Measuring poverty. Araar Abdelkrim and Duclos Jean-Yves. PEP-PMMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June overty and. olitiques.

Similar documents
The decomposition of inequality and poverty

CIRPÉE Centre interuniversitaire sur le risque, les politiques économiques et l emploi

An algorithm for computing the Shapley Value

On Measuring Growth and Inequality. Components of Changes in Poverty. with Application to Thailand

Inequality, poverty and redistribution

ECON 361 Assignment 1 Solutions

Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Empirical Issues

Poverty and Distributional Outcomes of Shocks and Policies

Consistent multidimensional poverty comparisons

Poverty and Inequality Components: a Micro Framework

The Role of Inequality in Poverty Measurement

COMPUTATIONAL TOOLS FOR POVERTY MEASUREMENT AND ANALYSIS

An Atkinson Gini family of social evaluation functions. Abstract

Welfare, Inequality & Poverty, # 4

On the decomposition of the Gini index: An exact approach

On the Mean of Squared Deprivation Gaps

Inequality and Envy. Frank Cowell and Udo Ebert. London School of Economics and Universität Oldenburg

Evaluating Dimensional and Distributional Contributions to Multidimensional Poverty

Counting and Multidimensional Poverty Measurement

Pro poor growth : a partial ordering approach

PRESENTATION ON THE TOPIC ON INEQUALITY COMPARISONS PRESENTED BY MAG.SYED ZAFAR SAEED

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 07-07

OPHI WORKING PAPER NO. 100

DECOMPOSITION OF NORMALIZATION AXIOM IN THE MEASUREMENT OF POVERTY: A COMMENT. Nanak Kakwani. Nanak Kakwani is a Senior Fellow at WIDER.

Poverty measures and poverty orderings

CIRPÉE Centre interuniversitaire sur le risque, les politiques économiques et l emploi

GROWTH AND INCOME MOBILITY: AN AXIOMATIC ANALYSIS

Ranking income distributions: a rank-dependent and needs-based approach

Statistical Inference for Stochastic Dominance and for the Measurement of Poverty and Inequality

POVERTY AND EQUITY: MEASUREMENT, POLICY AND ESTIMATION WITH DAD

The Dynamics of Poverty: A Review of Decomposition Approaches and Application to Data From Burkina Faso

Extensions to the Concentration Index: Inequality Aversion and the Health Achievement Index

Wages and housing transfers in China Inequality decomposition by source using copulas

INEQUALITY, POLARIZATION AND POVERTY IN NIGERIA. Awoyemi Taiwo Timothy Oluwatayo Isaac Busayo Oluwakemi Adewusi

Conciliating absolute and relative poverty: Income poverty measurement with two poverty lines.

Variance estimation for Generalized Entropy and Atkinson indices: the complex survey data case

Robust Multidimensional Poverty Comparisons

A new index combining the absolute and relative aspects of income poverty: theory and application

The measurement of welfare change

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION

Multi-dimensional Human Development Measures : Trade-offs and Inequality

Rolf Aaberge and Magne Mogstad

Inequality Measures and the Median:

More on multidimensional, intertemporal and chronic poverty orderings

Inequality, Poverty, and Stochastic Dominance

Multifactor Inequality: Substitution Effects for Income Sources in Mexico

Multidimensional Poverty Measurement and Analysis

Measuring Inequality for the Rural Households of Eritrea Using Lorenz Curve and Gini Coefficient

Food Price Shocks and Poverty: The Left Hand Side

Inequality Measurement and the Rich: Why inequality increased more than we thought

Household Heterogeneity and Inequality Measurement

Stochastic Dominance

OPHI WORKING PAPER NO. 77

Consistent Comparison of Pro-Poor Growth

Unit-consistency and polarization of income distributions

Heterogeneity. Krishna Pendakur. May 24, Krishna Pendakur () Heterogeneity May 24, / 21

Session III: New ETSI Model on Wideband Speech and Noise Transmission Quality Phase II. STF Validation results

Robust inequality comparisons

Contributions to the measurement of relative p-bipolarisation 1. Marek Kosny University of Wroclaw. and. Gaston Yalonetzky University of Leeds

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Assessing deprivation with ordinal variables: Depth sensitivity and poverty aversion

Dynamics of Growth, Poverty, and Inequality

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Survey nonresponse and the distribution of income

Measurement of Inequality and Social Welfare

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson.

Inequality: Measurement

Adjusting the HDI for Inequality: An Overview of Different Approaches, Data Issues, and Interpretations

Consumer Demand and the Cost of Living

The Impossibility of a Just Pigouvian

The Balance of Inequality: A rediscovery of the Gini s R concentration ratio and a new inequality

Gini, Deprivation and Complaints. Frank Cowell. London School of Economics. Revised July 2005

The Economics of Poverty and Inequality: Introduction. Frank Cowell London School of Economics

Intertemporal pro-poorness

The Measurement of Inequality, Concentration, and Diversification.

Anomalies in Exact Renomalization Group

The econometrics of inequality and poverty Lecture 8: Confidence intervals and testing

12 Lorenz line and Gini index

by John A. Weymark Working Paper No. 03-W14R July 2003 Revised January 2004 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235

Income Inequality, Trade and Financial Openness

MEASURING THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC BIPOLARIZATION PHENOMENON

Decomposing changes in multidimensional poverty in 10 countries.

Bayesian Inference for TIP curves: An Application to Child Poverty in Germany

Distribution-sensitive multidimensional poverty measures with an application to India

Reference Groups and Individual Deprivation

Top 10% share Top 1% share /50 ratio

An Axiomatic Approach To Systemic Risk

Selection of small area estimation method for Poverty Mapping: A Conceptual Framework

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty

Optimum Value of Poverty Measure Using Inverse Optimization Programming Problem

Erasmus Research Institute of Management. KEI Workshop, Leuven, 5-6 September 2006

Discussion Papers. Satya R. Chakravarty, Conchita D Ambrosio and Pietro Muliere. Target Shortfall Orderings and Indices

Leftist, Rightist and Intermediate Decompositions of Poverty Variations with an Application to China from 1990 to 2003

INEQUALITY, WELFARE AND ORDER STATISTICS

THE EXTENDED ATKINSON FAMILY: THE CLASS OF MULTIPLICATIVELY DECOMPOSABLE INEQUALITY MEASURES, AND SOME NEW GRAPHICAL PROCEDURES FOR ANALYSTS

CONSTRUCTING POVERTY RANKINGS FOR STATE SUBREGIONS: A CASE STUDY OF NORTH CAROLINA

ROBUST MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY COMPARISONS*

Index-Number Tests and the Common-Scaling Social Cost-of-Living Index 1

Poverty comparisons with endogenous absolute poverty lines

Transcription:

E Measuring poverty Araar Abdelkrim and Duclos Jean-Yves E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 1/43

roperties of overty Indices Main properties of poverty indices: A- Focus axiom overty is invariant to income changes of the non-poor if these non-poor do not become poor E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 2/43

Axioms of overty Indices B- Anonymity overty does not depend on information other living standards or incomes. C- opulation rinciple overty should be invariant to replications of the population: merging two identical distributions should not alter poverty. D- Scale Invariance overty is homogeneous of degree zero with respect to incomes Y and the poverty line z such as: (λy, λz) = (Y, z) E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 3/43

roperties of overty Indices E- Monotonicity overty declines, or does not rise, following an increase in the incomes of the poor. F- The igou-dalton Transfer rinciple overty should be sensitive to inequality within the poor: transfers from poorer to richer increases poverty. G- Subgroup Decomposability Total poverty is a weighted mean of poverty levels within each group. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 4/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms A- THE EDE AROACH One can identify a set of poverty indices that are linked by their functional form to the EDE income principe. A general form of these indices is: E (z; ρ, ǫ) = z ξ (z; ρ, ǫ) (1) where: ξ (z; ρ, ǫ) is the EDE income of the distribution of censored income and censored income: Q (p; z) = min(z, Q(p)). If we note the average censored income by µ (z), we can write what follows: (z; ρ, ǫ) = z µ (z) + c (z; ρ, ǫ) }{{}}{{} Average Gap Cost of Inequality (2) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 5/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms Example: Suppose that: arameters of aversion to inequality: ǫ = 0 and ρ = 2. With this, the EDE income is defined as follows: ξ(ρ = 2, ǫ = 0) = where y 1 y 2...y i y i+1... y n. Let the poverty line be z = 400. E 2(n i) + 1 n 2 y i (3) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 6/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms E Table 1: Illustrative Example Rank i Q(p i ) = y i Q (p i, z) = yi w i = 2(n i)+1 n 2 w i yi 1 100 100 0.31 30.56 2 200 200 0.25 50.00 3 300 300 0.19 58.33 4 400 400 0.14 55.56 5 500 400 0.08 33.33 6 600 400 0.03 11.11 Average 350 300 ξ (z; ρ, ǫ) = X i w i y i = 238.89 (4) c (z; ρ, ǫ) = µ (z) ξ (z; ρ, ǫ) = 61.11 (5) (z; ρ, ǫ) = 400 300 + 61.11 {z} {z} {z } z µ (z) c (z;ρ,ǫ) = 161.11 (6) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 7/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms E opular EDE overty Indices The Clark-Hemming-Ulph s overty Index : (z; ρ = 1, ǫ) = The Watts Index : ) 1 1 ǫ ( 1 z 0 Q (p; z) (1 ǫ) dp, when ǫ 1, ( ) 1 z exp 0 ln(q (p; z))dp, when ǫ = 1. W(z) = 1 0 ( ln z Q (p; z) (7) ) dp. (8) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 8/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms The Chakravarty Index : C(z; ǫ) = 1 E opular EDE overty Indices 1 0 ( Q ) 1 ǫ (p; z) dp, 0 ǫ < 1. (9) The S-Gini overty Index : When ǫ = 0, we obtain the class of S-Gini indices of poverty: (z; ρ) (z; ρ, ǫ = 0) = z z 1 0 Q (p; z)ω(p; ρ)dp (10) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 9/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms E opular Gap overty Indices overty gap indices are simply functions of poverty gaps, g i = max(z y i, 0). Denoting the weight on income y i as ω i, a general form for this class of indices is: (z) = n ω i g i (11) i=1 If the weight is simply the proportion of individuals that have income y i, then the index equals the average poverty gap. E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 10/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms The most popular class of poverty gap indices is the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (FGT) poverty indices: (z; α) = n w i gi α = i=1 When α > 1, the weight ω i = w i g (α 1) i E n i=1 w ii(g i > 0) when α = 0 n i=1 w ig i when α = 1, n i=1 w ig (α 1) i g i when α > 1, increases with gaps. When α > 1, this poverty index respects the igou-dalton transfer axiom. (12) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 11/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms Define the normalised poverty gap by ḡ i (z) = g i z ; the normalised FGT poverty index is then defined as: (z, α) = E n w i ḡi α (13) This normalised poverty index decreases with the parameter α since: (z, α) α = i=1 n p i ḡi α logḡ i 0 (14) The contribution of the poorest to total poverty, after an increase in the parameter α, may seem ambiguous. i=1 E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 12/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms Figure 1: Contribution of poverty gaps to FGT indices 1 g(p;z)/z E (g(p;z)/z) 3 Q(p)/z (g(p;z)/z) 2 F(z) p E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 13/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms Note that the relative contribution of the poorest increases with an increase in the parameter α, as showed in the following figure: Figure 2: Relative Contribution of poverty gaps to FGT indices 1/F(z) 1 2 g(p) /(z; α=2) E g(p) /(z; α=1) F( µ g (z)) F(z) p E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 14/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms EDE poverty gaps for FGT indices FGT indices for general values of α are difficult to interpret since these indices are averages of powers of poverty gaps. They are also neither unit-free nor money-metric (except for α = 0 and 1). A simple solution to these two problems is to transform the FGT indices into EDE (Equally Distributed Equivalent) poverty gaps as follows: E ξ g (z; α) = [(z; α)] 1/α. (15) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 15/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms The FGT EDE poverty gaps are as follows: where E ξ g (z; α) = z µ (z) + }{{} c(z; α) }{{} Average Gap Cost of Inequality (16) c(z; α) = ξ g (z; α) ξ g (z; α = 1) (17) The normalised EDE poverty gap index is defined as follows: ξ g (z; α) = ξg (z; α) z (18) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 16/43

overty Indices and Functional Forms Note that the EDE poverty gap respects the igou-dalton transfer axiom. Also, the EDE poverty gap index increases with α: ξ g (z; α) α E = ξ g [ n i=1 p ig α i log(g i) α(z; α) ] log((z; α)) α 2 > 0 (19) Note that the S-Gini poverty index belongs to the class of poverty gap indices: (z; ρ) (z; ρ, ǫ = 0) = z = = 1 0 1 0 1 0 Q (p; z)ω(p; ρ)dp (20) (z Q (p; z))ω(p; ρ)dp (21) g(p; z)ω(p; ρ)dp (22) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 17/43

Group-decomposable poverty indices Among desirable properties of poverty indices is their decomposability across population groups. This type of decomposition allows researchers and pmakers to identify the contribution of each group to total poverty. Among the most popular indices that obey the decomposability axiom across groups are FGT, the Chakravarty and the Watts indices. In general, the decomposition of these indices takes the following form: (z; α) = E K φ(k)(k; z; α) (23) where (k; z; α) and φ(k) are respectively the poverty index and the population share of group k. k E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 18/43

Group-decomposable poverty indices Starting from the last equation, the intensity of the contribution of each group to total poverty depends on the poverty of that group and its share in the population. E Table 2: Illustrative Example Group k φ(k) (k; z; α) Absolute Relative Contribution Contribution 1 0.2 0.8 0.16 1/3 2 0.8 0.4 0.32 2/3 Total 1.0 0.48 1.0 E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 19/43

inequality Two main factors determine the level of poverty. These are the average income and the level of inequality. When inequality equals zero, the two most basic indices of poverty (the average poverty gap and the headcount) depend on the difference between average income and the poverty line. Recall that the Lorenz curve gives a complete picture of relative income inequalities. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 20/43

inequality The link between the headcount index and poverty is: E L (H) = z µ The link between the average poverty gap index and inequality is: where (24) 1 = [z µ p ] H (25) L(H) = Hµ p µ The link between the severity index and poverty is: where (µ)l (p) = Q(p). 2 = H 0 (26) [z (µ)l (p)] 2 dp (27) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 21/43

inequality Starting from these links, we find that the cost of inequality equals to: c(z) = 2 1 = H 0 E [ z 2 2zQ(p) + Q(p) 2 z + µ p ] dp (28) What is the link between the standard Gini index and poverty indices? The Gini index is easily decomposable across poor and non-poor groups, such that: I = φ p ψ p I p + φ np ψ np I np + Ĩ (29) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 22/43

inequality L(p) 0.2.4.6.8 1 0.2.4.6.8 1 ercentiles (p) Between Group Inequality E Lorenz Curve & overty Contribution of the non poor group ECAM I: Cameroon (1996) Contribution of the poor group E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 23/43

inequality The link between headcount index and the between group inequality is as follows: ( ) 1 H = µĩ (30) µ µ p overty gap index can be expressed as follows: ( ) z µp 1 = µĩ µ µ p Finally, the link between the Gini Index and 2 cannot be established directly. This is explained by the different shapes. that the distribution can have, with the same level of inequality, measured by Gini index. E (31) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 24/43

overty curves overty Gap Curve g(z; p) This curve indicates simply the poverty gap at a given percentile of population p. The curve naturally decreases with the rank p in the population, and reaches zero at the value of p equal to the headcount. The integral under the curve gives the average poverty gap. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 25/43

overty curves Cumulative overty Gap Curve G(z; p) This curve is defined as follows: G(p; z) = p 0 E g(p; z)dq (32) The slope of this curve is non negative and equals to g(z; p). The level of concavity of this curve at p [0, H] expresses the level of inequality within the group of the poor. E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 26/43

overty curves µ g (z) Figure 3: The cumulative poverty gap curve G(p;z) E A B 0 F(z) 1 p E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 27/43

Normalised overty Indices The normalised FGT index is: (z; α) = 1 The derived EDE poverty gap lies between 0 and 1. 0 E ḡ(p; z) α dp (33) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 28/43

Normalised overty Indices This makes poverty indices independent of the monetary units. This makes the indices invariant to an equi-proportionate change in all incomes and in the poverty line. Normalised poverty indices can make poverty lines act as price indices. If real poverty lines can differ according to regions or time, absolute and normalised poverty indices can give different results concerning the level of poverty. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 29/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions As indicated above, poverty depends on two main factors which are average income and inequality. This implies that a difference in poverty across two distributions depends on the change in average income (Growth) and the change in levels of inequality (Redistribution). Suppose that one tries to explain the difference in poverty between distributions A and B using the Growth and the Redistribution components. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 30/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions To assess the impact of Growth, one can scale incomes of A by (µ B /µ A ) and estimate the growth effect on poverty as: ( ( ) ) zµa Growth Effect = A ; α A (z; α) (34) µ B To assess the impact of Redistribution, one can scale incomes of B by (µ A /µ B ) and estimate the redistribution effect on poverty as: Redistribution Effect = E ( ( zµb B ) ; α µ A Note that the reference period is the first one (A). ) A (z; α) (35) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 31/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions If one uses the second periods (B) as the referenced period, one find what follows: Growth Effect = Redistribution Effect = E ( B (α) B ( z; µ B ( B (z; α) A ( )) ; α µ A z; µ )) A ; α µ B These types of decomposition generates a residue, such that: Variation in overty = Growth Effect + Redistribution Effect + Residue (38) (36) (37) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 32/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions To remove the arbitrariness, that raises from the choice of the referenced period and causes the error term, one can adopts the Shapley approach where the Shapley-factors are the referenced periods. B (z; ( α) ( A (z; α) ) ) ( ( )) zµa zµb = 0.5 A ; α A (z; α) + B (z; α) B ; α µ B µ A }{{} Shapley growth effect E ( +0.5 ( B } (39) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 33/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions Example: Suppose that: overty line: z = 400. All incomes have increased proportionally by 20% in period B. The government redistributes a part of income through income taxes, such that: The excess of incomes over the poverty line is taxed by 20%: T i = 0.2 max(0, y i z)) The poor receives an allocation of the amount A = n i=1 T i H E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 34/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions E Table 3: Illustrative example Rank i Y A g A i Y B (G) g B i (G) Y B (G, R) g B i (G, R) 1 100 300 120 280 160 220 2 200 200 240 160 280 100 3 300 100 360 040 400 000 4 400 000 480 000 464 000 5 500 000 600 000 560 000 6 600 000 720 000 656 000 Average 350 100 420 070 420 060 1 B 1 A {z } 40 = Growth Effect {z } 20 + Redistribution Effect {z } 20 (40) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 35/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions E Table 4: Illustrative Example Rank i Y A Y B Y (µ B, I A ) Y (µ A, I B ) 1 100 080 120 066.66 2 200 220 240 183.33 3 300 340 360 283.33 4 400 560 480 466.66 Average 250 300 300 250 1 050 050 035 062.5 Y (µ B, I A ) = Y A µ B (41) µ A Y (µ A, I B ) = Y B µ A µ B (42) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 36/43

Growth-redistribution Decompositions Reference period is A: Reference period is B: GE = (Y (µ B, I A )) (Y A ) = 35 50 = 15.00 RE = (Y (µ A, I B )) (Y A ) = 62.5 50 = 12.50 GE = (Y B ) (Y (µ A, I B )) = 50 62.50 = 12.50 RE = (Y B ) (Y (µ B, I A )) = 50 35 = 15.00 Shapley decomposition: E GE = 13.75 RE = 13.75 E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 37/43

Sectoral Decompositions Recall that the absolute contribution of group k, noted by E(k), to total poverty is defined as follows: E E(k) = φ(k)(k; z, α) (43) Between two periods or two distributions A and B, the change in total poverty equals the sum of changes in group contributions, such that: B (z; α) A (z; α) = K (E B (k; z, α) E A (k; z, α)) (44) k=1 The change in the contribution of group k is defined as follows: E B (k; z, α) E A (k; z, α) = φ B (k) B (k; z, α) φ A (k) A (k; z, α) (45) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 38/43

Sectoral Decompositions For a given group k, one can use the reference period A to estimate the impact of the change in poverty or in the proportion of this group on the change of its contribution, such that: E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 39/43 E overty Impact(k) = φ A (k) ( B (k, z, α) A (k, z, α) ) (46) Demographic Impact(k) = A (k, z, α)(φ B (k) φ A (k)) (47) Starting from this, differences in poverty can be expressed as follows: B (z; α) A (z; α) = K k φ A(k) ( B (k; z; α) A (k; z; α) ) }{{} within-group poverty effects + K k + A (k; z; α) (φ B (k) φ A (k)) }{{} demographic or sectoral effects K ( B (k; z; α) A (k; z; α)(φ B (k) φ A (k)) ). k } {{ } interaction or error term (48)

Sectoral Decompositions To remove the arbitrariness in the choice of the reference period as well as the residual, one can apply the Shapley approach. With this approach the sectoral decomposition is as follows: E B (z; α) A (z; α) = K k φ(k) ( B (k; z; α) A (k; z; α) ) }{{} within-group poverty effects + K k (k; z; α) (φ B (k) φ A (k)) }{{} demographic or sectoral effects (49) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 40/43

Impact of demographic changes One can simulate the impact of a proportional increase in the population share of group t on poverty. Specifically, suppose that: The population share of group t increases proportionally by λ. The population share of other groups falls proportionally to keep the condition K φ(k)φ(t) k=1 = 1φ(k) satisfied (the share falls by The impact of this on poverty is then: (z; α) = (t; z; α) k t E φ(k) 1 φ(t) 1 φ(t) ). (k; z; α) φ(t)λ (50) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 41/43

Impact of demographic changes One can also simulate the impact of an absolute increase in the population share of group t on poverty. Specifically, suppose that: The population share of group t increases by λ. The population share of other groups falls proportionally to keep the condition K λφ(k) k=1 = 1φ(k) satisfied (the share falls by The impact of this on poverty is then: (z; α) = (t; z; α) k t E φ(k) 1 φ(t) 1 φ(t) ). (k; z; α) λ (51) E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 42/43

Decomposing by income sources By supposing that total income equals the sum of C income sources, the question is: How does each component contribute to the alleviation of poverty? It is clear that in the absences of all of these sources, the gap of each individu equals the poverty line. For the non poor, the sum of component exceeds the poverty line. How then can one estimate the contribution of any component? Again here, one can use the Shapley approach to overpass the arbitrariness of the order of the choice of components. To do this, we suppose that the marginal contribution of component c in reducing poverty, is simply the reduction in poverty after adding this component to an initial set of components. E E-MMA training workshop Addis Ababa, June 2006 Distributive Analysis and overty - p. 43/43