Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Similar documents
The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

ECON5110: Microeconomics

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Competitive Equilibrium

Econ 401A: Economic Theory Mid-term. Answers

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Second Welfare Theorem

Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

Adding Production to the Theory

a = (a 1; :::a i )

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

First Welfare Theorem

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Economics 101. Lecture 7 - Monopoly and Oligopoly

The Utility Frontier

PROFIT FUNCTIONS. 1. REPRESENTATION OF TECHNOLOGY 1.1. Technology Sets. The technology set for a given production process is defined as

Economics th April 2011

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

A function(al) f is convex if dom f is a convex set, and. f(θx + (1 θ)y) < θf(x) + (1 θ)f(y) f(x) = x 3

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course. Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Vector Spaces. Addition : R n R n R n Scalar multiplication : R R n R n.

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

Notes on General Equilibrium

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

The Real Business Cycle Model

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Economics 604: Microeconomics Deborah Minehart & Rachel Kranton

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

ECONOMICS 207 SPRING 2008 PROBLEM SET 13

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

2.9. V = u(x,y) + a(x-f(l x,t x )) + b(y-g(l y,t y )) + c(l o -L x -L y ) + d(t o -T x -T y ) (1) (a) Suggested Answer: V u a 0 (2) u x = -a b 0 (3)

Fixed Point Theorems

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Partial Differentiation

Introductory Microeconomics

0 Aims of this course

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Constrained optimization.

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

The Envelope Theorem

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture VII: Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

A MATHEMATICAL MODEL OF EXCHANGE

Solutions for Assignment #2 for Environmental and Resource Economics Economics 359M, Spring 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Transcription:

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production 1 The Second Welfare Theorem Last week we proved the First Basic Welfare Theorem, which states that under fairly weak assumptions, a Walrasian equilibrium is Pareto efficient. Now we will consider a result that can be thought of as a partial converse to that statement. Theorem 1 (Second Basic Welfare Theorem). When utility is concave, given any Pareto efficient allocation x, there is some initial allocation (endowments) e 1,..., e M that induces a Walrasian equilibrium with allocation x. So the Walrasian market can be thought of as a mechanism through which to achieve Pareto efficient allocations. Choosing the desired allocation is a matter of choosing the correct endowment. One additional implication of this result is that if the initial endowment itself is Pareto efficient, then there will be an equilibrium at that point for some prices p. In terms of policy, this result suggests that inducing desired allocation can be achieved using endowment transfers rather than taxation schemes. Example 1. Recall the 2 good, 2 allocation economy with Cobb-Douglas consumers that we discussed last lecture. The equilibrium price we found was p = (1 1 )e 1 1 + (1 2 )e 2 1 1 e 1 2 + 2 e 2 2 and the allocation is ( ) e x k 1 = k (e k 1 + p e k 2) and x k 2 = (1 k k ) 1 + p e k 2 Consider a set of allocations index by z [0, 1] e 1 1 = z and e 1 2 = z e 2 1 = 1 z and e 2 2 = 1 z p 1

In the Edgeworth box, this maps out a straight line from agent 1 s origin to agent 2 s origin. With this allocation, the equilibrium price is p = (1 1 )z + (1 2 )(1 z) 1 z + 2 (1 z) and the allocation is ( ) 1 + p x 1 1 = 1 z(1 + p ) and x 1 2 = (1 1 )z p ( ) 1 + p x 2 1 = 2 (1 z)(1 + p ) and x 2 2 = (1 2 )(1 z) With prices, we can derive p 1 + p = 2 1 z + 2 (1 z) and 1 + p p = 2 (1 1 )z + (1 2 )(1 z) Thus the allocation can be expressed as x 1 1 z 1 = 1 z + 2 (1 z) x 2 2 (1 z) 1 = 1 z + 2 (1 z) and x 1 (1 1 )z 2 = (1 1 )z + (1 2 )(1 z) and x 2 (1 2 )(1 z) 2 = (1 1 )z + (1 2 )(1 z) A Pareto efficient allocation must be feasible, which is evidently satisfied here. In addition, we saw last lecture that any Pareto efficient allocation must equate the marginal rates of substitution of each agent. In this setting that means 1 1 1 x1 2 x 1 1 = 2 1 2 x2 2 x 2 1 You can verify that indeed both marginal rates of substitution are equal to (1 1 )z + (1 2 )(1 z) 1 z + 2 (1 z) Therefore, all of these allocations are Pareto efficient, as we already knew from the first welfare theorem. Looking back to our original characterization of Pareto efficiency where we maximize W (x ), we can achieve the allocation resulting from a particular by simply setting z =. 2

As a final note, it is important to be aware that the second welfare theorem requires that utility be concave. That is, if concavity is not satisfied for each consumer, there can be Pareto efficient allocations that cannot be attained as a Walrasian equilibrium for any endowments. We know that at a Pareto efficient allocation, the marginal rates of substitution must be equal between the consumers. Furthermore, if it were to be a Walrasian equilibrium, the price ratio must also be equal to this common MRS value. If utility is concave, it is sufficient to conclude that consumers will optimally choose this allocation given these prices. However, without concavity, one of the consumers might choose some other point, meaning the desired point is not a Walrasian equilibrium. 2 Production Up until now, we ve been dealing with consumers with static, exogenous endowments who trade with one another in the Walrasian market. Obviously, this missed a lot of what goes on in the economy. Firms and production are an important component. To begin, we introduce an abstract notion of a firm. Firms maximize monetary profit by assumption. Since we have no stochastic elements, we don t have to worry about bankruptcy. A firm is characterized by a production function, which tells us how much of a certain output we get (say cars) for a given amount of inputs (say steel and labor). Formally, we say y = f(x), where x and y are vectors of inputs and outputs, respectively. Usually, y is onedimensional. As with consumers, firms face certain exogenously given prices. Take note that this is a very strong assumption in certain conditions. We may weaken this one later on. Let the price vector of outputs be p and the price vector of inputs be w (as is done in Varian). A firm s profits are then π(x) = p f(x) w x N O N I = p i f i (x) w j x j i=1 The only constraint is that x j 0 for all j, which we will generally omit. j=1 3

The firm s profit maximization problem is then max p f(x) w x x R N I + We can use Lagrangian techniques to derive conditions for optimal production. But first, we need to ensure that the conditions to use them hold. We need to ensure that profit is concave. To get this, we must assume that the production function is concave. For arbitrary x and y, we have π(θx + (1 θ)y) = p f(θx + (1 θ)y) w (θx + (1 θ)y) = p f(θx + (1 θ)y) θw x (1 θ)w y p [θf(x) + (1 θ)f(y)] θw x (1 θ)w y = θ [p f(x) w x] + (1 θ) [p f(y) w y] = θπ(x) + (1 θ)π(y) Thus profit is concave and we are free to use Lagrangian techniques so long as the production function is concave. Since there are no constraints, the Lagrangian is just the production function. For now, let s assume that there is only one output, so that L = p f(x) w x = pf(x) i w i x i Taking derivatives L x i = pf(x) i w i = 0 f i (x) = w i p So the first derivative of the production function with respect to x i, which we call the marginal product of good i, is equal to the ratio of the price of the output to the price of input i. Example 2. You thought you had escaped Cobb-Douglas, but it s actually a production function as well. It has the same functional form as the utility function, except we can t take logs as before f(x 1, x 2 ) = Ax 1 x 2 4

where > 0, > 0, and + < 1. Thus profits are π(x) = pf(x) w x = pax 1 x 2 w 1 x 1 w 2 x 2 Taking derivatives, we get These imply : x 1 : x 2 Apx 1 1 x 2 w 1 = 0 Apx 1 x 1 2 w 2 = 0 Diving, we find Apx 1 x 2 = w 1 x 1 Apx 1 x 2 = w 2 x 2 = w 1 x1 w 2 x 2 x 1 = w 2 x 2 w 1 From here we can use the first order condition for x 2 ( ) x1 Ap x 2 = w 2 x 2 x 2 ( ) ( ) w2 Ap = w 2 x 1 2 x 2 = w 1 [ A 1 ( ) ( p w2 w 2 w 1 ) ( ) ] 1 1 and by symmetry [ ( ) ( ) ( ) ] 1 1 p w1 x 1 = A w 1 w 2 So you can see that things kind of blow up if + 1. 5

2.1 An Alternative Interpretation Another way to think about production technologies is to use the concept of a production set. A production set is similar to a budget set, but for producers. It is simply the set of points (x, y) for which it is possible to produce at least y units of output using x units of input. For a production function f(x), the production set is simply Y = { } (x, y) R N I + R N O + y f(x) We can use this to imagine what the optimal choice will be. Since profits are π(x, y) = p y w x The optimal choice is the (x, y) Y that yields the highest value for profit max p y w x (x,y) Y In the case of 1 input and 1 output, consider a set of points in Y that yields some constant of profit π, which we can call an isoprofit line. This will satisfy π = py wx y = π p + ( w p Maximizing profit subject to being in Y will result in a point where the slope of the isoprofit line is equal to the slope of the boundary of Y (Actually, this is only true when Y is convex set, which is the case when f is a concave function.) As it happens, the slope of the boundary of Y is equal to the marginal product f (x). So we arrive at the same condition equating the marginal product to the ratio of prices of inputs to outputs. ) x 3 Returns to Scale One important property of production functions is how they behave locally at various levels of production. Along these lines, we define some terms to classify this behavior. 6

Decreasing Returns to Scale: For fixed input proportions, as inputs are scaled up, output scales up at a decreasing rate. Formally, for all x 1, x 2, and t > 1 tf(x 1, x 2 ) > f(tx 1, tx 2 ) For instance, if you go from using (x 1, x 2 ) as inputs to using (2x 1, 2x 2 ), your new production is less than 2 times the original production, i.e. The other two cases are f(2x 1, 2x 2 ) < 2f(x 1, x 2 ) Increasing Returns to Scale: For fixed input proportions, as inputs are scaled up, output scales up at a increasing rate. Formally, for all x 1, x 2, and t > 1 tf(x 1, x 2 ) < f(tx 1, tx 2 ) Constant Returns to Scale: For fixed input proportions, as inputs are scaled up, output scales up at a constant rate. Formally, for all x 1, x 2, and t > 1 tf(x 1, x 2 ) = f(tx 1, tx 2 ) We almost always assume either decreasing or constant returns to scale. The most common assumption is constant returns. Example 3. Consider varying the scale parameter with a Cobb-Douglas production function f(tx 1, tx 2 ) = A(tx 1 ) (tx 2 ) So the returns to scale condition becomes = Ax 1 x 2t = t f(x 1, x 2 ) tf(x 1, x 2 ) f(tx 1, tx 2 ) tf(x 1, x 2 ) t f(x 1, x 2 ) t t 1 + 7

with the last line coming from the fact that t > 1. So the returns to scale can be characterized by 4 Cost Minimization + < 1 decreasing returns + = 1 constant returns + > 1 increasing returns Often it is useful or insightful to consider the profit maximization problem as two nested subproblems. First, there is cost minimization: given a certain target level of output y, we wish to choose inputs x so as to produce exactly y units of output for the least cost. Here, the cost is simply that of buying the goods at their market prices w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 The minimization problem is then { min w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 C(y) = x 1,x 2 s.t. y = f(x 1, x 2 ) Once we have this defined, we can then recast profit maximization as max y py C(y) Let s use Lagrangian techniques to solve the cost minimization problem Taking derivatives L = w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 + λ [y f(x 1, x 2 )] L x 1 = w 1 λf 1 (x 1, x 2 ) = 0 L x 2 = w 2 λf 2 (x 1, x 2 ) = 0 Rearranging and dividing, we find the condition f 1 (x 1, x 2 ) f 2 (x 1, x 2 ) = w 1 w 2 The ratio of the marginal products equals the ratio of the input prices. This is analogous to an MRS condition for production. 8

Example 4. Let s look again at a Cobb-Douglas production function f(x 1, x 2 ) = Ax 1 x 2 The Lagrangian for the cost minimization problem is Taking derivatives These imply Dividing yields By symmetry L = w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 + λ(y Ax 1 x 2) L = w 1 λax 1 1 x 2 = 0 x 1 L = w 2 λax 1 x 1 2 = 0 x 2 w 1 x 1 = λax 1 x 2 = λy w 2 x 2 = λax 1 x 2 = λy w 1 x 1 = w 2 x 2 ( ) ( ) w1 x 2 = x 1 w 2 [( ) ( y = Ax 1 x w1 1 x 1 = x 2 = ( y A) 1 ( y A) 1 w 2 [( w1 w 2 [( w2 w 1 )] ) ( )] ) ( )] 9

Thus the total cost is C = w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 ( y 1 = w A) = ( yw1 w 2 A [ ( y = ( + ) A = Kw 1 w2 ) 1 +beta ( ) ( w 1 1 w2 y 1 [ ( + ) ) ( w2 ) + ( ) ] 1 ) ] where K is some constant. So we can see that input price increases raise the cost of producing a fixed y. Furthermore, producing more y costs more for fixed input prices. 4.1 Relationship with Returns to Scale A few moments of contemplation will reveal a linkage between cost functions and returns to scale. For any y, let C(y) be the cost of the optimal choices of x 1 and x 2, i.e., the minimal cost. If C(y) is linear, producing twice as much will simply cost twice as much, meaning we use twice as many inputs, thus the technology satisfies constant returns to scale. If C(y) is superlinear (convex), then producing twice as much costs more than twice as much, thus we are in the case of decreasing returns to scale. Finally, if C(y) is sublinear (concave), then producing twice as much costs less than twice as much, so the technology exhibits increasing returns to scale. Another way to think about this is to define average cost AC(y) = C(y) y This is just the per-unit cost of producing y. If f(x 1, x 2 ) has constant returns, then C(y) is linear and AC(y) is constant. If f has decreasing returns, C(y) is superlinear, meaning AC(y) is increasing. If f has increasing returns, C(y) is sublinear, so AC(y) is decreasing. 10

Example 5. Recall that the cost function for Cobb-Douglas was of the form C(y) = Ky 1 We can see that the concavity/convexity of C(y) depends on whether 1, the same condition that determines its returns to scale. Average costs are of the form AC(y) = Ky 1 which again comports with the discussing on returns to scale. 11