Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Similar documents
Learning and Global Dynamics

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

TARIFF AND EQUILIBRIUM INDETERMINACY: A GLOBAL ANALYSIS

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Volume 30, Issue 3. Ramsey Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth: A Comment. Jenn-hong Tang Department of Economics, National Tsing-Hua University

Advanced Macroeconomics

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Equilibrium Determinacy in a Two-Tax System with Utility from Government Expenditure

Advanced Macroeconomics

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Endogenous growth with addictive habits

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model)

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Indeterminacy in a Matching Model of Money with Productive Government Expenditure

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

... Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium Models Using Log Linear Approximation

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne UMR 8174

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Multiple equilibria and indeterminacy in money-in-the-production-function model

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

The Real Business Cycle Model

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

Indeterminacy in a Matching Model of Money with Productive Government Expenditure

Advanced Macroeconomics

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality

Lecture 1: Overview, Hamiltonians and Phase Diagrams. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall

Population Aging, Government Policy and the Postwar Japanese Economy

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

1 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PS 5, preliminary version

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Problem 1 (30 points)

Nonlinear Systems and Control Lecture # 19 Perturbed Systems & Input-to-State Stability

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model

The Neoclassical Growth Model

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Adaptive Learning and Applications in Monetary Policy. Noah Williams

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Solving Linearized Rational Expectations Models

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Econ 204A: Section 3

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Housing in a two sector dynastic altruism model

Steady state analysis and endogenous uctuations in a nance constrained model

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOPHISTICATED MONETARY POLICIES. Andrew Atkeson V. V. Chari Patrick Kehoe

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600

Nominal Rigidities, Government Spending, and Long-Run Policy Trade-Off

The basic representative agent model: Ramsey

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

Suggested Solutions to Homework #6 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Investment, interest rate rules, and equilibrium determinacy

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

A comparison of numerical methods for the. Solution of continuous-time DSGE models. Juan Carlos Parra Alvarez

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

optimal simple nonlinear rules for monetary policy in a new-keynesian model

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Transcription:

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Literature Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (JPE 1997): Ramsey model with endogenous labor income tax + balanced budget (fiscal) policy rule. Also (Constant) Government spending is pure waste. Endogenous labor supply and additively-separable preferences. Local indeterminacy Giannitsaru (EJ 2007): Endogenous (time-varying) consumption tax never leads to local indeterminacy. Nourry et al. (JET 2011): Endogenous (time-varying) consumption tax may imply multiple steady states and local indeterminacy under GHH utility function. Result is robust to government spending in the utility function. Aggregate instability means possibility of sunspot equilibria. Woodford (1984): local indeterminacy implies sunspot equilibria.

Motivation No contribution on endogenous time-varying consumption tax financing productive government spending. No contribution on time-varying endogenous taxes in an endogenous growth model a la Barro (JEP 1990). Aim of the paper is to fill this gap.

Model Setup The representative household solves the following problem taking as given the time-varying paths of G and τ: where c 1 σ 1 max 0 1 σ e ρt dt s.t. k = Ak α G 1 α δk (1 + τ)c k 0, c 0 k(0) = k 0 > 0 given Θ def = {(α, ρ, δ, σ, A) : α (0, 1), ρ > 0, δ > 0, σ > 0 and A > 0}.

Given an initial capital stock k 0 and the path (τ(t), G(t)) t 0, the representative household maximizes his/her utility by choosing any path (c(t), k(t)) t 0 which solves the system of ODEs k = Ak α G 1 α δk (1 + τ)c (1) [ ċ = 1 ( ) ] α 1 k αa δ ρ τ (2) c σ G 1 + τ respects the inequality constraints and the transversality condition lim t + k c σ (1 + τ) e ρt = 0 (3)

The government balances its budget in every period: G = τ( c) c (4) where c = ce γt, with γ the asymptotic (endogenous) growth rate and τ(.) continuous and differentiable. Barro: τ = τ 0 for all t. Giannitsaru: G constant and therefore τ time-varying. Nourry et al.: τ = τ(c) since no growth. with positive growth we need to de-trend consumption to avoid an explosive (counterfactual) consumption tax.

We also assume the following: Assumption The elasticity of τ with respect to c is constant: φ def = dτ d c c τ = constant (5) Therefore by differentiating τ( c) w.r.t. t (ċ ) τ τ = φ c γ (6)

Observe that integrating (6) leads to a menu of fiscal policies: τ(t) = B ( c(t)e γt) φ with B a generic (and not exogenously given) constant. (7) To avoid to introduce a trivial form of indeterminacy we need to select just one of them. To do so τ 0 has to be exogenously given.

Intertemporal equilibrium Definition Given k 0 > 0 and τ 0 > 0, an intertemporal equilibrium is any path (c(t), k(t), τ(t), G(t)) t 0 which satisfies the system of equations (1), (2), (4) and (6), respects the inequality constraints and the transversality condition (3).

In particular we may define the control-like variable x def = c k and observe that the intertemporal equilibrium can be derived studying the following system of nonlinear ODEs: ẋ = [(1 + τ)(1 σ) φτ] [ αa(xτ) 1 α δ ρ σγ ] x σ(1 + τ) + φτ + γ(1 σ) + (1 + τ)x (1 α)a(xτ) 1 α ρ (8) τ = φτ(1 + τ) [ αa(xτ) 1 α δ ρ σγ ] σ(1 + τ) + φτ (9)

Balanced Growth Paths A balanced growth path (BGP) is an intertemporal equilibrium where consumption, and capital are purely exponential functions from t greater than zero. Formally: k(t) = k 0 e γt and c(t) = c 0 e γt t 0. (10) From equation (6) it follows immediately that along a BGP τ(t) = ˆτ = τ 0 t 0 with the hat symbol indicating, from now on, the value of a variable on a BGP. Also purely exponential government spending.

Proposition (Existence and Uniqueness of a BGP) Given any initial condition of capital k 0 > 0 and the tax rate τ 0 > 0, there exist A > 0, τ > 0 and τ(σ) (0, + ] with τ(σ) > τ such that when A > A and one of the following conditions hold i) σ 1 and τ 0 > τ, ii) σ (0, 1) and τ 0 (τ, τ(σ)), there is a unique balanced growth path where the consumption over capital ratio is constant and equal to ˆx and the growth rate of the economy is ˆγ = αa(ˆx ˆτ) 1 α δ ρ > 0, (11) with ˆτ = τ 0. Remark (ˆx, ˆτ) = ( ĉ0 k 0, τ 0 ) is a steady state of the system (8), (9).

Local determinacy of the steady state (ˆx, ˆτ) Proposition Consider the steady state (ˆx, ˆτ) (with ˆτ = τ 0 ) which characterizes the unique BGP of our economy. For any given initial conditions (k 0, τ 0 ), there is no transitional dynamics, i.e. there exists a unique c 0 = k 0ˆx such that the economy directly jumps on the BGP from the initial date t = 0.

τ(t) 0.2 0.2 x (t)=0 x (t)=0 0.18 τ (t)=0 0.18 τ (t)=0 saddle path 0.16 0.16 0.14 0.14 0.12 0.12 x(t) 0.1 x(t) 0.1 0.08 x 0 = x* 0.08 x 0 = x* E 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.02 0 τ 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0 = 0.1 0 0.05 τ 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0 = τ* τ(t) Figure: Phase Diagrams when φ = 0.5 (left) and φ = 0.01 (right) and γ = ˆγ 0

Existence of other equilibria Differently from Barro, some transitional dynamics may occur in our model. Indeed, the BGP as defined by (ˆx, ˆτ) and ˆγ is not the unique possible equilibrium of our economy. Look for the existence of equilibrium path (x t, τ t ) t 0 which may eventually converge to an asymptotic BGP.

Definition An ABGP is any path (x(t), τ(t)) t 0 = (x, τ ) such that: a) τ is a positive arbitrary constant sufficiently close to (but different from) τ 0 ; b) (x, τ ) is a steady state of (8)-(9) with x > 0 and γ > 0 solution of 0 = (α 1)A(xτ ) 1 α + (1 + τ )x ρ (12) γ = αa(xτ ) 1 α δ ρ. (13) c) (x, τ ) satisfies the transversality condition. Remark An ABGP is not an equilibrium since it does not satisfy the initial condition τ(0) = τ 0.

The existence of an equilibrium path converging to an ABGP is associated to the existence of consumers beliefs that are different from those associated to the BGP. Indeed, they may believe that the consumption tax profile will not remain constant but rather change over time and eventually converge to a positive value τ τ 0 where the consumption over capital ratio and the growth rate are x and γ respectively. Based on that we will prove that under some conditions the consumers may indeed decide a consumption path which makes this belief selffulfilled.

τ(t) 0.2 0.2 0.18 x (t)=0 τ (t)=0 0.18 x (t) τ (t) saddle path 0.16 0.16 0.14 0.14 0.12 0.12 x(t) 0.1 x(t) 0.1 0.08 E x* x 0 E 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.02 0 τ τ* = 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0 = 0.1 0 τ τ* =0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0 = 0.1 τ(t) Figure: Phase Diagrams when φ = 0.5 (left) and φ = 0.01 (right) and γ = ˆγ 1

Proposition Given any initial condition k 0 > 0 and τ 0 > 0, consider τ and τ(σ) as defined by Proposition 1. There exist A > 0 such that when A > A, there is a unique equilibrium path (x t, τ t ) t 0 converging over time to the ABGP (x, τ ) if and only if φ ( σ(1 + τ )/τ, 0) and one of the following conditions hold: i) σ 1 and τ > τ, ii) σ (0, 1) and τ (τ, τ(σ)).

The last proposition actually proves that there exists a continuum of equilibria each of them converging to a different ABGP. Any value of τ in a neighborhood of the given initial value τ 0 is a belief that the consumers may self-fulfilled if the conditions of the Proposition are met. Of course this implies a form of global indeterminacy since from a given τ 0, one can select the unique BGP by jumping on it from the initial date or any other equilibrium converging to an ABGP.

Theorem Given the initial conditions k 0 and τ 0 let τ inf = τ 0 ɛ > 0 and τ sup = τ 0 + ε with ε > 0 small enough. Assume that one of the following conditions holds i) σ < 1 and A (A 2 (τ inf ), Ā(τ sup)); ii) 1 < σ < 1 + ρ δ and A > A 2 (τ inf ); iii) σ > 1 + ρ δ and A > max{a 1(τ inf ), A 2 (τ inf )}; Then if φ ( σ(1+τsup) τ sup, 0), there is a continuum of equilibrium paths indexed by the letter j, departing from (τ 0, x j 0 ), each of them converging to a different ABGP (τ j, x j ) with τ j (τ inf, τ sup ), i.e. the dynamics of the economy is globally, but not locally, indeterminate. On the other hand, the dynamics of the economy is globally and locally determinate if φ (0, + ).

x 1 0 x 2 0 x 3 0 x 4 0 x 6 0 x 7 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 x 8 0.25 0.24 τ 1 =0.24 0.23 τ 2 =0.23 0.22 τ 3 =0.22 τ 0 = 0.21 0.2 BGP τ 4 =0.21 τ 5 =0.2 0.19 τ 6 =0.19 0.18 τ 7 =0.18 0.17 τ 8 =0.17 Periods 0.19 x 5 0 BGP x 1 x 5 x 8 0 0.1735 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Periods Figure: Dynamics of the Tax Rate and of the Consumption-capital Ratio

x t f 1(t; t 0) f BGP (t; t 0) steady states locus f -1(t; t 0) f -2(t; t 0) BGP f 2(t; t 0) t 0 t t Figure: Examples of Saddle-Paths

Sunspot Equilibria Sunspot equilibria, and therefore aggregate instability, may emerge in our framework once extrinsic uncertainty is introduced. We do that introducing extrinsic uncertainty in the discrete time counterpart of the dynamical system F (x, τ).

An illustrative example Discrete time with period length h; Dynamics is then described by ( ) Et ( x t+h ) = F(x τ t, τ t )h with (x 0, τ 0 ) given t+h where χ t+h χ t+h χ t with χ = x, τ. Equivalently ( ) ( ) xt+h εt+h = F(x τ t, τ t )h + s with (x t+h 0 0, τ 0 ) given (14) where E t ( ε t+h ) = 0 with ε t the sunspot variable. ε t takes the values (0, z 1, z 2 ) at dates (0, t 1 +h, t 2 +h) respectively (deterministic) sunspots

Dynamics in t [0, t 1 h] will be described by the initial value problem (from now on IVP) ( ) xt+h = F (x τ t, τ t )h with (x 0, τ 0 ) given t+h Unique equilibrium path {x t, τ t } t 1 t=0 = {φ 1x (t), φ 1τ (t)} t 1 t=0.

Then at date t = t 1 due to the arrival of the second sunspot at date t = t 1 + h we have that ( ) ( ) xt1 +h z1 0 = F (x τ t1, τ t1 )h + s t1 +h 0 which clearly implies that ( ) ( xt1 +h φ1x (t = 1 ) φ 1τ (t 1 ) τ t1 +h ) ( z1 + F (φ 1x (t 1 ), φ 1τ (t 1 ))h + s 0 ) (15)

Dynamics in t [t 1 + h, t 2 h] will be given by the IVP ( ) xt+h = F(x τ t, τ t )h with (x t1 +h, τ t1 +h) given by (15). (16) t+h Unique equilibrium path {x t, τ t } t 2 t=t1 +h = {φ 2x(t), φ 2τ (t)} t 2 t=t1 +h. The presence of the sunspot variable has just modified the deterministic framework by allowing a jump at date t 1 + h of size sz 1 in the no-predetermined variable while the dynamics of the economy is still described by F(.) since the uncertainty is extrinsic and does not affect the fundamentals.

(x u-2, t u-2 ) steady states locus BGP (x u2, t u2 ) (x ubgp, t ubgp ) t 0 t t Figure: Example of a Sunspot Equilibrium

A similar argument can be applied for the arrival of the third sunspot. A sunspot equilibrium can be obtained through a randomization over the deterministic equilibrium paths. Continuous time case can be naturally derived by considering the limit h 0. In the paper, we prove the existence of sunspot equilibria by explicitly describing the stochastic process (continuous time Markov chain) governing the sunspot variable.