Nonlinear DSGE model with Asymmetric Adjustment Costs under ZLB:

Similar documents
Estimating a Nonlinear New Keynesian Model with the Zero Lower Bound for Japan

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Estimating a Nonlinear New Keynesian Model with the Zero Lower Bound for Japan

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND: FREQUENCY, DURATION,

Variance Decomposition Analysis for Nonlinear DSGE Models: An Application with ZLB

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

DSGE Models in a Liquidity Trap and Japan s Lost Decade

Piecewise Linear Continuous Approximations and Filtering for DSGE Models with Occasionally-Binding Constraints

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Under Remittance Fluctuations. Technical Appendix and Additional Results

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach

Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS NEAR THE ZLB: A TALE OF TWO COUNTRIES. S. Bora ğan Aruoba Pablo Cuba-Borda Frank Schorfheide

Sequential Monte Carlo Methods (for DSGE Models)

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Zero Lower Bound and Parameter Bias in an Estimated DSGE Model

DSGE Methods. Estimation of DSGE models: Maximum Likelihood & Bayesian. Willi Mutschler, M.Sc.

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Escaping the Great Recession 1

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Title. Description. Remarks and examples. stata.com. stata.com. Introduction to DSGE models. intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge

Y t = log (employment t )

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Learning and Global Dynamics

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Ambiguous Business Cycles: Online Appendix

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

The Empirical Implications of the Interest-Rate Lower Bound

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Forecasting using a Nonlinear DSGE Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Lecture on State Dependent Government Spending Multipliers

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession?

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

Are Uncertainty Shocks Aggregate Demand Shocks?

DSGE Model Econometrics

Point, Interval, and Density Forecast Evaluation of Linear versus Nonlinear DSGE Models

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Macroeconomics Theory II

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

On the Empirical (Ir)Relevance of the Zero Lower Bound Constraint

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Implementable Fiscal Policy Rules

The importance of timevarying. in new Keynesian models with zero lower bound SFB E C O N O M I C R I S K B E R L I N

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Discussion Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound

1 The Basic RBC Model

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Non-Markovian Regime Switching with Endogenous States and Time-Varying State Strengths

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Latent variables and shocks contribution in DSGE models with occasionally binding constraints

Bayesian Computations for DSGE Models

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Looking for the stars

Transcription:

Nonlinear DSGE model with Asymmetric Adjustment Costs under ZLB: Bayesian Estimation with Particle Filter for Japan Hirokuni Iiboshi Tokyo Metropolitan University Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office and Mototsugu Shintani University of Tokyo Vanderbilt University Febrary 6 Abstract From the viewpoint of Bayesian approach with particle filter, we estimate the latest Japanese economy between 985Q3 and 5Q including more than one decade zero interest rate policy, using a nonlinear New Keynesian DSGE models extending asymmetric adjustment costs (AAC to Rotemberg price setting mechanism and zero lower bound (ZLB to monetary policy rule. Model selection in terms of marginal likelihood shows that the both ZLB and AAC overwhelmingly contribute to explain fluctuations of his output growth, inflation and nominal interest rate. This result indicates that the adjustment costs in rising prices are about 33-48% higher than ones in dropping prices, and that the policy function of inflation is mostly likely to be shaped as strong convex, because the ZLB amplifies deflation and the AAC inhibits rising price level. The wide curved policy functions make the effects of monetary policy shock much more uncertain expressing as spread credible bands of the impulse responses, whereas variations of estimated structural shocks are rarely influenced in spite of adding both assumptions. We also report models with only the ZLB constraint mislead the effect of monetary policy to output and inflation over-estimated when we estimate Japan. Keywords, New Keynesian model, zero lower bound, Rotemberg price setting, policy function iterations, projection method, particle filter Metropolis-Hastings algorithm JEL Classifications, C, C3, C5 The views expressed herein are of our own and do not represent those of the organizations the authors belongs to.

Introduction Motivation We apply a nonlinear New Keynesian (NK DSGE extended to two aspects to Japanese economy for the last thirty years including so called Bubble boom and Lost decade by using advance techniques for solving and estimating models. What difference between nonlinear and linear DSGE models when estimating Japan. Related Literature What difference between nonlinear and linear NK DSGE models under zero lower bound (ZLB were studied by Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (5. Richter et al. (4 concluded that a time iteration method with linear interpolation (TL has got the best balance between speed and precision for solving nonlinear DSGE models under ZLB within the class of policy function iteration. Recently, a textbook dealing with Bayesian estimation for DSGE including nonlinear model has been published by Herbst and Schorfheide (6. Gust et al. (3 estimated a nonlinear New Keynesian (NK DSGE under ZLB for US, using particle filter Metropolis-Hastings (PFMH algorithm. Aruoba et al (4 and Aruoba and Schorfhide (5 estimated a New Keynesian DSGE under ZLB with regime switching of target inflation for Japan as well as US and EU. What we do Instead of considering regime switching of target inflation, we focus on asymmetry adjustment costs with respect to the target inflation (or steady state of inflation. And we combine TL method for solving a nonlinear model provided by Richter et al. (4 and PFMH explained by Herbst and Schorfheide (6, and extend the NK model estimated by Gust et al. (3 to adding aymmetric adjustment costs in order to estimate deflation for the last three decades in Japan, between 985:Q3 and 5:Q. Model selection in terms of marginal likelihood shows that the both assumptions overwhelmingly contribute to explain fluctuations of his output growth, inflation and nominal interest rate. This result indicates that the adjustment costs in rising prices are about 33-48% higher than ones in dropping prices, and that the policy function of inflation is mostly likely to be shaped as strong convex, because the ZLB amplifies deflation and the AAC inhibits rising price level.

The wide curved policy functions make the effects of monetary policy shock much more uncertain expressing as spread credible bands of the impulse responses, whereas variations of estimated structural shocks are rarely influenced in spite of adding both assumptions. We also report only the ZLB constraint misleads the effect of monetary policy to output growth and inflation over-estimated when we estimate Japan. Model We embed the following two assumptions in a small-scale New Keynesian DSGE model that studied by An and Schorfheide (7 and Herbst and Schorfheide (6, and numerically solve a rational expectations equilibrium (REE directly from a nonlinear original model but not a log-linearized version studied by the previous researches.. Monetary Policy under ZLB Monetary policy rule is constrained by ZLB and written as R t = max(, R ρ R t R ρ R t e ɛ R,t, ( where R t is the gross nominal interest rate, R t is nominal target rate and ɛ R,t is monetary policy shock. The nominal target rate, R t, is given as 3 where π and Yt respectively. ( Rt = rπ πt ( ψ ψ Yt, ( π Yt is inflation target (or steady state of inflation and output target,. Asymmetric Adjustment Cost (AAC Adjustment costs (AC adopted by Rotemberg 4 are etented to variant costs with asymmetrically state-dependent on inflation, π t, as below. AC t (j = φ(π t ( Pt (j P t (j π Y t (j, (3 { φ (= ( + δφ > φ, if φ(π t = φ, if P t(j (= π P t (j t π P t(j (= π, P t (j t < π Aruba et al (4 and Aruoba and Schorfhide (5 also used the model and extent it to regime switching model under ZLB. We exten Eq. (. of Herbst and Schorfheide (6 to monetary policy rule under ZLB. 3 Eq.( is corresponding to Eq. (. of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 4 We exten Eq. (.6 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6 toasymmetric adjustment costs. 3

where φ(π t is coefficient of the AC and δ is fraction of the cost generated when rising prices against when decline of prices. Although asymmetric adjustment costs (AAC were studied by Kim and Ruge-Murcia (9, our setting is easy and intuitive to show that the costs kink around the steady state of inflation, π, and that the costs when rising price of goods are higher than when dropping the prices..3 Agencys Firms Monopolistically competitive intermediate goods producing firms maximize the present value of future profits: Π, 5 under the following two conditions. = Et [ s= ( ] β s Pt+s (j Q t+s t Y t+s (j W t+s N t+s (j AC t+s (j, P t where β is discount factor. The one condition is the demand for intermediate goods, j, given by 6 ( /ν Pt (j Y t (j = Y t, P t where ν is inverse elasticity of demand for goods j. And the other is the linear production technology as 7 Y t (j = A t N t (j, where A t and N t (j are exogenous common productivity process and the labor input of firm j, respectively. Households The households maximize utilities, U, under the budget constraint 8 U = E t [ s= β s ( (Ct+s /A t+s τ τ + χ M ln ( Mt+s P t+s ] χ H H t+s, where τ is inverse elasticity of intertemporal substitution of consumption. And the household s budget constraint is 9 P t C t + B t + M t + T t = P t W t H t + R t B t + M t + P t D t + P t SC t, 5 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.7 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 6 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.3 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 7 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.5 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 8 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.8 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 9 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.9 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 4

Government The government s budget is given by constraint P t G t + R t B t + M t = T t + B t + M t, and the government s expenditure is described by G t = ( gt Y t. (4.4 Exogenous Shocks Aggregate productivity evolves as nonstationary process as below. ln A t = ln γ + ln A t + ln z t, ln z t = ρ z ln z t + ɛ z,t, (5 where γ stands for average technology growth rate, z t is the exogenous fluctuation of the technology growth rate and ɛ z,t is the productivity shock. The fraction of government to aggregate ouput is given by ln g t = ( ρ g ln g + ρ g ln g t + ɛ g,t, (6 where ɛ g,t is government shock. This shock could be regarded as a aggregate exogenous demand shock..5 Equilibrium Relationships The potential aggregate output (or target level of output in the monetary policy rule 3 The market clearing conditions are given by 4 Y t = ( ν /τ A t g t, (7 Y t = C t + G t + AC t, N t = H t, (8 The optimality conditions of households (or the consumption Euler equation: 5 [ (Ct+ τ /A t+ A t = βe t C t /A t A t+ And the optimality conditions of intermediate firms: 6 R t π t+ This equation is corresponding to Eq. (. of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.3 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.4 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 3 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.9 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 4 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.5 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 5 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.7 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. 6 This equation is corresponding to Eq. (.8 of Herbst and Schorfheide (6. ] (9 5

[( = φ(π t (π t π π t + ν [ (Ct+ /A t+ φ( E t (π t+ βe t C t /A t [ ( τ ] Ct. + ν A t π π t+ ] τ Y t+ /A t+ Y t /A t (π t+ ππ t+ ] ( Notice that due to asymmetric adjustment costs the sizes of φ(π t and φ(e t (π t+ in the first and the second terms of the RHS depend on the values of current inflation, π t, and expected inflation, E t (π t+, respectively..6 Variations of our Models To solve our nonlinear models, we use above ten equations ( through ( corresponding to ten endogenous variables: Y t, Yt, C t, G t, AC t, π t, R t, Rt, A t, g t, and three exogenous structural shocks: ε R,t, ε z,t, ε g,t. And there are 5 parameters such as β, τ, ν, φ, δ, ψ, ψ, γ, π, ρ r, ρ g, ρ z, σ r, σ g, σ z, all of which are estimated. The definitions of the parameters are summarized in Table. We examine and estimate four models classified with respect to the two assumptions. The four models are summarized in Table. Model : in absence of the ZLB and the AAC Model : in presence of the ZLB Model 3: in presence of the AAC Model 4: in presence of both the ZLB and the AAC Here, we incorporate the standard monetary policy rule, R t = R ρ R t R ρ R t e ɛ R,t, into the models in absence of the ZLB binds, instead of Eq.(. In the models in absence of the AAC, we use a invariant coefficient, φ, in Eq.(3, instead of φ(π t. [ Insert Table and Table ] 3 Solution and Estimation Methods 3. Projection Method The model is solved using a time iteration method with linear interpolation (TL within the class of projection methods (or policy function iteration methods. Richtcher et al. (4 reported TL provides the best balance between speed and accuracy. In 6

addition, TL outperforms time iteration with Chebyshev polynominal, which is the popular method in the class of policy function iteration, when the ZLB constraint is embeded. The model s decision rules (or policy functions can be written as ( Y t /A t, π t, R t = P( R t, g t, z t ε R,t, ( where Y t /A t, π t, and R t in the LHS are control variables in the decision rules and R t, g t, z t, and ε R,t in the RHS are state variables of the function. We specify nine grid points on each continurous state variables which implies 79 nodes. The Appendix shows our solving method. 3. PFMH We estimate the nonlinear model using Bayesian methods with particle filter, following Gust et al. (. Particle filter Metropolis-Hastings algorithm (PFMH, or Particle Markov Chain Monte Carlo (PMCMC, was established in Andrieu et al. (. We describe the algorithm in the Appendix following Herbst and Schorfheide (6, ch 8 and ch 9. After solving for the decision rule, P( R t, g t, z t, ε R,t, our economic environment can be represented as nonlinear state space model consisting of the following two equations ( and (3. State Equations The policy functions, Eq.(, are used as a state equation for estimation by combined with Eq. (, (5 and (6, and rewritten as s t = Φ(s t, ε t, θ, ( where s t is endogenous variables: s t = ( Y t /A t, π t, R t, g t, z t, and ε t = ( ε R,t, ε g,t, ε z,t. θ is the parametars. Measurement Equations A measurement equation represents connection between endogenous variables and observed variables as y t = ψ(s t, θ + u t, where y t is observed variables and u t is measurement errors. We set the measurement equation as Eq. (3. Y GR t INF L t INT t = /4 (ln (Y t /A t ln (Y t /A t + ln z t + ln γ ln π t ln R t + u y,t u π,t u r,t. (3 7

where three observations in the LHS are adopted for estimation: quarter-to-quarter real GDP growth rate (YGR, annualized quarter-to-quarter inflation rates (INFL, and annualized nominal interest rates (INT. These three series are measured in percentage. 3.3 Data and Prior Setting Data and Sample Period We estimate the model using Japan data on output growth ( y t, inflation (π t, and nominal interest rate rates (R t from 985:Q3 through 5:Q. Following Aruoba et al. (4, we collect real GDP figures from the Cabinet Office s National Accounts. We used the statistical release of benchmark year 5 that cover the period 994Q- 5Q. To extend the sample, we collected them from the benchmark year release and spanned the period 985Q3-5Q. For the price level we use the implicit GDP deflator index from the Cabinet Office. We also extend the benchmark year 5 release using the growth rate of the index from the benchmark year release in the same way as real GDP. For the nominal interest rate we use the Bank of Japan s uncollateralized call rate and transformed monthly figures to quarterly averages over the sample period. Prior setting Table shows the prior disributions of the structural parameters. These distributions are assumed to be independent across parameters. 4 Empirical Results 4. Posterior Estimations and Model Selection Table shows log marginal likelihoods and posterior model probabilities of the four models. And Table 3 shows posterior means and 9% credible intervals of 5 parameters of the models. As Table, Models 3 and 4 holding the assumption of the AAC have much higher the likelihood than Models and without the AAC, so that the AAC must be the necessary assumption to explain deflations during the last three decades in Japan. In addition, since posterior model probability of Model 4 is as much as 97.7%, the model including the ZLB and the AAC is thought to be very close to the true model among the four models. On the other hand, that the likelihood of Model is lower than the reference model, Model, indicates that the model holding only the ZLB constraint seems to fail to estimate Japanese economy overall for both of interest rate policy period and conventional monetary policy period. The parameter δ of Model 3 and 4 in Table 3 have around.46 and.33 as posterior means, respectively. This result indicates that the adjustment costs in rising prices are likely to be about 33% through 46% higher than ones in dropping prices, and that 8

it is much hard for producing firms to rise the prices of their goods rather than to decline the prices. [ Insert Table 3 ] 4. Estimated Policy Functions Using posterior means of the parameters in the four models, their policy functions are calculated and shown at Figure. Graphs in the first, second and third rows are the functions in term of the three state variables: z t, R t and g t, respectively. Generally, reactions of the functions in Model 4 (red bold line are drawn between Model (green line and Model (blue line, and that suggests that addition of the AAC mitigates reactions to output and inflation. More detail focusing on the graphs, reaction of the technology growth rate z t to inflation in Model 4 (red line seems to be shaped as stronger convex than Model (blue line, whereas reaction of Model is obviously linear as shown at the top line and the second column. As the figure at the third column, reactions to interest rate in the two models with the ZLB are kinked at over unity of z t. On the other hand, there are no big difference in impacts of government shocks g t on the three endogenous variables among the four models as the third row. These results also suggest that if Model 4 is close to true as the marginal likelihood shows, the model with only ZLB bind as Model might overestimate responses of the TFP and monetary shocks to output and inflation. [ Insert Fig. ] 4.3 Nonlinear Filtering of Variables and Shocks Figures through 4 show posterior estimations of output, inflation and interest rate derived from particle filter, respectively. The black solid line, blue shaded area and red dashed line stand for the posterior means, the 68% credible intervals and the observed series, respectively. As Figure, 68% range of output becomes much tighter by incorporations of the AAC, the ZLB or both, since these assumptions could contribute to explain the flactuation. Meanwhile, estimated inflation and output of Model through 4 show that it is difficult to explain synchronization of deep deflation and boom in output happened between and 5 in terms of the AAC and the ZLB, as the black lines do not almost match the corresponding red lines. To explain this period we need to extend our model from another aspect. We remain this discrepancy as this puzzle to solve in the next research. Figure 5 shows posterior means of estimated exogenous three shocks of the four models. Surprisingly, there are no big differences among these estimated shocks, even though the two assumptions are added. This suggests that we can robustly estimate movements of structural shocks no matter what extension are conducted in a model. 9

[ Insert Fig. through Fig.5 ] 4.4 Estimated Impulse Response Figure 6 shows means (blue line and 95% interval (light blue shaded area of impulse response functions (IRF of monetary policy shock in the four models calculated with posterior means of the parameters by using generalized impulse response method (Koop et al.,996. As panel (b and (c, the 95% (or times standard deviation of simulations bands are very wide by introducing the ZLB, since policy functions of Models and 4 in Figure are deeply curved. Under the ZLB, the effect of monetary policy depends not only on the size of the shocks but also on the situation of state variables. It suggests forecasting of effects of monetary policy are the most uncertain around zero interest rate. The IRF of Model 3 has slightly wide range so that the AAC makes policy functions curved, whereas the IRF of Model has narrow one and their policy functions are flat. Finaly, we report that the impulse responses on inflation and output in the models with only the ZLB bind are much bigger than other three as panel (b and it suggests that only the ZLB constraint misleads the effect of monetary policy overestimated in the case of the latest Japanese economy. [ Insert Fig. 6 ] 5 Conclusion TBA References [] An S., and F. Schorfheide (7 Bayesian Analysis of DSGE Models," Econometric Reviews, 6(-4, 3-7. [] Andrieu, C., A. Doucet, and R. Holenstein ( Particle Markov Chain Monte Carlo Methods," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B, 7(3, 69-34. [3] Aruoba, S.B., P. Cuba-Borda, and F.Schorfhide (4 Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries," NBER Working Paper, 948. [4] Aruoba, S.B., and F.Schorfhide (5 Inflation during and after the Zero Lower Bouns, mimeo. [5] Chib, S., and S. Ramamurthy ( Tailored Randomized Block MCMC Methods with Application to DSGE Models," Journal of Econometrics, 55(, 9-38.

[6] Fernandez-Villaverde, J., J., G. Gordon, P. Guerron-Quintana and J.F. Rubio- Ramirez (5 Nonlinear Adventures at the Zero Lower Bound," Journal of Economic and Dynamic Control, 57, 8-4. [7] Fernandez-Villaverde, J., and J.F. Rubio-Ramirez (5 Estimating Dynamic Equilibrium Economies: Linear versus Nonlinear Likelihood, Journal of Applied Economeyrics,, 89-9. [8] Gust, C., López-Salido, D., Smith, M.E., ( The Empirical Implications of the Interest-Rate Lower Bound, mimeo, Federal Reserve Board. [9] Keen, B.D., Richter, A. W., and Throckmorton, N.A. (5 Forward Guidance and the State of Economy, mimeo. [] Kim, J. and F. Ruge-Murcia (9 How Much In ation is Necessary to Grease the Wheels," Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 365-377. [] Herbst, E.P., and F. Schorfheide (6 Bayesain Estimation of DSGE models, Princeton University Press. [] Koop, G., M.H. Pesaran, S. M. Potter (996 Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate Models, Journal of Econometrics, 74, 9 47. [3] Richter, A., Throckmorton, N., and T. B. WALKER (4 Accuracy, Speed and Robustness of Policy Function Iteration, Computational Economics, 44, 445 476. [4] Richter, A., and Throckmorton, N., (5 The zero lower bound: frequency, duration, and numerical convergence, The B.E. J. Macroecon. 5(, 57 8. [5] Rotemberg (98 Sticky Prices in the United States, Journal of Political Economy, 9, 87. A Appendix A. Projection Method TBA A. PFMH TBA

B Tables Table : Prior Setting parameters definition distribution parameter parameter β discount factor beta.98. τ inverse elasticity of substitution gamma.. ν inverse elasticity of demand for goods gamma.3. φ coef. of adjustment costs gamma.. δ Degree of asymmetric AC beta.5. ψ reaction of inflation normal.5.5 ψ reaction of output normal.5.5 γ average technology growth rate normal.4. π Steady state inflation rate normal.. ρ r persistence of MP shock beta.75. ρ g persistence of Gov shock beta.75. ρ z persistence of TFP shock beta.75. σ r St.D. of MP iid shock Inverse gamma.5 5 σ g St.D. of Gov iid shock Inverse gamma.5 5 σ z St.D. of TFP iid shock Inverse gamma.5 5 Notes: In Beta and Normal distributions, parameter and represent mean and Standard deviation, respectively. Table : Model Definitions and Model Selection ZLB AAC Log Marginal Likelihood Posterior Model Prob Model No No -765.54. Model Yes No -769.37. Model 3 No Yes -757.336.3 Model 4 Yes Yes -753.58.977 Notes: ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively.

Table 3: Posterior Parameters Estimations parameters Model Model Model 3 Model 4 ZLB AAC ZLB & AAC β.98.98.98.98 [.98,.98] [.98,.98] [.98.98] [.98,.98] τ.6.99 3..86 [.6,.63] [.98, 3.] [3., 3.4] [.84,.87] ν..38.4.37 [.,.3] [.37,.38] [.4,.43] [.35,.38] 4.97 5.78 7.4 5.59 φ [4.4, 5.77] [5.34, 6.4] [7., 7.9] [5.8, 5.96] δ N.A. N.A.46.33 [.4,.5] [.7,.44].7.57.34.7 ψ [.7,.73] [.55,.58] [.33,.35] [.7,.7].44.4.39.6 ψ [.43.45] [.4,.43] [.38,.4] [.6,.63] γ.... π [.,.] [.,.] [.,.] [.,.].... [.,.] [.,.] [.,.] [.,.] ρ r.6.8.64.74 [.6.6] [.8,.8] [.63,.65] [.73,.75] ρ g.93.87.9.9 [.93.94] [.87,.88] [.9,.93] [.9,.9] ρ z.76.83.8.8 [.75,.77] [.83,.84] [.8,.8] [.8,.83] σ r.9.5.3.3 [.9,.9] [.5,.5] [.3,.3] [.3.33] σ g.63.69.8.37 [.63,.63] [.69,.69] [.8,.9] [.37.37] σ z.43.3.53.34 [.43,.43] [.3,.3] [.53,.54] [.34,.34] Notes: In the first row in each parameter, the value represents their posterior mean. In the second row, the values within parenthesis stand for 9% credible bands. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 3

C Figures Figure : Posterior Estimation of Policy Functions.5 output.6 Inflation.4 Interest Rate.95.9..98..4 TFP (z t output AAC & ZLB ZLB AAC None.4..98.96.98..4 TFP (z t Inflation.3...99.6.98..4 TFP (z t Interest Rate.9.8.7.6.5.98..4.6 MP (R t-.6.4. output.8...3.4.5.6 Gov (g t.99.98.97.96.98..4.6 MP (R t-...99 Inflation.98...3.4.5.6 Gov (g t.4..4.3...98..4.6 MP (R t- Interest Rate.99...3.4.5.6 Gov (g t Notes: The above policy functions are calculated from posterior means of parameters. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 4

Figure : Posterior Estimates of Real GDP (a Model (w/o both AAC and ZLB 8 6 4 - -4-6 Output: Observable vs. Particle Filtered variables -8 985 99 995 5 5 (b Model (w/o AAC and w/ ZLB 8 6 4 - -4-6 Output: Observable vs. Particle Filtered variables -8 985 99 995 5 5 (c Model 3 (w/ AAC and w/o ZLB 8 6 4 - -4-6 Output: Observable vs. Particle Filtered variables -8 985 99 995 5 5 (d Model 4 (w/ both AAC and ZLB 8 6 4 - -4-6 Output: Observable vs. Particle Filtered variables -8 985 99 995 5 5 Notes: The black solid line and the red dashed line stand for posterior mean and actual data, respectively. The blue shaded areas represent 68% credible band. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 5

Figure 3: Posterior Estimates of Inflation (a Model (w/o both AAC and ZLB Inflation: Observable vs.particle Filter 5-5 985 99 995 5 5 (b Model (w/o AAC and w/ ZLB Inflation: Observable vs.particle Filter 5-5 985 99 995 5 5 (c Model 3 (w/ AAC and w/o ZLB Inflation: Observable vs.particle Filter 5-5 985 99 995 5 5 (d Model 4 (w/ both AAC and ZLB Inflation: Observable vs.particle Filter 5-5 985 99 995 5 5 Notes: The black solid line and the red dashed line stand for posterior mean and actual data, respectively. The blue shaded areas represent 68% credible band. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 6

Figure 4: Posterior Estimates of Interest Rate (a Model (w/o both AAC and ZLB 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 Interest Rate: Observable vs.particle Filter - 985 99 995 5 5 (b Model (w/o AAC and w/ ZLB 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 Interest Rate: Observable vs.particle Filter - 985 99 995 5 5 (c Model 3 (w/ AAC and w/o ZLB 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 Interest Rate: Observable vs.particle Filter - 985 99 995 5 5 (d Model 4 (w/ both AAC and ZLB 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 Interest Rate: Observable vs.particle Filter - 985 99 995 5 5 Notes: The black solid line and the red dashed line stand for posterior mean and actual data, respectively. The blue shaded areas represent 68% credible band. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 7

Figure 5: Posterior Estimates of Exogenous shocks..5 ACC+ZLB ZLB AAC None Government Shock -.5 -. 985 99 995 5 5. TFP Shock.5 -.5 -. 985 99 995 5 5.4 Monetary Policy Shock. -. -.4 -.6 985 99 995 5 5 Notes: Posterior Estimates of shocks are posterior means derived from samples acumulated. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 8

Figure 6: Impulse Response Functions of Monetary Policy Shock (a Model (w/o AAC and ZLB (b Model (w/ ZLB.5 Output.5 Output.5.5 3 4 5 6 Inflation.5 3 4 5 6 Inflation.5.5.5 3 4 5 6 Interest Rate 3 4 5 6 Interest Rate - - - - -3 3 4 5 6-3 3 4 5 6 (c Model 3 (w/ AAC (d Model 4 (w/ AAC and ZLB.5 Output.5 Output.5.5 3 4 5 6 Inflation.5 3 4 5 6 Inflation.5.5.5 3 4 5 6 Interest Rate 3 4 5 6 Interest Rate - - - - -3 3 4 5 6-3 3 4 5 6 Notes: The values of impulse response are derived using the method of generalized impulse response funtion. The blue solid line and light blue shaded area represent means and 9% interval, respectively. ZLB and AAC stand for zero lower bound and asymmetric adjustment cost, respectively. 9