Citation for published version (APA): Ochea, M. I. (2010). Essays on nonlinear evolutionary game dynamics Amsterdam: Thela Thesis

Similar documents
Citation for published version (APA): Ochea, M. I. (2010). Essays on nonlinear evolutionary game dynamics Amsterdam: Thela Thesis

On the Stability of the Cournot Equilibrium: An Evolutionary Approach

Recent revisions of phosphate rock reserves and resources: a critique Edixhoven, J.D.; Gupta, J.; Savenije, H.H.G.

Citation for published version (APA): Harinck, S. (2001). Conflict issues matter : how conflict issues influence negotiation

Imitation Dynamics in Oligopoly Games with Heterogeneous Players

Citation for published version (APA): Kopányi, D. (2015). Bounded rationality and learning in market competition Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute

Imitation Dynamics in Oligopoly Games with Heterogeneous Players

MDEF th Workshop MDEF Modelli Dinamici in Economia e Finanza Dynamic Models in Economics and Finance

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository)

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Converting lignin to aromatics: step by step Strassberger, Z.I. Link to publication

Rotational symmetry breaking in the topological superconductor SrxBi2Se3 probed by uppercritical

Data-driven methods in application to flood defence systems monitoring and analysis Pyayt, A.

Evolutionary Competition between Adjustment Processes in Cournot Oligopoly: Instability and Complex Dynamics

Mass loss and evolution of asymptotic giant branch stars in the Magellanic Clouds van Loon, J.T.

NMDA receptor dependent functions of hippocampal networks in spatial navigation and memory formation de Oliveira Cabral, H.

Citation for published version (APA): Weber, B. A. (2017). Sliding friction: From microscopic contacts to Amontons law

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Phenotypic variation in plants Lauss, K. Link to publication

Published in: Tenth Tbilisi Symposium on Language, Logic and Computation: Gudauri, Georgia, September 2013

Physiological and genetic studies towards biofuel production in cyanobacteria Schuurmans, R.M.

Research Article Chaos Control on a Duopoly Game with Homogeneous Strategy

Citation for published version (APA): Hin, V. (2017). Ontogenesis: Eco-evolutionary perspective on life history complexity.

IERCU. Dynamic Monopoly with Demand Delay

Coherent X-ray scattering of charge order dynamics and phase separation in titanates Shi, B.

On a unified description of non-abelian charges, monopoles and dyons Kampmeijer, L.

Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot duopoly game with heterogeneous players

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository)

NMDA receptor dependent functions of hippocampal networks in spatial navigation and memory formation de Oliveira Cabral, H.

Research Article Complexity Analysis of a Cournot-Bertrand Duopoly Game Model with Limited Information

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Electrokinetics in porous media Luong, D.T. Link to publication

Combining radar systems to get a 3D - picture of the bird migration Liechti, F.; Dokter, A.; Shamoun-Baranes, J.Z.; van Gasteren, J.R.; Holleman, I.

Analysis of Duopoly Output Game With Different Decision-Making Rules

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) The syntax of relativization de Vries, M. Link to publication

Monitoring and modelling hydrological fluxes in support of nutrient cycling studies in Amazonian rain forest ecosystems Tobon-Marin, C.

FADING MEMORY LEARNING IN THE COBWEB MODEL WITH RISK AVERSE HETEROGENEOUS PRODUCERS

EconS Nash Equilibrium in Games with Continuous Action Spaces.

Quaderni di Dipartimento. Double route to chaos in an heterogeneous triopoly game. Ahmad Naimzada (Università di Milano-Bicocca)

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

Static Models of Oligopoly

Price and Quantity Competition in Di erentiated Oligopoly Revisited

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

NONLINEAR DELAY MONOPOLY WITH BOUNDED RATIONALITY

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly

Fractional Dynamic Oligopoly Model

Discussion Paper No.241. Delay Dynamics of a Cournot Game with Heterogenous Duopolies. Akio Matsumoto Chuo University

EconS Sequential Competition

Analysis of nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Carrot and stick games

A Special Labor-Managed Oligopoly

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information*

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

Imitation and the Evolution of Walrasian Behavior: Theoretically Fragile but Behaviorally Robust

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

Complex Systems Workshop Lecture III: Behavioral Asset Pricing Model with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Discussion Paper Series No.51. Complexity yields benefits: An example of a heterogeneous duopoly market. Yasuo Nonaka.

Price and Quantity Competition in Dynamic Oligopolies with Product Differentiation

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Advanced Microeconomics

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Nonlinear dynamics in a duopoly with price competition and vertical differentiation

Cournot Duopoly when the Competitors Operate Multiple Production Plants

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

C31: Game Theory, Lecture 1

Chaotic Dynamics and Synchronization of Cournot Duopoly Game with a Logarithmic Demand Function

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Measurement of the charged particle density with the ATLAS detector: First data at vs = 0.9, 2.36 and 7 TeV Kayl, M.S.

Citation for published version (APA): Jak, S. (2013). Cluster bias: Testing measurement invariance in multilevel data

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices

Dynamics of a Bertrand Game with Heterogeneous Players and Different Delay Structures. 1 Introduction

Published in: ICCSA 2014: Fourth International Conference on Complex Systems and Applications: June 23-26, 2014, Le Havre, Normandie, France

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Matrix perturbations: bounding and computing eigenvalues Reis da Silva, R.J. Link to publication

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Information Advantage in Cournot Ol Title Separable Information, or Nondiffer.

Topics in Nonlinear Economic Dynamics: Bounded Rationality, Heterogeneous Expectations and Complex Adaptive Systems

Measuring more or less: Estimating product period penetrations from incomplete panel data Hoogendoorn, A.W.

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Chaos in adaptive expectation Cournot Puu duopoly model

Solving Extensive Form Games

Behavioural & Experimental Macroeconomics: Some Recent Findings

Oligopoly games with Local Monopolistic Approximation

Citation for published version (APA): Nguyen, X. C. (2017). Different nanocrystal systems for carrier multiplication

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Transcription:

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Essays on nonlinear evolutionary game dynamics Ochea, M.I. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Ochea, M. I. (200). Essays on nonlinear evolutionary game dynamics Amsterdam: Thela Thesis General rights It is not permitted to download or to forward/distribute the text or part of it without the consent of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), other than for strictly personal, individual use, unless the work is under an open content license (like Creative Commons). Disclaimer/Complaints regulations If you believe that digital publication of certain material infringes any of your rights or (privacy) interests, please let the Library know, stating your reasons. In case of a legitimate complaint, the Library will make the material inaccessible and/or remove it from the website. Please Ask the Library: http://uba.uva.nl/en/contact, or a letter to: Library of the University of Amsterdam, Secretariat, Singel 425, 02 WP Amsterdam, The Netherlands. You will be contacted as soon as possible. UvA-DARE is a service provided by the library of the University of Amsterdam (http://dare.uva.nl) Download date: 24 Dec 208

Chapter 4 On the Stability of the Cournot Solution: An Evolutionary Approach 4. Introduction Within a linear cost-linear demand set-up, Theocharis (960) shows that once the duopoly assumption is relaxed and the number of players increases, the Cournot Nash equilibrium loses stability and bounded oscillations arise already for triopoly quantity-setting games. For more than 3 players oscillations grow quickly unbounded but they are stabilized by the non-negativity price and demand constraint. Hahn (962) puts forth an alternative proof of this results and derives stability conditions for asymmetric cost functions and nonlinear cost and demand functions. Fisher (96) and McManus (964) recover stability of the equilibrium when rms use, instead of the discrete-time best response dynamic of Theocharis (960), a continuous adjustment process to some optimally derived output target. However, rms do these adjustments incompletely (i.e. with di erent speeds of adjustment) at each time instance. In this class of adjustment processes, increasing the marginal costs acts as 89

a stabilizer of the Cournot-Nash equilibrium, irrespective of the number of players. In Okuguchi (970) both the actual output and expectations of rivals output follow a continuous adjustment process to some target and restrictions on the speeds of adjustment (of both actual and the rival s expected output) are derived in relation to the rate of marginal costs increase such that stability is regained for an arbitrary number of players. Adaptive expectations generalize Cournot (naive) expectations. Thus, in a multi-player oligopoly game, where players follow a discrete-time bestresponse to adaptively formed expectations about rivals output, Szidarovszky et al. (994) nd suitable restrictions on the coe cients of adaptive expectations such that the unique Cournot-Nash equilibrium is stabilized. In this short Chapter we take a di erent route and relax the assumption of homogenous expectations, while preserving the linear structure and best-reply adjustment dynamics of Theocharis (960). The questions we address is whether Theocharis (960) classical instability result still persist under the evolutionary selection of heterogenous expectations rule. We show that, in an evolutionary environment, the instability is robust to a heterogenous ecology of heuristics. In particular, we focus on the interplay between a simple adaptive rule and a more involved, but costly, rational rule with agents choosing the best-performing rule according to a logistic updating mechanism. The threshold number of players that triggers instability may vary with the costs of the rational expectations rule or with the adaptive expectations coe cient. In Section 4.2 the model is introduced, results and simulations are reported in Section 4.3 while Section 4.4 contains some concluding remarks. 90

4.2 The model We start with the Theocharis (960) simple linear inverse demand-linear costs homogenous, n-player oligopoly game. Linear inverse demand is given by P = a nx b q i ; (4.) i= and linear costs by C i (q i ) = cq i : (4.2) Each period n players are drawn from a large populations to play a n-player quantity-setting game. Furthermore, assume that the population of oligopolists consists of two behavioural types: adaptive players (share p in the population) playing quantity q and rational (share p) picking quantity q 2 : From the perspective of an individual player the aggregate output of the remaining n opponents, given behavioral types, could be computed for di erent market structures as follows: In the triopoly case the two randomly drawn opponents may be, with probability p 2 of rational type (producing q 2 each), with probability ( p) 2 of adaptive type (and thus choosing q each) and, with probability 2p( p) of di erent types (thus picking q and q 2 ; respectively). Thus, the output of an average opponent in a triopoly game is given by: p 2 2q 2 + 2p( p)(q 2 + q ) + ( p) 2 2q (4.3) Similarly, for the quadropoly Cournot game we get p 3 3q 2 + 3p 2 ( p)(2q 2 + q ) + 3p( p) 2 (q 2 + 2q ) + ( p) 3 3q (4.4) 9

and for quintopoly: p 4 4q 2 +4p 3 ( p)(3q 2 +q )+6p 2 ( p) 2 (2q 2 +2q )+4p( p) 3 (3q 2 +3q )+( p) 4 4q (4.5) More generally, in the n-player quantity-setting game the output of an average opponent is given by: Xn n p k ( p) n k ((n k)q + kq 2 ) k k=o Xn = q 2 k=o n k p k ( p) n k k Xn + q k=o n p k ( p) n k (n k ) k = q 2 (n )p + q (n )( p) (4.6) The aggregate expected output of the n opponents is equivalent to the output of n averaged-across-types opponents. Thus, each player has to form expectations about the output chosen by the average type in the population. The adaptive type (AE) forms adaptive expectations about average the opponent: q e (t + ) = q e (t) + ( )[q (t)( p) + q 2 (t)p)]: (4.7) The rational type (RE) has perfect foresight: q e 2(t + ) = q (t + )( p) + q 2 (t + )p): (4.8) Both AE and RE types best-respond to expectations: q (t + ) = R (q e (t + )) = a c b(n )qe (t+) 2b q 2 (t + ) = R 2 (q e 2(t + )) = a c b(n )qe 2 (t+) 2b (4.9) 92

q 2 (t) = R 2 (q e 2(t)) = a c b(n )qe 2(t) 2b = a c b(n )[q (t)( p) + q 2 (t)p)] 2b (4.0) q 2 (t) = a c bq (t) (n ) ( p) (4.) 2b p (n ) + 2 After substituting (4.9) and (4.) into (4.7) we obtain the adaptive expectations dynamics as: q(t+) e = q+( e )[R (q(t))( e p)+ a c + br (q(t)) e (n ) ( p) p)] (4.2) 2b p (n ) + 2 Next, we compute the expected pro ts as: (t) = q (t)[a b[q (t) + (n )[q (t)( p) + q 2 (t)p)]] c] 2 (t) = q 2 (t)[a b[q 2 (t) + (n )[q (t)( p) + q 2 (t)p)]] c] The share p of rational players updates according to asynchronous updating (only a fraction revise strategies according to the logistic probability) based on the realized performance measure: p(t + ) = p(t) + + e (( (R(q e (t));r(qe 2 (t));p(t)) 2(R(q e (t));r(qe 2 (t));p(t))+k)) (4.3) where k stands for the costs associated with the rational expectations predictor (see the discussion regarding asyncronous logistic updating in Chapter 3). Equations (4.2) and (4.3) de ne a two dimensional dynamical system (q e (t + ); p(t + )) = (q e (t); p(t)) which has an interior steady state at: (q e = a c b( + n) ; p = + exp(k) ) 93

Expressed in terms of actual quantity choices the steady state is: q = q 2 = a c b( + n) ; p = + exp(k) (4.4) Before proceeding to the stability analysis of this equilibrium, we present in Fig. 4. simulations of the system behavior for varying number of players. As the game changes from triopoly to a large number of players the interior Cournot-Nash equilibrium (4.4) loses stability and bounded, regular or irregular oscillations arise. We identify a period-doubling route to strange attractors as the number of players increases.. A snapshot of such a strange attractor is captured in Fig. 4.e along with numerical evidence (strictly positive largest Lyapunov exponent) for chaos in Panel (f). This bifurcation diagram should be interpreted under the caveat that n is not a continous parameter (the number of players in the Cournot game only takes positive integers value). Still, the bifurcation diagram can provide some information about qualitative changes in the behavior of the system, given the number of players. 94

Lyapunov exp. 2.4 q 2 q.8.5.2 0.6 0 0 5 0 5 20 25 30 0.5 0 5 0 5 20 25 30 (a) Time series, triopoly [n = 3] (b) Time series, quadropoly [n = 4].5 q 0.5 0 0 5 0 5 20 25 30 (c) Time series, octopoly [n = 8] (d) Bifurcation diagram q n 0.4 0. 0.2 0.5 0.8 2 4 6 8 0 n (e) Phase plot, octopoly [n = 8] (f) Largest Lyapunov exponent Figure 4.: Linear n-player Cournot game with an ecology of Adaptive and Rational players. Panels (a)-(c) display converging, oscillating and chaotic time series of the quantity q chosen by the Adaptive type for 3; 4 and 8-player game, respectively. Instability sets in already for the quadropoly game (Panel (b)). Panel (d) depicts a period-doubling route to chaotic dynamics in equilibrum quantity q as we increase the number of players n. A typical phase portrait for an 8-player game is shown in Panel (e) while Panel (f) provides numerical evidence for chaos (i.e. positive largest Lyapunov exponent) as number of players increases. Game and behavioral parameters: a = 7; b = ; c = 0; k = ; = 0:; = 2:8; = 0:: 95

4.3 Results We start with the following: Proposition 7 The Cournot-Nash equilibrium (q e = a c b(+n) ; p = +exp(k) ) loses (local) stability as the number of player n reaches a critical threshold n P D = 2p 3 2p + and a 2-cycle in the equilibrium quantities is born via a period-doubling bifurcation. Proof. We can rewrite system in deviations from the Cournot-Nash steady-state Q(t) = a c b(+n) q e (t) : ( + (n + p(t)) + n( + p(t))) Q(t + ) = Q(t) p(t)(n ) + 2 p(t + ) = + exp(( Q(t)(n2 )(Q(t)bn 2 +2cpn+4c Q(t)b 2cp) 4n 2 p 2 8np 2 +6np+4p 2 6p+6 + k)) (4.5) (4.6) with the interior steady state: (Q = 0; p = +exp(k) steady state is: 2 4 ( n p (n )+2 p + n ( + p ) + ) 0 (4c 2cn+2cnp )p ( )(p )((p ) 2 ) 4n 2 (p ) 2 8n 2 p +4n 2 +6np 6n+6 ): The Jacobi matrix at this with corresponding eigenvalues = np p +2 ( n p + n + np + ) and 2 = : The period-doubling bifurcation ( = ) condition reads: 3 5 ; np p + 2 ( n p + n + np + ) = ; which yields, n P D = 2p 3 2p + : (4.7) We notice rst that the Cournot-Nash equilibrium is stable if the rational predictor is costless. The threshold (4.7) can be re-arranged as P D = ln (+)(+n) k n (+n)+3 96

and observe that there is no nite value of the intensity of choice satisfying this equality for costless RE (i.e. k = 0): 4.3. Best-response dynamics limit,! We can now derive Theocharis (960) unstable triopoly result (i.e. bounded oscillations for n = 3 and exploding oscillations for n = 4) in the limit of naive expectations [! 0] and best-response dynamics [! ]. First we compute lim! p = 0 and then evaluate the period-doubling threshold (4.7) at! 0 yielding lim!;!0 np D (p (k)) = 3: (4.8) The intuition behind the original "two is stable, three is unstable" result had to do with the slope of a reaction curves (4.9) @R = n : For a duopoly game this slope is, in absolute values, always smaller than ; but it hits the instability threshold exactly at n = 3 and is larger than starting for a quadropoly game. This is exactly what our threshold n P D boils down to when we let players choose a best reply [! ] to Cournot (i.e. naively-determined) expectations [! 0]: Some further comparative statics can be informative about the role expectations play in (de) stabilizing a Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Ceteris paribus, the number of players instability threshold n increases in the degree of expectation adaptiveness []: @n P D p =@ = 4 ( + 2p ) 2 > 0: Intuitively, a larger implies that the unstable adaptive rule place a higher weight on remote observations in the past and thus it acts as an e ective stabilizing force. This, in turn, requires an even larger slope of the reaction curve (i.e. larger threshold n ) to de-stabilize the interior CN equilibrium. Similarly, we can show that @q 2 97

n decreases in the costs associated with the perfect foresight rule: @n P D (p (k))=@k < 0; as @n P D (p )=@p = 4 + (2p+ ) 2 > 0 and @p =@k < 0: For a given number of players, at the steady state, higher costs of rational expectations k; increase the payo di erential between the rational and the naive heuristics. Hence, more agents switch to the simple, yet destabilizing adaptive strategy. Thus, the system becomes more unstable and it takes a less steeper reaction curve (i.e. fewer players) to hit the period-doubling threshold (4.7). 4.3.2 Costly Rational Expectations, k > 0 and nite In the sequel we derive the threshold number of rms for which instability arises when there are positive costs associated with the perfect foresight and the other behavioural rule approaches either the Cournot ( = 0) or adaptive expectations (e.g. = 0:2). Recall from (4.7) that n P D = 2p 3 and 2p + p = : For small +exp(k) costs of the rational predictor (k = ) the period-doubling threshold is hit at: n P D k= = + 3e + e + e e (4.9) Table 4. reports unstable market structures in evolutionary Cournot games (i.e. number of players period-doubling, rounded thresholds (4.9)) for di erent adaptive expectations rule and intensity of choice : 98

= - "low" 5 - "high" 0 ("Cournot" expectation) 5 (quintopoly) 3 (triopoly) 0:2 ("adaptive" expectations) 0 (decapoly) 4 (quadropoly) Table 4.: Linear n-player Cournot game with costly Rational expectations. Unstable market structures for di erent expectations and behavioral parameterization. Game and behavioral parameters: a = 7; b = ; c = 0; k = ; = 0:: These analytically derived thresholds are con rmed by the numerically-computed bifurcations curves illustrated Fig. 4.2a-d. Higher values of the intensity of choice may destabilize a given market structure: larger e ectively implies turning on the evolutionary selection mechanism built into the model and population switching into/away from the adaptive, unstable heuristic. The two bottom panels in Fig. 4.2 display, for a quintopoly game, a strange attractors in the quantities chosen by the two types in the population (Panel (e)) and fractions of rational players-deviations from steady state quantity (Panel (f)). 99

(a) = 0; = : n P D =Quintopoly (b) = 0; = 5: n P D =Triopoly (c) = 0:2; = : n P D =Decapoly (d) = 0:2; = 5: n P D =Quadropoly (e) n = 5; = 0:2; = 0:65 (f) n = 5; = 0:2; = 0:65 Figure 4.2: Linear n-player Cournot game with costly Rational expectations. Bifurcation diagrams of the deviations Q from equilibrium quantity q with respect to number of rms n for Naive [ = 0] (Panel (a), (b)) and Adaptive [ = 0:2] (Panel (c), (d)) expectations. Panels (a)-(d): The rst period-doubling bifurcation threshold decreases in the intensity of choice parameter. Panels (e)-(f) display projection of a strange attractor onto the quantity-quantity and deviations from CNE quantity-fractions of RE players, respectively. Game and behavioral parameters: a = 7; b = ; c = 0; k = ; = 0:: 00

4.4 Conclusions We constructed an evolutionary version of Theocharis (960) seminal work on the stability of the Cournotian equilibrium in multi-player quantity-setting games. The assumption of homogenous naive expectations is relaxed and players are allowed to choose between a costless, adaptive rule and a costly, rational rule. The results are consistent with the original homogenous-expectations analysis of Theocharis, but the instability thresholds vary with the costs of the sophisticated rule and the degree of adaptiveness in the expectation formation process. One implication of the model is that by ne-tuning these two parameters a particular Cournot market structure can be (de)stabilized. For instance, the classical unstable Cournot triopoly may be stabilized via making the rational expectations predictor freely available. On the other hand, when rational expectations are costly a period-doubling bifurcation route to chaos arises when the number of players increases. 0