Module 8: Multi-Agent Models of Moral Hazard

Similar documents
Module 16: Signaling

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

1 Moral Hazard: Multiple Agents 1.1 Moral Hazard in a Team

Moral Hazard in Teams

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions

Teoria das organizações e contratos

What happens when there are many agents? Threre are two problems:

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Optimal Incentive Contract with Costly and Flexible Monitoring

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Moral hazard in teams

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Introduction to Game Theory

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework

Contests for Experimentation

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Module 18: VCG Mechanism

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

George Georgiadis. Joint work with Jakša Cvitanić (Caltech) Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University

Contracts in informed-principal problems with moral hazard

5. Relational Contracts and Career Concerns

Basics of Game Theory

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

Moral Hazard. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Advanced Microeconomics II - Washington State University

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I

This is designed for one 75-minute lecture using Games and Information. October 3, 2006

Organization, Careers and Incentives

A note on the take-it-or-leave-it bargaining procedure with double moral hazard and risk neutrality

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

arxiv: v4 [cs.gt] 13 Sep 2016

Theory of Auctions. Carlos Hurtado. Jun 23th, Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

Moral Hazard: Hidden Action

(a) Output only takes on two values, so the wage will also take on two values: z(0) = 0 0 z(0) 0. max s(d)z { d. n { z 1 0 (n + d) 2.

Linear Contracts. Ram Singh. February 23, Department of Economics. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, / 22

Lecture Notes on Solving Moral-Hazard Problems Using the Dantzig-Wolfe Algorithm

Collective Production and Incentives

Lecture Slides - Part 4

Optimal Shirking in Teams

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Equilibrium Refinements

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3

ECO421: Moral hazard. Marcin P ski. March 26, 2018

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics"

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework

Guilt in Games. P. Battigalli and M. Dufwenberg (AER, 2007) Presented by Luca Ferocino. March 21 st,2014

Moral Hazard: Characterization of SB

Moral Hazard. EC202 Lectures XV & XVI. Francesco Nava. February London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures XV & XVI Feb / 19

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

Multi prizes for multi tasks: externalities and the optimal design of tournaments

Incentives versus Competitive Balance

Crowdsourcing contests

Hidden information. Principal s payoff: π (e) w,

When to Ask for an Update: Timing in Strategic Communication

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry

On the Informed Principal Model with Common Values

LEN model. And, the agent is risk averse with utility function for wealth w and personal cost of input c (a), a {a L,a H }

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

Game Theory Review Questions

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

D i (w; p) := H i (w; S(w; p)): (1)

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Impatience vs. Incentives

A Principal-Agent Model of Sequential Testing

Introduction to Game Theory. Outline. Topics. Recall how we model rationality. Notes. Notes. Notes. Notes. Tyler Moore.

Spence s labor market signaling model

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Microeconomics. 2. Game Theory

Three Essays on Economic Agents Incentives and Decision Making

Game Theory, Information, Incentives

Relative Performance Evaluation

COMMON-VALUE ALL-PAY AUCTIONS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND BID CAPS. Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach and Aner Sela. Discussion Paper No.

Some Notes on Moral Hazard

NTU IO (I) : Auction Theory and Mechanism Design II Groves Mechanism and AGV Mechansim. u i (x, t i, θ i ) = V i (x, θ i ) + t i,

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB)

Optimality of Quota Contract

Optimal Sequence for Teamwork

Bayesian Games and Auctions

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

The Value of Symmetric Information in an Agency Model with Moral Hazard: The Ex Post Contracting Case

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006)

Game Theory Fall 2003

Economics of Leadership and Hierarchy

Introduction to game theory LECTURE 1

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Transcription:

Module 8: Multi-Agent Models of Moral Hazard Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis Types of models: 1. No relation among agents. an many agents make contracting easier? 2. Agents shocks are correlated. e.g., output of agent i is given by q i = + i and i s are positively correlated. Output of agent i contains information about the e orts of all the other agents. 3. Joint production. Try to separate the agents performance given joint output. 4. Each agent may have information about the e ort choices of the other agents. Problem Formulation (with 2 agents): 2 risk-neutral agents Agent i takes action at cost c ( ) Agent i s utility: u i = w i c ( ) Output of agent i: q i = + i, where 1 is independent of 2, and E [ i ]=0. First best: max E [q w (q) ],w( ) s.t. E [w (q) c ( ) ] ū (IR) 1

Straightforward that (IR) binds. Then E [w (q)] = c ( )+ū. Then the maximization problem reduces to: FO: c 0 ( )=1. max {E [q c ( ) ] ū} =max { c ( ) ū} Implement with a Tournament onsider a two-player tournament where the winner is the player who produces the highest q. Prizes w H and w L for the agent with the higher and lower output, respectively. Idea: ontestants pre-commit their investments early in life, knowing the prizes and the rules of the game. Pr {i wins} =Pr{q i >q j } =Pr{ + i >a j + j } =Pr{ j i < a j } = H ( a j ), where H ( ) is the cdf of j i. Agent i s problem: max w H H ( a j )+w L [1 H ( a j )] c ( ) FO: (w H w L ) h ( a j )=c 0 ( ) Symmetric equilibrium =) = a j = a =) c 0 (a )=(w H w L ) h (0). Each agent wins with probability 1 2. (1) Equilibrium e ort is first best if (w H w L ) h (0) = 1. (2) For (IR) to be satisfied, w H,w L must satisfy: w H+w L 2 c (a )=ū. Obtain w H,w L by solving (1) and (2). Advantages: 2

Simplicity Private evaluation robustness With individual incentives, if explicit contracts cannot be written down, firms may not pay the bonus. (May be solved by repeated interaction, but only partially.) If a prize must be given, might as well give it to the best performer. Disadvantages: Asymmetric equilibria Risk aversion causes problems Solution depends on the specification of h ( ) ollusion Sabotage If uncertainty unfolds gradually and agents can change their e orts (after observing the realization of shocks), e ort decreases as the gap between the leader and the laggard increases: Tournaments can undermine incentives in a dynamic setting. Holmstrom (Bell Journal, 1982) n risk-neutral agents, each with reservation utility ū. Agent i s utility: u i = t i c ( ) Action 2 A i R, and c ( ) is convex. Output (deterministic): q (a), where a = {a 1,..,a n }, q ( ) is di erentiable and dq d > 0. e.g., q = P n i=1 First best: a 2 arg max {q (a) P i c ()} Any internal maximum satisfies dq(a ) d = c 0 (a i ) for all i. P Assume q (a ) i c P (a i ) i ūi. Split proceeds {t i } i such that (i) t i c (a i ) ū i for all i and (ii) P i t i = q (a ). 3

Moral Hazard Problem: Use output sharing rule {t i (q)} i such that P i t i (q) =q (balanced budget). Assume that t i (q) is di erentiable. Agent i s Problem: max t i (q (, ã i )) c ( ) FO: t 0 i (q (ã)) dq(ã) d = c 0 (ã i ) t 0 i (q) is agent i s marginal pay per-unit of output. an we implement first best a? From the first best FO and each agent s FO, it must be the case that t 0 i (q (a )) = 1 for all i =) t i (q) =q F i. But then, the budget balance constraint is violated; i.e., P i t i (q) =nq cannot hold for all q. P i F i = q To obtain first-best, every agent must get his marginal $, but this is impossible!) =) there exists no budget balanced sharing rule that achieves first best. Intuition: Each agent must share the marginal benefit of his output, but he alone bears its cost. How to obtain First Best? 1. Destroy output: Let: Problems: t i (q) = ( t i if q = q (a ) K otherwise. (a) Not renegotiation proof. (b) What if output is random? (Multiple equilibria.) 2. Budget breaker: Introduce (n +1) th agent. 4

Let: t i (q) = q F i for all i 2 {1,..,n} nx t n+1 (q) = q t i (q) = X F i (n 1) q i=1 i where F i are transfers from agent i to the (n +1) th agent. hoose {F i } i such that t n+1 (q (a )) = 0; i.e., P i F i =(n 1) q (a ). Problems: (a) How to interpret budget breaker? (Not a manager. Observe that BB pays more, the lower the output.) (b) BB has incentives to sabotage. 3. Spotting Individual Deviations: Suppose A i is discrete: q (a) 6= q (a 0 ) for all a 6= a 0. Use the following scheme: 8 >< t i (q) = >: t i if q = q (a ) K if q = q, a i 6= q (a ) q+k n 1 if q = q (a i, ) 6= q (a ) q n otherwise. Di erent Types of Implementation 2agents E ort a 2 {L, H}; cost of e ort c L = 0 and c H = >0. Project succeeds or fails and Pr {success} = P (x), where x = # of agents who exert a = H. P (x) increases in x. Increasing returns: P (2) P (1) > P(1) P (0) (i.e., agents e orts are complements). What is the cheapest way for a principal to incentivize workers? ontract for worker i: w i 1 {success} (agent is protected by limited liability) 5

1. Partial Implementation: hoose w i s such that there exists an equilibrium in which both agents work. Assume agent i believes that agent i will work. Then (I i ) w i P (2) w i P (1) =) w i P (2) P (1) = wp (1) The other agent faces the same constraint. Suppose that each agent receives w P when the project succeeds. What happens to contract given in (1) if agent i beliefs that agent i will shirk? Write agent i s I: w P P (1) w P P (0) P (1) =) P (2) P (1) P (0) P (2) P (1) =) P (1) P (2) + P (1) P (0) =) P (2) P (1) apple P (1) P (0) ontradicts the assumption that e orts are complements Therefore, if an agent believes that the other agent will shirk, then he will also shirk (i.e., 2 Nash equilibria). 2. Full Implementation: How can we ensure that both agents exerting a = H is the unique equilibrium? One possibility is to set w 1 = w 2 =. an we do better? P (1) P (0) Yes! hoose w 1 such that agent 1 finds it optimal to exert a = H no matter what. Then set w 2 = w P =. Given that agent 1 exerts a = H, agent 2 will P (2) P (1) also exert a = H. To ensure that agent 1 exerts a = H no matter what, we need: w 1 P (1) w 1 P (0) =) w 1 P (1) P (0) 6

and w 1 w P. Because P (1) P (0) >wp, we set w F 1 = P (1) P (0) and wf 2 = P (2) P (1). Full implementation: oncerned with characterizing all Nash equilibria. Partial implementation: haracterizing one (of possibly many) Nash equilibria. 3. Sequential Implementation: Suppose agent 1 chooses a 1. Agent 2 observes agent 1 s choice and chooses a 2. observable but not contractible.) (We assume that e ort is Working backwards: w S 2 = P (2) P (1), i.e., agent 2 finds it optimal to work when agent 1 works. We want to choose the wage of agent 1 such that he works, and as a consequence, agent 2 also works. Agent 1 s I constraint: w S 1 P (2) w S 1 P (0) =) w S 1 = P (2) P (0). Because P (1) >P(0), w S 1 >w S 2. There exists a unique equilibrium in which both agents work. Observe that 2w P <w S 1 + w S 2 <w F 1 + w F 2. References Board S., (2011), Lecture Notes. Bolton and Dewatripont, (2005), ontract Theory, MIT Press. Holmstrom B., (1982), Moral Hazard in Teams, Bell Journal of Economics. Winter E., (2004), Incentives and Discrimination, American Economic Review. Winter E., (2006), Optimal Incentives for Sequential Production Processes, RAND Journal of Economics. 7