Pairwise Comparison Dynamics for Games with Continuous Strategy Space

Similar documents
Survival of Dominated Strategies under Evolutionary Dynamics. Josef Hofbauer University of Vienna. William H. Sandholm University of Wisconsin

Evolutionary Game Theory: Overview and Recent Results

Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics

Logit Dynamic for Continuous Strategy Games: Existence of Solutions.

Gains in evolutionary dynamics. Dai ZUSAI

Distributional stability and equilibrium selection Evolutionary dynamics under payoff heterogeneity (II) Dai Zusai

Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics

Nonaggregable evolutionary dynamics under payoff heterogeneity

LEARNING IN CONCAVE GAMES

Gains in evolutionary dynamics: unifying rational framework for dynamic stability

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Static Stability in Games Part I: Symmetric and Population Games

Survival of Dominated Strategies under Evolutionary Dynamics

Distributed Learning based on Entropy-Driven Game Dynamics

Deterministic Evolutionary Dynamics

Equilibria in Games with Weak Payoff Externalities

Survival of dominated strategies under evolutionary dynamics

On The Transmission of Continuous Cultural Traits

Stable Games and their Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Pairwise Comparison Dynamics and Evolutionary Foundations for Nash Equilibrium

DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC SELECTION DYNAMICS

Local Stability of Strict Equilibria under Evolutionary Game Dynamics

Population Dynamics Approach for Resource Allocation Problems. Ashkan Pashaie

Brown von Neumann Nash dynamics: The continuous strategy case

Online Appendices for Large Matching Markets: Risk, Unraveling, and Conflation

Games on Manifolds. Noah Stein

Evolution & Learning in Games

Large deviations and averaging for systems of slow fast stochastic reaction diffusion equations.

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

Spatial Economics and Potential Games

Thomas Demuynck, P. Jean-Jacques Herings, Riccardo D. Saulle, Christian Seel. The Myopic Stable Set for Social Environments RM/17/002

The Index of Nash Equilibria

Utilitarian Preferences and Potential Games

Derivatives. Differentiability problems in Banach spaces. Existence of derivatives. Sharpness of Lebesgue s result

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Payoff Continuity in Incomplete Information Games

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Evolution in Bayesian games I: theory. Received 30 January 2002

Decompositions of normal form games: potential, zero-sum, and stable games

Static and dynamic stability conditions for structurally stable signaling games

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency

Inverse function theorems

p-dominance and Equilibrium Selection under Perfect Foresight Dynamics

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Weak Robust (Virtual) Implementation

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #04 Mixed-Strategy Equilibrium

Variational approach to mean field games with density constraints

Irrational behavior in the Brown von Neumann Nash dynamics

Hannu Salonen Utilitarian Preferences and Potential Games. Aboa Centre for Economics

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

Robust Comparative Statics in Large Static Games

Lecture 7 Monotonicity. September 21, 2008

EVOLUTIONARY GAMES WITH GROUP SELECTION

Stochastic Evolutionary Game Dynamics: Foundations, Deterministic Approximation, and Equilibrium Selection

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide

Inertial Game Dynamics

Pure Strategy Equilibria in Symmetric Two-Player Zero-Sum Games

The projection dynamic and the replicator dynamic

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

epub WU Institutional Repository

ELEMENTS OF PROBABILITY THEORY

Pseudo-Potential Games

Learning in Mean Field Games

Economics 201B Economic Theory (Spring 2017) Bargaining. Topics: the axiomatic approach (OR 15) and the strategic approach (OR 7).

Economics Noncooperative Game Theory Lectures 3. October 15, 1997 Lecture 3

Distributed learning in potential games over large-scale networks

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities

Long Run Equilibrium in Discounted Stochastic Fictitious Play

Stability and Long Run Equilibrium in Stochastic Fictitious Play

Selçuk Demir WS 2017 Functional Analysis Homework Sheet

Revenue Maximization in Multi-Object Auctions

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 515

Dynamic Programming Theorems

Learning in Games and the Topology of Dynamical Systems. Georgios Piliouras

Evolutionary Internalization of Congestion Externalities When Values of Time are Unknown

Decompositions and Potentials for Normal Form Games

WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY

1. Introduction. 2. A Simple Model

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

Geometric Inference for Probability distributions

Existence of Equilibrium in Minimax Inequalities, Saddle Points, Fixed Points, and Games without Convexity Sets

APPROXIMATING BOCHNER INTEGRALS BY RIEMANN SUMS

Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents

The Dynamic Instability of Dispersed Price Equilibria.

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND

Strict Nash equilibria in Non-Atomic Games with Strict Single Crossing in Types and Actions

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces

Half of Final Exam Name: Practice Problems October 28, 2014

ON SOME GLOBAL AND UNILATERAL ADAPTIVE DYNAMICS

Correlated Equilibrium in Games with Incomplete Information

arxiv: v1 [cs.sy] 13 Sep 2017

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

Topics on strategic learning

DISCRETIZED BEST-RESPONSE DYNAMICS FOR THE ROCK-PAPER-SCISSORS GAME. Peter Bednarik. Josef Hofbauer. (Communicated by William H.

A remark on discontinuous games with asymmetric information and ambiguity

Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing

Bounded uniformly continuous functions

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1)

Transcription:

Pairwise Comparison Dynamics for Games with Continuous Strategy Space Man-Wah Cheung https://sites.google.com/site/jennymwcheung University of Wisconsin Madison Department of Economics Nov 5, 2013

Evolutionary dynamics with finite strategy space Incentives and aggregate behavior Nash stationarity (NS): rest points of the dynamic coincide with the set of Nash equilibria positive correlation (PC): whenever the dynamic is not at rest, the covariance between strategies payoffs and growth rates is positive under the uniform probability distribution on strategies Convergence results for pairwise comparison dynamics (PCD) potential games: all ω-limit points of the dynamic are NE contractive games: set of NE is globally asymptotically stable Usually, the underlying games studied are normal form games with finite number of strategies.

However, the restriction on the dimension of strategy space limits the use of population games in applications whose strategy spaces are naturally modeled as continuous, e.g., auctions, bargaining games, games of timing, oligopoly games.

However, the restriction on the dimension of strategy space limits the use of population games in applications whose strategy spaces are naturally modeled as continuous, e.g., auctions, bargaining games, games of timing, oligopoly games. Evolutionary dynamics with continuous strategy space New technical issues: infinite dimensional state space choice of topology matters existence/uniqueness of solutions definition/analysis of stability

Literature Bomze (1990, 1991) defines replicator dynamic in Banach space of finite signed measures with variational norm shows replicator dynamic is well-defined if certain Lipschitz continuity conditions are satisfied for mean payoff function Oechssler and Riedel (2001, 2002) show Bomze s conditions are always satisfied in pairwise encounters if underlying pairwise payoff function is bounded introduce evolutionary robustness Hofbauer, Oechssler and Riedel (2009) show Nash stationarity (NS) is satisfied for BNN dynamic provide stability results for doubly symmetric games ( potential games) and contractive games

This paper studies PCD for population games with cts strategy space shows PCD is well-defined under certain mild Lipschitz continuity conditions establishes Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC)

This paper studies PCD for population games with cts strategy space shows PCD is well-defined under certain mild Lipschitz continuity conditions establishes Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC) defines potential games with cts strategy space, and provides a global convergence result for general deterministic evolutionary dynamics in potential games defines contractive games with cts strategy space, and provides a global asymptotic stability result for PCD in contractive games

Settings The set of strategies is S, which is compact and convex, with metric d. There is a unit mass of agents. Each chooses a pure strategy from S. Thus, a population state (distribution over strategies) is described by a probability measure µ M + 1 (S)

Settings The set of strategies is S, which is compact and convex, with metric d. There is a unit mass of agents. Each chooses a pure strategy from S. Thus, a population state (distribution over strategies) is described by a probability measure µ M + 1 (S) Payoffs A population game is a map F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) that is continuous with respect to the weak topology. (Thus, F (µ) C b (S).) F x (µ) is the payoff of pure strategy x S at state µ.

Example: Matching to play a 2-player symm game a unit mass of agents are matched to play a 2-player symm game S: continuous strategy set, convex and compact each pair of agents is matched exactly once h(x, y): single match payoff of an agent playing x S against an opponent playing y S, assume h is bounded and continuous F x (µ) = h(x, y) µ(dy), average payoff of x S at state µ S

Example: Matching to play a 2-player symm game a unit mass of agents are matched to play a 2-player symm game S: continuous strategy set, convex and compact each pair of agents is matched exactly once h(x, y): single match payoff of an agent playing x S against an opponent playing y S, assume h is bounded and continuous F x (µ) = h(x, y) µ(dy), average payoff of x S at state µ S µ F x (µ) is continuous wrt weak topology x F x (µ) is bounded continuous thus, F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) defines a population game

Weak topology vs strong topology Strong topology existence/uniqueness of solutions ϕ := sup g g dϕ, the variational norm on M(S), where the sup is taken over all mble g : S R with g 1 (M(S), ) is a Banach space allows us to show existence/uniqueness of solutions Pic

Weak topology vs strong topology Strong topology existence/uniqueness of solutions ϕ := sup g g dϕ, the variational norm on M(S), where the sup is taken over all mble g : S R with g 1 (M(S), ) is a Banach space allows us to show existence/uniqueness of solutions Weak topology gives a more natural notion of closeness for definitions of local stability strong topology only consider perturbations to states by (possibly large) change of strategic play from small fraction of players (e.g., change from δ x to (1 ε)δ x + εδ u ) in applications, also want to consider perturbations to states by small change of strategic play from large fraction of players (e.g., change from δ x to δ u with d(x, u) < ε) Pic

Weak topology vs strong topology (con t) Weak topology provides the more natural notion of convergence for sequences of population states (ex.: µ n N (x, σ 2 n) with σ n 0), and is needed to ensure existence of ω-limit points

Weak topology vs strong topology (con t) Weak topology provides the more natural notion of convergence for sequences of population states (ex.: µ n N (x, σ 2 n) with σ n 0), and is needed to ensure existence of ω-limit points µ n µ in strong topology µ n µ in weak topology F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) continuous in weak topology continuous in strong topology

Pairwise comparison dynamics (PCD) Let λ be a fixed probability measure that has full support. Special case: Smith dynamic (SD) (1984) µ(a) = [F y (µ) F z (µ)] + λ(dy) µ(dz) z S y A [F z (µ) F y (µ)] + µ(dy) λ(dz), (SD) z S y A which is inflow of agents into strategies in A at state µ outflow of agents from strategies in A at state µ

Pairwise comparison dynamics (PCD) Let λ be a fixed probability measure that has full support. Special case: Smith dynamic (SD) (1984) µ(a) = [F y (µ) F z (µ)] + λ(dy) µ(dz) z S y A [F z (µ) F y (µ)] + µ(dy) λ(dz), (SD) z S y A which is inflow of agents into strategies in A at state µ outflow of agents from strategies in A at state µ Remark: All results apply to the more general pairwise comparison dynamics (PCD).

Existence and uniqueness of solutions Theorem: Under mild Lipschitz continuity conditions, solutions to SD exist and are unique, and are continuous in initial conditions.

Existence and uniqueness of solutions Theorem: Under mild Lipschitz continuity conditions, solutions to SD exist and are unique, and are continuous in initial conditions. Corollary: For the ex. of matching to play a 2-player symm game, solutions to SD exist and are unique, and are continuous in initial conditions.

Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC) relate dynamics to underlying game provide tools for analysis of convergence Nash stationarity (NS): rest points of the dynamic coincide with the set of Nash equilibria positive correlation (PC): whenever the dynamic is not at rest, the covariance between strategies payoffs and growth rates is positive under the uniform probability distribution on strategies

Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC) relate dynamics to underlying game provide tools for analysis of convergence Nash stationarity (NS): rest points of the dynamic coincide with the set of Nash equilibria positive correlation (PC): whenever the dynamic is not at rest, the covariance between strategies payoffs and growth rates is positive under the uniform probability distribution on strategies Proposition: Every pairwise comparison dynamic satisfies Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC).

Potential games (Monderer and Shapley (1996), Sandholm (2001)) Idea: There is a real-valued function of the population state that dynamics ascend, converging to NE. Def

Potential games (Monderer and Shapley (1996), Sandholm (2001)) Idea: There is a real-valued function of the population state that dynamics ascend, converging to NE. Definition: Population game F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) is a potential game if there exists a continuous (wrt weak topology) function f : M(S) R s.t. f is Fréchet-differentiable with gradient f satisfying f (µ) = F (µ), µ M + 1 (S). (PG) The function f is called the potential function. Def

Potential games (Monderer and Shapley (1996), Sandholm (2001)) Idea: There is a real-valued function of the population state that dynamics ascend, converging to NE. Definition: Population game F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) is a potential game if there exists a continuous (wrt weak topology) function f : M(S) R s.t. f is Fréchet-differentiable with gradient f satisfying f (µ) = F (µ), µ M + 1 (S). (PG) The function f is called the potential function. Denote by Ω the set of all ω-limit points of all solution trajectories. Theorem: Let F be a potential game with potential function f, and µ = V F (µ) be SD for F. Then Ω = RP(V F ) = NE(F ). Def

Potential games (Monderer and Shapley (1996), Sandholm (2001)) Idea: There is a real-valued function of the population state that dynamics ascend, converging to NE. Definition: Population game F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) is a potential game if there exists a continuous (wrt weak topology) function f : M(S) R s.t. f is Fréchet-differentiable with gradient f satisfying f (µ) = F (µ), µ M + 1 (S). (PG) The function f is called the potential function. Denote by Ω the set of all ω-limit points of all solution trajectories. Theorem: Let F be a potential game with potential function f, and µ = V F (µ) be SD for F. Then Ω = RP(V F ) = NE(F ). Remark: For general deterministic dynamics, if only (PC) is satisfied but not (NS), then we still have Ω = RP(V F ). Def

Contractive games (Hofbauer and Sandholm (2009)) Idea: If states move in the direction of the payoff vectors, then distinct states move closer together.

Contractive games (Hofbauer and Sandholm (2009)) Idea: If states move in the direction of the payoff vectors, then distinct states move closer together. Definition: Population game F is a contractive game if F (µ) F (ψ), µ ψ (F (µ) F (ψ)) d(µ ψ) 0, µ, ψ M + 1 (S). (CG) S strictly contractive game: ineq holds strictly whenever µ ψ null contractive game: ineq always binds

Contractive games (Hofbauer and Sandholm (2009)) Idea: If states move in the direction of the payoff vectors, then distinct states move closer together. Definition: Population game F is a contractive game if F (µ) F (ψ), µ ψ (F (µ) F (ψ)) d(µ ψ) 0, µ, ψ M + 1 (S). (CG) S strictly contractive game: ineq holds strictly whenever µ ψ null contractive game: ineq always binds Theorem: Let F : M + 1 (S) C b(s) be C 1 contractive game, µ = V F (µ) be SD, and η y (d) := d 0 [r] + dr. Define H : M + 1 (S) R + by H(µ) := η y (F y (µ) F z (µ)) µ(dz) λ(dy). y S z S Then H 1 (0) = NE(F ). Furthermore, H acts as a decreasing strict Lyapunov function, and so NE(F ) is globally asymptotically stable.

Summary studied PCD for population games with cts strategy space showed PCD is well-defined under certain mild Lipschitz continuity conditions established Nash stationarity (NS) and positive correlation (PC) defined potential games with cts strategy space, and provided a global convergence result for general deterministic evolutionary dynamics in potential games defined contractive games with cts strategy space, and provided a global asymptotic stability result for PCD in contractive games

Fréchet-differentiability and gradient Suppose f : M(S) R is Fréchet-differentiable when M(S) is endowed with strong topology. 1 The Fréchet-derivative of f at µ M(S) is a cts linear map Df (µ) : M(S) R that maps tangent vectors ζ M(S) to rates of change in the value of f when one moves from µ in the direction ζ. Since Df (µ) is a linear map from M(S) to R, by Riesz representation theorem, there is an element f (µ) of C b (S) (the dual space of M(S)) that represents Df (µ) in the sense that Df (µ)ζ = f (µ)dζ f (µ), ζ. This f (µ) is called the gradient of f at µ. 1 If X and Y are Banach spaces, we say g : X Y is Fréchet-differentiable at x if a continuous linear map T : X Y such that g(x + ϑ) = g(x) + T ϑ + o( ϑ ) for all ϑ in some nbd of zero in X. If it exists, this T is called the Fréchet-derivative of g at x, and is written as Dg(x). Return

Weak topology vs strong topology (picture) Return