I c 1 c 2 0 L 4 (c 1 c 2 λ µ 1 µ 2) = c 1 0 L 5 (c 1 c 2 λ µ 1 µ 2) = c 2 0 the nonnegativity conditions λ 0 µ 1 0 µ 2 0 the complementary slackness conditions λ (I c 1 c 2) = 0 µ 1c 1 = 0 µ 2c 2 = 0. The first-order conditions the nonnegativity conditions for µ 1 µ 2 imply that λ > 0 so that the budget constraint must always bind. Hence there are three possibilities to consider. The first possibility is that µ 1 > 0 µ 2 = 0. In this case the complementary slackness condition requires that c 1 = 0 the binding budget constraint implies that c 2 = I/. The first-order conditions require that λ = 1/ µ 1 = λ 1 = / 1. But this last condition is consistent with µ 1 > 0 only if >. The second possibility is that µ 1 = 0 µ 2 > 0. In this case reasoning analogous to that above implies that c 1 = I/ c 2 = 0 λ = 1/ µ 2 = / 1. But this last condition is consistent with µ 2 > 0 only if > p1. The final possibility is that µ 1 = µ 2 = 0. The first-order conditions imply that this case can only occur when = so that 6

λ = 1/ = 1/ any values of c 1 c 2 satisfying the budget constraint with equality will work. These solutions serve to confirm the guesses from part (a) above. 6. Elasticities of Dem (a) Differentiate both sides of equation (5) with respect to one of the prices p j to obtain c 1( p 3 I) p j + c 2( p 3 I) p j + p 3 c 3( p 3 I) p j + c j( p 3 I) = 0. Now use the definition of the price elasticities ε ij to rewrite this expression as [c 1( p 3 I)/p j ]ε 1j + [c 2( p 3 I)/p j ]ε 2j +p 3 [c 3( p 3 I)/p j ]ε 3j + c j( p 3 I) = 0. Finally multiply through by p j divide through by I rearrange to obtain s 1 ε 1j + s 2 ε 2j + s 3 ε 3j = s j. (b) Differentiate both sides of equation (5) with respect to I to obtain c 1( p 3 I) I + c 2( p 3 I) I + p 3 c 3( p 3 I) I = 1. Now use the definition of the income elasticities η i to rewrite this expression as [c 1( p 3 I)/I]η 1 + [c 2( p 3 I)/I]η 2 + p 3 [c 3( p 3 I)/I]η 3 = 1 or more simply s 1 η 1 + s 2 η 2 + s 3 η 3 = 1. (c) Differentiate both sides of (6) with respect to r to obtain c i (r r rp 3 ri) +p 3 c i (r r rp 3 ri) p 3 + c i (r r rp 3 ri) + I c i (r r rp 3 ri) p I = 0. Now divide through by c i (r r rp 3 ri) set r = 1 to obtain ε i1 + ε i2 + ε i3 + η i = 0. 7