A note on the convex infimum convolution inequality

Similar documents
ON THE CONVEX INFIMUM CONVOLUTION INEQUALITY WITH OPTIMAL COST FUNCTION

Concentration Properties of Restricted Measures with Applications to Non-Lipschitz Functions

Spectral Gap and Concentration for Some Spherically Symmetric Probability Measures

Convex inequalities, isoperimetry and spectral gap III

Weak and strong moments of l r -norms of log-concave vectors

LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS. S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov. September 25, 2011

On the convex infimum convolution inequality with optimal cost function

KLS-TYPE ISOPERIMETRIC BOUNDS FOR LOG-CONCAVE PROBABILITY MEASURES. December, 2014

Discrete Ricci curvature: Open problems

Probability and Measure

Contents 1. Introduction 1 2. Main results 3 3. Proof of the main inequalities 7 4. Application to random dynamical systems 11 References 16

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents

From the Brunn-Minkowski inequality to a class of Poincaré type inequalities

GAUSSIAN MEASURE OF SECTIONS OF DILATES AND TRANSLATIONS OF CONVEX BODIES. 2π) n

1 Cheeger differentiation

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

NONHOMOGENEOUS ELLIPTIC EQUATIONS INVOLVING CRITICAL SOBOLEV EXPONENT AND WEIGHT

Stepanov s Theorem in Wiener spaces

On John type ellipsoids

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

Concentration inequalities: basics and some new challenges

Sobolev Spaces. Chapter 10

EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course. Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1

On the Brunn-Minkowski inequality for general measures with applications to new isoperimetric-type inequalities

Concentration inequalities for non-lipschitz functions

Stability results for Logarithmic Sobolev inequality

ESTIMATES FOR THE MONGE-AMPERE EQUATION

Integration on Measure Spaces

COMPARISON THEOREMS FOR THE SPECTRAL GAP OF DIFFUSIONS PROCESSES AND SCHRÖDINGER OPERATORS ON AN INTERVAL. Ross G. Pinsky

On isotropicity with respect to a measure

Recall that if X is a compact metric space, C(X), the space of continuous (real-valued) functions on X, is a Banach space with the norm

PROPERTY OF HALF{SPACES. July 25, Abstract

Another Riesz Representation Theorem

The optimal partial transport problem

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

MODIFIED LOG-SOBOLEV INEQUALITIES AND ISOPERIMETRY

3. Convex functions. basic properties and examples. operations that preserve convexity. the conjugate function. quasiconvex functions

HOMEOMORPHISMS OF BOUNDED VARIATION

PACKING-DIMENSION PROFILES AND FRACTIONAL BROWNIAN MOTION

Concentration inequalities and the entropy method

Constrained Optimization and Lagrangian Duality

Entropy and Ergodic Theory Lecture 15: A first look at concentration

Phenomena in high dimensions in geometric analysis, random matrices, and computational geometry Roscoff, France, June 25-29, 2012

KLS-type isoperimetric bounds for log-concave probability measures

Mass transportation methods in functional inequalities and a new family of sharp constrained Sobolev inequalities

Expansion and Isoperimetric Constants for Product Graphs

Logarithmic Sobolev Inequalities

Heat Flows, Geometric and Functional Inequalities

N. GOZLAN, C. ROBERTO, P-M. SAMSON

ON GAP FUNCTIONS OF VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY IN A BANACH SPACE. Sangho Kum and Gue Myung Lee. 1. Introduction

Richard F. Bass Krzysztof Burdzy University of Washington

On the Brunn-Minkowski inequality for general measures with applications to new isoperimetric type-inequalities

SOME PROPERTIES ON THE CLOSED SUBSETS IN BANACH SPACES

APPLICATIONS OF DIFFERENTIABILITY IN R n.

MASS TRANSPORT AND VARIANTS OF THE LOGARITHMIC SOBOLEV INEQUALITY

AN ASYMPTOTIC MEAN VALUE CHARACTERIZATION FOR p-harmonic FUNCTIONS. To the memory of our friend and colleague Fuensanta Andreu

SYMMETRY RESULTS FOR PERTURBED PROBLEMS AND RELATED QUESTIONS. Massimo Grosi Filomena Pacella S. L. Yadava. 1. Introduction

THE INVERSE FUNCTION THEOREM

6.2 Fubini s Theorem. (µ ν)(c) = f C (x) dµ(x). (6.2) Proof. Note that (X Y, A B, µ ν) must be σ-finite as well, so that.

High-dimensional distributions with convexity properties

Functional inequalities for heavy tailed distributions and application to isoperimetry

BOUNDS ON THE DEFICIT IN THE LOGARITHMIC SOBOLEV INEQUALITY

Functions of several variables of finite variation and their differentiability

APPROXIMATE ISOMETRIES ON FINITE-DIMENSIONAL NORMED SPACES

FKN Theorem on the biased cube

A REMARK ON MINIMAL NODAL SOLUTIONS OF AN ELLIPTIC PROBLEM IN A BALL. Olaf Torné. 1. Introduction

Characterization of Self-Polar Convex Functions

Integral Jensen inequality

Random Bernstein-Markov factors

Stein s method, logarithmic Sobolev and transport inequalities

Entropy and Ergodic Theory Lecture 17: Transportation and concentration

A NEW PROOF OF THE ATOMIC DECOMPOSITION OF HARDY SPACES

On the isotropic constant of marginals

ON CONCENTRATION FUNCTIONS OF RANDOM VARIABLES. Sergey G. Bobkov and Gennadiy P. Chistyakov. June 2, 2013

Math The Laplacian. 1 Green s Identities, Fundamental Solution

Local semiconvexity of Kantorovich potentials on non-compact manifolds

AN ASYMPTOTIC MEAN VALUE CHARACTERIZATION FOR p-harmonic FUNCTIONS

Poincaré Inequalities and Moment Maps

Invariances in spectral estimates. Paris-Est Marne-la-Vallée, January 2011

ON A MAXIMAL OPERATOR IN REARRANGEMENT INVARIANT BANACH FUNCTION SPACES ON METRIC SPACES

MAJORIZING MEASURES WITHOUT MEASURES. By Michel Talagrand URA 754 AU CNRS

EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR QUASILINEAR HEMIVARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES AT RESONANCE. Leszek Gasiński

A COUNTEREXAMPLE TO AN ENDPOINT BILINEAR STRICHARTZ INEQUALITY TERENCE TAO. t L x (R R2 ) f L 2 x (R2 )

18.409: Topics in TCS: Embeddings of Finite Metric Spaces. Lecture 6

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

ON APPROXIMATE DIFFERENTIABILITY OF THE MAXIMAL FUNCTION

Brunn-Minkowski inequality for the 1-Riesz capacity and level set convexity for the 1/2-Laplacian

AN INEQUALITY FOR TAIL PROBABILITIES OF MARTINGALES WITH BOUNDED DIFFERENCES

A fixed point theorem for weakly Zamfirescu mappings

RENORMINGS OF L p (L q )

PCA sets and convexity

Sobolev spaces. May 18

NECESSARY CONDITIONS FOR WEIGHTED POINTWISE HARDY INEQUALITIES

Characterizing Robust Solution Sets of Convex Programs under Data Uncertainty

ON BOUNDEDNESS OF MAXIMAL FUNCTIONS IN SOBOLEV SPACES

Packing-Dimension Profiles and Fractional Brownian Motion

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis

Transcription:

A note on the convex infimum convolution inequality Naomi Feldheim, Arnaud Marsiglietti, Piotr Nayar, Jing Wang Abstract We characterize the symmetric measures which satisfy the one dimensional convex infimum convolution inequality of Maurey. For these measures the tensorization argument yields the two level Talagrand s concentration inequalities for their products and convex sets in R n. 00 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 6D0; Secondary 8A35, 5A0, 60E5. Key words and phrases. Infimum convolution, Concentration of measure, Convex sets, Product measures, Poincaré inequality. Introduction In the past few decades a lot of attention has been devoted to study the concentration of measure phenomenon, especially the concentration properties of product measures on the Euclidean space R n. Through this note by x p we denote the l p norm on R n, namely x p = n i= x i p /p, and let us take Bp n = {x R n : x p }. We say that a Borel probability measure µ on R n satisfies concentration with a profile α µ t if for any set A R n with µa / we have µa + tb n α µ t, t 0, where B n is the Euclidean ball of radius, centred at the origin. Equivalently, for any -Lipschitz function f on R n we have µ{x : f Med µ f > t} α µ t, t > 0, where Med µ f is a median of f. Moreover, the median can be replaced with the mean, see [L, Proposition.8]. The usual way to reach concentration is via certain functional inequalities. For example, we say that µ satisfies Poincaré inequality sometimes also called the spectral gap inequality with constant C, if for any f : R n R which is, say, C smooth, we have Var µ f C f dµ. We assume that C is the best constant possible. This inequality implies the exponential concentration, namely, concentration with a profile α µ t = exp t/ C. The product exponential probability measure ν n, i.e., measure with density n exp x, satisfies with the constant 4 the one dimensional case goes back to [K]; for a one-line proof see Lemma. in [BL]. From this fact case n = one can deduce, using the transportation argument, that any one-dimensional log-concave measure, i.e. the measure with the density of the form e V, where V is convex, satisfies the Poincaré inequality with a universal constant C. In fact, there is a so-called Muckenhoupt condition that fully characterize measures satisfying the one dimensional Poincaré inequality, see [Mu] and [K]. Namely, let us assume, for simplicity, that our measure is symmetric. If the density of the absolutely continuous part of µ is equal to p then the optimal constant in satisfies + B C 4B, where B = sup x>0 { µ[x, x 0 py dy }.

In particular, the constant C is finite if B <. Suppose that µ,... µ satisfy Poincaré inequality with constant C. Then the same can be said about the product measure µ = µ... µ n, due to tensorization property of see Corollary 5.7 in [L], which follows immediately from the subadditivity of the variance. Thus, one can say that the Poincaré inequality is fully understood in the case of product measures. A much stronger functional inequality that gives concentration is the so-called log-sobolev inequality, Ent µ f C f dµ, where for a function g 0 we set Ent µ g = g ln g dµ g dµ ln g dµ. It implies the Gaussian concentration phenomenon, i.e., concentration with a profile α µ t = exp t /6C. As an example, the standard Gaussian measure γ n, i.e., the measure with density π n/ e x /, satisfies with the constant see [G]. As in, the log-sobolev inequality possess similar terrorization properties and there is a full description of measures µ satisfying on the real line, see [BG]. Namely, the optimal constant C in satisfies 75 B C 936B, where B = sup x>0 { µ[x, ln µ[x, x 0 } py dy. Another way to concentration leads through the so-called property τ see [M] and [LW]. A measure µ on R n is said to satisfy property τ with a nonnegative cost function ϕ if the inequality e f ϕ dµ e f dµ 3 holds for every bounded measurable function f on R n. Here f ϕ = inf y {fy + ϕx y} is the so-called infimum convolution. Property τ implies concentration, see Lemma 4 in [M]. Namely, for every measurable set A we have µ {x / A + {ϕ < t}} µa e t. In the seminal paper [M] Maurey showed that the exponential measure ν satisfies the infimum convolution inequality with a the cost function ϕt = min{ 36 t, t }. As a consequence 9 of tensorization see Lemma in [M] we get that ν n satisfies 3 with the cost function ϕx = n i= ϕx i. This leads to the so-called Talagrand s two level concentration, ν n A + 6 tb n + 9tB n ν n A e t, see Corollary in [M]. As we can see, this gives a stronger conclusion than the Poincaré inequality. It is a well known fact that the property τ with a cost function which is quadratic around 0, say ϕx = C x for x, implies the Poincaré inequality with the constant /4C, see Corrolary 3 in [M]. We shall sketch the argument in Section. The goal of this article is to investigate concentration properties of a wider class of measures, i.e., measures that may not even satisfy the Poincaré inequality. For example, in the case of purely atomic measures one can easily construct a non-constant function f with f dµ = 0. However, one can still hope to get concentration if one restricts himself to the class of convex sets. It turns out that to reach exponential concentration for convex sets, it suffices to prove that the measure µ satisfies the convex Poincaré inequality. Below we state the formal definition.

Definition. We say that a Borel probability measure µ on R satisfies the convex Poincaré inequality with a constant C p if for every convex function f : R R with f bounded we have Var µ f C p f dµ. 4 Here we adopt the standard convention that for a locally Lipschitz function f : R R the gradient f is defined by f fx + h fx x = lim sup. 5 h 0 h This definition applies in particular to convex f. If f is differentiable, 5 agrees with the usual derivative. We also need the following definition. Definition. Let h > 0 and λ [0,. Let Mh, λ be the class of symmetric measures on R, satisfying the condition µ[x + h, λµ[x, for x 0. Moreover, let M + h, λ be the class of measures supported on R +, satisfying the same condition. The inequality 4 has been investigated by Bobkov and Götze, see [BG, Theorem 4.]. In particular, the authors proved 4 in the class Mh, λ with a constant C p depending only on h and λ. This leads to the exponential concentration for -Lipschitz convex functions f as well as the exponential concentration for convex sets via the standard Herbst-like argument which actually goes back to [AS] see also, e.g., Theorem 3.3 in [L], by deriving the bound on the Laplace transform of f. It is worth mentioning that a much stronger condition µ[x + C/x, λµ[x,, x m, where m is a fixed positive number, has been considered. It implies log-sobolev inequalities for log-convex functions and the Gaussian concentration of measure for convex sets. We refer to the nice study [A] for the details. In [M] the author showed that every measure supported on a subset of R with diameter satisfies the convex property τ, i.e. the inequality 3 for convex functions f, with the cost function 4 x see Theorem 3 therein. The aim of this note is to extend both this result and the convex Poincaré inequality of Bobkov and Götze. We introduce the following definition. Definition 3. Define ϕ 0 x = R { x x x x >. We say that a Borel probability measure µ on R satisfies convex exponential property τ with constant C τ if for any convex function f : R R with inf f > we have e f ϕ dµ e f dµ 6 with ϕx = ϕ 0 x/c τ. We are ready to state our main result. Theorem. The following conditions are equivalent a µ Mh, λ, 3

b There exists C p > 0 such that µ satisfies the convex Poincaré inequality with constant C p, c There exists C τ > 0 such that µ satisfies the convex exponential property τ with constant C τ. Moreover, a implies c with the constant C τ = 7h/ λ, c implies b with the constant C p = C τ and b implies a with h = 8C p and λ = /. This generalizes Maurey s theorem due to the fact that any symmetric measure supported on the interval [, ] belongs to M, 0. It is well known that the convex property τ tensorizes, namely, if µ,..., µ n have convex property τ with cost functions ϕ,... ϕ n then the product measure µ = µ... µ n has convex property τ with ϕx = n i= ϕ ix i, see [M, Lemma 5]. Therefore Theorem implies the following Corollary. Corollary. Let µ,..., µ n Mh, λ and let us take µ = µ... µ n. Define the cost function ϕx = n i= ϕ 0x i /C τ, where C τ = 7h/ λ. Then for any coordinate-wise convex function f in particular, for any convex function we have e f ϕ dµ e f dµ. 7 As a consequence, one can deduce the two-level concentration for convex sets and convex functions in R n. Corollary. Let µ,..., µ n Mh, λ. Let C τ = 7h/ λ. Take µ = µ... µ n. Then for any convex set A with µa > 0 we have µ A + tc τ B n + tc τ B n e t µa. Corollary 3. Let µ,..., µ n Mh, λ. Let C τ = 7h/ λ. Take µ = µ... µ n. Then for any convex function f : R n R with we have and fx fy a x y, fx fy b x y, x, y R n, µ {f > Med µ f + C τ t} exp 8 { } tb min, t, t 0, 8 a µ {f < Med µ f C τ t} exp 8 { } tb min, t, t 0. 9 a Let us mention that very recently Adamczak and Strzelecki established related results in the context of modified log-sobolev inequalities, see [ASt]. For simplicity we state their result in the case of symmetric measures. For λ [0,, β [0, ] and h, m > 0 the authors defined the class of measures M β AS h, λ, m satisfying the condition µ[x + h/xβ, λµ[x, for x m. Note that M 0 AS h, λ, 0 = Mh, λ. They proved that products µ = µ... µ n of such measures satisfy the inequality Ent µ e f C AS e f f f 4 β+ β β+ β dµ. 0

for any smooth convex function f : R R. As a consequence, for any convex set A in R n with µa / we have µ A + t B n + t +β Cτ B+β n e C AS t, t 0. Here the constants C AS, C AS depend only on the parameters β, m, h and λ. They also established inequality similar to 8, namely for a convex function f with fx fy a x y, fx fy +β b x y +β, x, y R n, one gets µ {f > Med µ f + t} exp 36 min { t +β t, b +β C β a C AS AS }, t 0. However, the authors were not able to get 9. In fact one can show that for β = 0 our Theorem is stronger than 0. In particular, the inequality 0 is equivalent to e f ϕ dµ e f dµ, see [AS], which easily follows from 7. The rest of this article is organized as follows. In the next section we prove Theorem. In Section 3 we deduce Corollaries and 3. Proof of Theorem We need the following lemma, which is essentially included in Theorem 4. of [BG]. For reader s convenience we provide a straightforward proof of this fact. Lemma. Let µ M + h, λ and let g : R [0, be non-decreasing with g0 = 0. Then g dµ λ gx gx h dµx. Proof. We first prove that λ gx dµx gx h dµx for any non-decreasing g : R [0, such that g0 = 0. Both sides of this inequality are linear in g. Therefore, it is enough to consider only functions of the form gx = [a, x for a 0, since g can be expressed as a mixture of these functions. For gx = [a, x the above inequality reduces to λµ[a, µ[a + h,, which is clearly true due to our assumption on µ. The above is equivalent to λ gx dµx gx gx h dµx. 5

Now, let us use with g instead of g. Then, g dµ gx gx h dµx λ = gx gx hgx + gx h dµx λ λ λ / gx gx h dµx / gx gx h dµx / gx + gx h dµx / gx dµx We arrive at Our assertion follows. / g dµ λ gx gx h dµx /. In the rest of this note, we take f : R R to be convex. Let x 0 be a point where f attains its minimal value. Note that this point may not be unique. However, one can check that what follows does not depend on the choice of x 0. Moreover, if f is increasing decreasing we adopt the notation x 0 = x 0 =. Let us define a discrete version of gradient of f, fx fx h x > x 0 + h Dfx = fx fx 0 x [x 0 h, x 0 + h]. fx fx + h x < x 0 h Lemma. Let f : R R be a convex function with f0 = 0 and let µ Mh, λ. Then e f/ e f/ 8 dµ e fx Dfx dµx. λ Proof. Step. We first assume that f is non-negative and non-decreasing. It follows that fx = 0 for x 0. Correspondingly, the function g = e f/ e f/ is non-negative, non-decreasing and g0 = 0. Moreover, let µ + be the normalized restriction of µ to R +. Note that µ + M + h, λ. From Lemma we get e f/ e f/ dµ = Observe that = g dµ + gx gx h dµ + x λ gx gx h dµx. 4 λ gx gx h = e fx e fx e fx h + e fx h = e fx e fx h + e fx fx h e fx e fx h e fx fx fx h, 6

where the last inequality follows from the mean value theorem. We arrive at e f/ e f/ dµ e fx Dfx dµx. λ Step. Now let f be non-decreasing but not necessarily non-negative. From convexity of f and the fact that f0 = 0 we get f x fx for x 0. This implies the inequality e f x e f x e fx e fx, x 0. From the symmetry of µ one gets e f/ e f/ e dµ f/ e f/ dµ +. Let f = f [0,. From Step one gets e f/ e f/ dµ + = e f/ e f/ dµ 8 λ 8 λ e fx D fx dµx e fx Dfx dµx. Step 3. The conclusion of Step is also true in the case of non-increasing functions with f0 = 0. This is due to the invariance of our assertion under the symmetry x x, which is an easy consequence of the symmetry of µ and the fact that for F x = f x we have DF x = Df x. Step 4. Let us now eliminate of the assumption of monotonicity of f. Suppose that f is not monotone. Then f has a not necessarily unique minimum attained at some point x 0 R. Due to the remark of Step 3 we can assume that x 0 0. Since f0 = 0, we have fx 0 < 0. Take y 0 = inf{y R : fy = 0}. Clearly y 0 x 0. We define { { fx x x0 0 x y0 f x =, f fx 0 x < x x =. 0 fx x < y 0 Note that f is non-decreasing and f is non-increasing. Moreover, f 0 = f 0 = 0. Therefore, from the previous steps applied for f and f we get + + e fx0/ e fx0/ µ, x 0 ]+ e f/ e f/ 8 dµ e fx Dfx dµx x 0 λ x 0 and y0 e f/ e f/ 8 y0 dµ e fx Dfx dµx. 3 λ Moreover, since fx fx 0 on [y 0, x 0 ], we have x0 e f/ e f/ dµ e fx 0 / e fx0/ µ[y 0, x 0 ] e fx0/ e fx0/ µ, x 0 ]. 4 y 0 Combining, 3 and 4, we arrive at e f/ e f/ dµ 8 λ e fx Dfx dµx. 7

The following lemma provides an estimate on the infimum convolution. Lemma 3. Let C, h > 0. Define ϕ x = C ϕ 0 x/h. Assume that a convex function f satisfies f /C h. Then f ϕ x fx C Dfx. Proof. Let us consider the case when x x 0 +h. We take θ [0, ] and write y = θx h+ θx. Note that x y = hθ. By the convexity of f we have f ϕ x fy + ϕ x y θfx h + θfx + ϕ hθ = θfx h + θfx + C θ. Let us now take θ = C fx fx h. Note that 0 f /C h yields θ [0, ]. We get f ϕ x fx θfx fx h + C θ = fx C fx fx h. The case x x 0 h follows by similar computation one has to take y = θx + h + θx. Also, in the case x [x 0 h, x 0 + h] it is enough to take y = θx 0 + θx and use the fact that x y = θx x 0 hθ. Proof of Theorem. We begin by showing that a implies c. We do this in three steps. Step. We first show that it is enough to consider only the case when f satisfies f /C τ. Since inf f >, then either there exists a point y 0 such that f y 0 /C τ, or f attains its minimum at some point y 0 for example if fx = x /C τ, only the second case is valid. Let us fix this point y 0. Moreover, let us define y = sup{y y 0 : f y /C τ } and y + = inf{y y 0 : f y /C τ } if f < /C τ then we adopt the notation y + = and, similarly, y = if f > /C τ. Let us consider a function g with g = f on [y, y + ] and with the derivative satisfying g = sgnf min{ f, /C τ } when f 0 and g = max{f, /C τ } when f < 0. Clearly g f and gx = fx for y x y +. We now observe that f ϕ = g ϕ. To see this recall that f ϕx = inf y fy + ϕx y. The function ψ x y = fy + ϕx y satisfies ψ xy = f y ϕ x y f y /C τ. Thus, for y y + we have ψ xy 0 and therefore ψ x is non-decreasing for y y +. Similarly, ψ x is non-increasing for y y. This means that inf y fy + ϕx y is attained at some point y = yx [y, y + ]. Thus, f ϕx = fyx + ϕx yx = gyx + ϕx yx = g ϕx. The last equality follows from the fact that the minimum of y gy + ϕx y is achieved at the same point y = yx. Therefore, since f ϕ = g ϕ and g f, we have e f ϕ dµ e f dµ e g ϕ dµ e g dµ and g /C τ. Step. The inequality 6 stays invariant when we add a constant to the function f. Thus, we may and will assume that f0 = 0. Note that from the elementary inequality 4ab a + b we have 4 e f ϕ dµ e e f dµ f ϕ + e f dµ. 8

Thus, it is enough to show that e f ϕ + e f dµ. Step 3. Assume f /C τ. Take C = 7/ λ, C τ = C h and ϕx = ϕ 0 x/c τ. By the convexity of ϕ 0 we get ϕx C ϕ 0 x/h, since C >. Thus, by Lemma 3 we get f ϕ fx C Dfx. By the mean value theorem Dfx /h /C τ. Therefore, C Dfx C h C τ = /C. Let αc = C exp C. The convexity of the exponential function yields e s αc s, s [0, /C ]. Therefore, e f ϕ + e f dµ e fx C Dfx + e fx dµx e fx C αc Dfx + e fx dµx. Therefore, since e f + e f = e f/ e f/, we are to prove that e f/ e f/ C dµ αc e fx Dfx dµx. From Lemma this inequality is true whenever C αc 8 λ. It suffices to observe that C αc = C e C C + = C C + C C + 8 = 8 λ. We now sketch the proof of the fact that c implies b. Due to the standard approximation argument one can assume that f is a convex C smooth function with bounded first and second derivative note that in the definition of the convex Poincaré inequality we assumed that f is bounded. Consider the function f ε = εf. The infimum of ψ x y = ϕy + εfx y is attained at the point y satisfying the equation ψ xy = ϕ y εf x y = 0. Note that ψ x is strictly increasing on the interval [ C τ, C τ ]. If ε is sufficiently small, it follows that the above equation has a unique solution y x and that y x [ C τ, C τ ]. Thus, y x = C τ εf x y x. This implies y x = εc τ f x + oε. We get f ϕx = ϕy x + εfx y x = y Cτ x + εfx εcτ f x + oε = ε C τ f x + εfx ε C τ f x + oε = εfx ε C τ f x + oε. Therefore, from the infimum convolution inequality we get e εfx ε Cτ f x +oε dµx e εf dµ. Testing 6 with fx = x /C τ one gets that e ϕ dµ < and therefore e x /Cτ dµ <. Also, there exists a constant c > 0 such that fx c + x, x R. As a consequence, after some 9

additional technical steps, one can consider the Taylor expansion of the above quantities in ε = 0. This gives + εf ε Cτ f + ε f + oε dµ εf + ε f + oε dµ. Comparing the terms in front of ε leads to f dµ f dµ C τ f dµ. This is exactly the Poincaré inequality with constant C τ. We show that b implies a. Suppose that a symmetric Borel probability measure µ on R satisfies the convex Poincaré inequality with a constant C p. Consider the function f u x = max{x u, 0}, u 0. We have f ux dµx = µ[u,. R Since f u y = 0 for y 0 and µ, 0] /, one gets Var µ f u = f u x f u y dµxdµy 0 f u x f u y dµxdµy R R R f u x dµx [ 4 R 4 f u x dµx C p µ u + 8C p,. u+ 8C p These two observations, together with Poincaré inequality, yield that µ M 8C p, /. 3 Concentration properties We show that the convex property τ implies concentration for convex sets. Proposition. Suppose that a Borel probability measure µ on R n satisfies the convex property τ with a non-negative cost function ϕ, restricted to the family of convex functions. Let B ϕ t = {x R n : ϕx t}. Then for any convex set A we have µa + B ϕ t e t µa. The proof of this proposition is similar to the proof of Proposition.4 in [LW]. We recall the argument. Proof. Let f = 0 on A and f = outside of A. Note that f is convex to avoid working with functions having values + one can consider a family of convex functions f n = n dista, x and take n. Suppose that f ϕx t. Then there exists y R n such that fy+ϕx y t. Thus, y A and x y B ϕ t. Therefore x A + B ϕ t. It follows that x / A + B ϕ t implies f ϕx > t. Applying the infimum convolution inequality we get e t µa + B ϕ t µa e f ϕ dµ e f dµ. Our assertion follows. 0

We are ready to derive the two-level concentration for convex sets. Proof of Corollary. The argument is similar to [M, Corollary ]. Due to Corollary, µ = µ... µ n satisfies property τ with the cost function ϕx = n i= ϕ 0x i /C τ. Suppose that ϕx t. Define y, z R n in the following way. Take y i = x i if x i C τ and y i = 0 otherwise. Take z i = x i if x i > C τ and z i = 0 otherwise. Then x = y + z. Moreover, n ϕy i /C τ + i= n ϕz i /C τ = i= n ϕx i /C τ t. In particular y C τ t and t n i= ϕz i/c τ z /C τ, since z i z i for z i. This gives x tc τ B n + tc τ B n. Our assertion follows from Proposition. Finally, we prove concentration for convex Lipschitz functions. Proof of Corollary 3. The proof of 8 is similar to the proof of Propositon 4.8 in [L]. Let us define a convex set A = {f Med µ f} and observe that µa /. Moreover, A + C τ tb n + tb n {f Med µ f + C τ a t + bt}. Applying Corollary we get { µ f > Med µ f + C τ a } t + bt e t, t 0. Take s = C τ a t + bt and r = s/c τ. Suppose that r r. Then b a a t + tb = r a r/b + r = a r 8b + b r 4b a r 8b + b r 8b. By the monotonicity of x a x + xb, x 0 it follows that min{ r, r } = r 8 b a 8b if r r, then b a a t + tb = r r + br a = a Therefore, 8 min{ r b, r a } = r 8a t. Thus, i= r r + b 8a 4a a µ {f > Med µ f + rc τ } e t exp 8 { rb min, r a r r + b 8a 8a. }, t 0. t. Moreover, For the proof of 9 we follow [T]. Define a convex set B = {f < Med µ f C τ a t + bt} with t 0. It follows that and thus Corollary yields A + C τ tb n + tb n {f < Med µ f} µ A + C τ tb n + tb n e t µb. Therefore µb e t. To finish the proof we proceed as above.

Acknowledgements We would like to thank Rados law Adamczak for his useful comments regarding concentration estimates for Lipschitz functions. This research was supported in part by the Institute for Mathematics and its Applications with funds provided by the National Science Foundation. References [A] R. Adamczak, Logarithmic Sobolev inequalities and concentration of measure for convex functions and polynomial chaoses. Bull. Pol. Acad. Sci. Math. 53 005, no., 38. [AS] S. Aida, D. Stroock, Moment estimates derived from Poincaré and logarithmic Sobolev inequalities. Math. Res. Lett. 994, no., 75 86. [ASt] R. Adamczak, M. Strzelecki, Modified logarithmic Sobolev inequalities for convex functions, preprint to be submitted on arxiv [BG] S. Bobkov, F. Götze, Discrete isoperimetric and Poincaré-type inequalities. Probab. Theory Related Fields 4 999, no., 45 77. [BG] S. G. Bobkov, F. Götze, Exponential integrability and transportation cost related to logarithmic Sobolev inequalities. J. Funct. Anal. 63 999, no., 8. [BL] S. Bobkov, M. Ledoux, Poincaré s inequalities and Talagrand s concentration phenomenon for the exponential distribution. Probab. Theory Related Fields 07 997, no. 3, 383 400. [GRST] N. Gozlan, C. Roberto, P.M. Samson, and P. Tetali, Kantorovich duality for general transport costs and applications, preprint 04, arxiv:4.7480. [G] L. Gross, Leonard Logarithmic Sobolev inequalities. Amer. J. Math. 97 975, no. 4, 06 083. [K] Ch. Klaassen, On an inequality of Chernoff. Ann. Probab. 3 985, no. 3, 966 974. [LW] R. Lata la, J. O. Wojtaszczyk, On the infimum convolution inequality, Studia Math. 89 008, 47 87. [L] M. Ledoux, The concentration of measure phenomenon. Mathematical Surveys and Monographs, 89. American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 00. [M] B. Maurey, Some deviation inequalities, Geom. Funct. Anal. 99, 88 97. [Mu] B. Muckenhoupt, Hardy s inequality with weights. Studia Math. 44 97, 3 38. [T] M. Talagrand, An isoperimetric theorem on the cube and the Kintchine-Kahane inequalities. Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 04 988, no. 3, 905 909.