Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Similar documents
In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Competitive Equilibrium

The Envelope Theorem

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

General Equilibrium and Welfare

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Second Welfare Theorem

Economics th April 2011

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Advanced Microeconomics

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Constrained optimization.

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium.

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Advanced Macroeconomics

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

a. This is an inequality constrained maximization problem. The Lagrangian is µ 1 q 1 = 0 µ 2 q 2 = 0 1 (q 1 ) φ φ c 2 (q 2) p 1 c 1(q 1 ) = 0

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Econ Macroeconomics I Optimizing Consumption with Uncertainty

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Basics of Game Theory

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Introduction to Continuous-Time Dynamic Optimization: Optimal Control Theory

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Adding Production to the Theory

EconS Sequential Competition

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Lecture Notes: Math Refresher 1

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Long-run Analysis of Production. Theory of Production

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Mathematics Review Revised: January 9, 2008

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Problem Set 1: Tariffs and Quotas (Solutions) Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Economics of European Integration TA: Victor Troster Fall 2012

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Econ 8601: Industrial Organization (Thomas J. Holmes) Lecture 1. Part 1: The Cost of Monopoly in General Equilibrium. μ 1

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

The Monopolist. The Pure Monopolist with symmetric D matrix

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #10 - Externalities

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Notes on Winnie Choi s Paper (Draft: November 4, 2004; Revised: November 9, 2004)

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Advanced Macroeconomics

School of Business. Blank Page

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Can everyone benefit from innovation?

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Transcription:

What is market design? Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. This requires different tools and ideas than neoclassical economics, which arose in the 18th century and sought to explain broad trends in the absence of data and direct applications Market design problems are often subject to difficult constraints (money or prices cannot be used, certain quotas must be met, participants can lie about their objectives, there are legal or social customs to be respected) The frictionless ideal: perfectly competitive markets Consumption and production don t impose costs or benefits on other parties (no externalities) Households and firms take prices as given and decide quantities (no market power) The market is centralized, trade occurs all at once (no search frictions) All relevant information is known to all parties (complete information) The only relevant good is the one we are studying in isolation (complete markets) The frictionless ideal: perfectly competitive markets We ll start with the firm/production side, then consider the consumer/consumption side. Once we understand both sides of the market, we ll put them together at look at equilibrium. We ll look at two representative agents. What we re really thinking of is a large number of identical firms and households who all behave more or less the same. To keep things concrete, we ll use particular functional forms rather than more general ones. The presentation might be more mathematical than you re used to, even though we ll get the same results and pictures: that s part of building up to more abstract models later. The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior A representative firm receives a price p per unit of a good it sells, and it costs C(q) = c 2 q2 to produce q units. Then Total revenue of q units is pq 1

Total costs are C(q) = c 2 q2 Profits are the difference between total revenue and total cost, π(q) = pq C(q) = pq c 2 q2 How do we find the profit-maximizing quantity, q, for which π(q ) π(q ) for any other q the firm could pick? The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior Let s start by thinking about searching for a maximum, starting from some arbitrary quantity q. Consider the change in profit from using some other quantity, q : ( π(q) π(q ) = pq c 2 q2) (pq c 2 q 2) Now, divide by q q to get = p(q q ) c 2 (q + q )(q q ) π(q) π(q ) q q = p c 2 (q + q ) This represents the normalized gain/loss to switching from q to q. The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior We now take the limit as q goes to q: or π(q) π(q ) lim q q q q = lim p c q q 2 (q + q ) π (q) = p cq So the change in profit π(q) when evaluated at the optimal quantity q equals p cq. If this is positive, it means that profits are increasing at q, so we should pick a larger value. If this is negative, it means that profits are decreasing at q, and we should pick a smaller value. Only when π (q ) = 0 do we know that there are no better options than q nearby. (Maximization in general) 2

( ) ( ) >0 (Maximization in general) So for x to solve max f(x), x it is necessary that f (x ) = 0; we call the equation f (x ) = 0 the first-order necessary conditions. For some problems, this approach doesn t work. Why not? The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior Now we know that a necessary condition for q to be a maximum of π(q) is that π (q ) = p cq = 0 or q = p c In other words, the firm s supply curve is q S = p/c. The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior 3

: = The perfectly competitive market: Consumer behavior There is a representative consumer who buy the good q along with another good, we ll call m, the numeraire or money. The consumer has a utility function over bundles (q, m) of u(q, m) = b log(q) + m The consumer also faces a budget constraint, w = pq + m, so that total expenditures on the two goods cannot be more than w. What bundle should the consumer pick? (Quick aside: Quasilinear utility ) In the way we specified utility, we have u(q, m) = b log(q) + m, where m is money spent on goods besides q. We call this kind of utility function quasilinear since m enters additively or linearly. It implies that there are no substitution effects between consumption of this good and the others that the consumer purchases, or that this good is a small fraction of the consumer s total budget. We ll use this idea over and over later in class. The perfectly competitive market: Consumer behavior 4

Rather than use Lagrange multipliers, we can rewrite the budget constraint as m = w pq and substitute it into the utility function to get max b log(q) + w pq q which is unconstrained in q, making it a much easier problem to solve. Then our necessary condition is giving us an demand curve, q D = b p. b q p = 0 q = b p The perfectly competitive market: Consumer behavior : = / Market Equilibrium Definition 1. A price-quantity pair (p, q ) is a price-taking equilibrium or perfectly competitive equilibrium if 1. Firms maximize profits, taking the price as given. 2. Consumers maximize utility, taking the price as given. 3. Markets clear, so that supply equals demand, or q S = q D. 5

We ve already solved for supply and demand above, so all that s left to do is equate them: so that p = bc and q = b c. q S = p c = b p = qd Market Equilibrium : = : = / Market Equilibrium This model gives all the basic predictions of principles micro: Demand is downward sloping (LOD), supply is upward sloping (LOS) If there s a positive shock to demand (i.e., b increases), quantity demanded shifts up at all prices, and the market-clearing price and quantity increase. If there s a positive shock to supply (i.e., c increases), quantity supplied shifts down at all prices, and the market-clearing price goes up while the market-clearing quantity goes down. If b and c change at the same time, it s difficult to say much about what happens. 6

Perfectly competitive markets in general There are i = 1, 2,..., I consumers who each choose a bundle of goods (q i, m i ) to maximize its utility, v i (q) + m i, subject to the constraint pq i + m i = w i, taking prices as given. There are j = 1, 2,..., J firm who each choose how much quantity q j to supply to maximize its profits, π j (q j ) = pq j C j (q j ), taking prices as given. A perfectly competitive equilibrium is then a price p, a set of quantities demanded (q,..., q i=i ), and a set of quantities supplied (q,..., q j=j ) such that households are maximizing their utilities taking the price as given, firms are maximizing their profits taking the price as given, and markets clear: qi = What are reasonable assumptions to make about what v i (q i ) and C j (q j ) look like? The perfectly competitive market: Firm behavior in general Each firm j then solves q j max q j pq j C j (q j ), which has the FONC p = C j (q j ), or price equals marginal cost. Each consumer then solves max q i v i (q i ) pq i + w i, which has the FONC v i (q i ) = p, or marginal benefit equals price. At the perfectly competitive equilibrium, for every household i and firm j, v i (q i ) = p = C j (q j ), so the price, marginal cost, and marginal benefit of the last units produced or consumed are equated across all firms and consumers. The Welfare Theorem Rather than letting the market determine the outcome, what if a benevolent social planner decided the quantities (q,..., q i=i ) and (q,..., q j=j )? How would the outcome be different? Definition 2. The social planner s problem is found by summing the payoffs of all the agents, and maximizing the resulting social welfare function. The outcome that maximizes the social welfare function is efficient. 7

Here, the social welfare function is the sum of profits and utility, giving us W (q) = = (v i (q i ) pq i + w i ) + (pq j C j (q j )) (v i (q i ) + w i ) C j (q j ) The Welfare Theorem So we want to maximize subject to (v i (q i ) + w i ) q i = C j (q j ) q j. This is a constrained maximization problem, and we need a Lagrangian to solve it. Lagrangians Suppose you want to maximize f(x 1,..., x N ) subject to a constraint like p 1 x 1 +... + p N x N = w. The Lagrangian function works like this: 1. Move all the terms in your constraint to the same side of the equality: p 1 x 1 +... + p N x N w = 0. 2. Multiply by λ, where λ is the Lagrange multiplier, and add to your objective function: L(x, λ) = f(x 1,..., x N ) λ (p 1 x 1 +... + p N x N w) 3. Take derivatives with respect to each variable you are maximizing and the Lagrange multiplier: for each i, f(x) x i λp i = 0, and (p 1 x 1 +... + p N x N w) = 0. 8

Lagrangians The Lagrangian function works like this: 1. The constraint becomes: q i q j = 0. 2. The Lagrangian is: L(q, λ) = i (q i ) + w i ) (v C j (q j ) λ q i 3. The FONCs are v i (q i ) λ = 0 for each household i, and C j (q j )+λ = 0 ( I for each firm j, and for the Lagrange multiplier, q i ) J q j = 0 The Welfare Theorem But the Lagrangian FONCS imply and v i(q i ) = λ = C j(q j ) qi = qj, so the Lagrange multiplier at the optimum must be the same as the price in the perfectly competitive market, and the outcomes must be the same. Theorem 3. Perfectly competitive markets maximize (utilitarian) social welfare. The Welfare Theorem What does the welfare theorem say? If 1. no agents consumption/production decisions have a direct impact on the utility of other agents... 2. no agents have market power... 3. all agents meet and trade at the same time... 4. all agents are completely informed... 5. this good can be studied in isolation from the rest of the economy and society... then markets implement the same outcome a benevolent government would pick. q j 9

Interpretations of the Welfare Theorem The traditional capitalist: Governments actually don t and couldn t aggregate all the information available to firms and consumers and pick outcomes, so it s best to leave the job to markets despite their other flaws. Sure, these flaws create inefficiencies, but entrepreneurs will step in to resolve them and pick up the rents themselves. The traditional socialist: Markets are only really optimal when all of the problems have been assumed away. Market power, incomplete information, and search frictions are huge problems. The obvious fix for these flaws is for the government to intervene directly through regulation. Institutions We see both entrepreneurs and regulation throughout the economy: Signaling: credentials, accreditation, resumes, guilds; university degrees Screening: discounts, coupons, price schedules/discrimination; business vs coach Intermediaries: universities, headhunters, market makers, e-commerce; Google, Uber, Walmart Financial instruments: derivatives, futures, insurance; MacDonald s and the McRib Policy: licensing, auditing, inspections, taxes/subsidies, artificial markets, black markets, crime, tariffs; farm subsidies Welfare Why did our social planner maximize the sums of household utilities and firm profits? The answer is: it seems like a reasonable thing to do, but there are many, other reasonable things to do As a society, the way we decide how to evaluate welfare is important, and (despite its role in economics) utilitarianism is a questionable philosophy in general Classic Notions of Welfare Suppose there are agents i = 1,..., N with utility functions u i (x) over some outcome x. We wish to discuss the relative social desirability of different outcomes x. 10

Utilitarian: The best x solves Rawlsian: The best x solves U r = max x U R = max x N u i (x) min u i (x) i Pareto dominance: An outcome x Pareto dominates x if for all i, u i (x) u i (x ) and for at least one i, u i (x) > u i (x ). An outcome x is Pareto optimal if no outcome x Pareto dominates it. Where does the firehouse go? Households are uniformly distributed between zero and one Suppose we are deciding where to place a firehouse, x [0, 1] For each i in [0, 1], the payoff to that household is u i (x) = x i, the distance from i to x. Utilitarian welfare is W u = x 0 (i x)di + 1 What x maximizes utilitarian welfare? x (x i)di = x x 2 1 2. Rawlsian welfare is W R = { x, x 1/2 (1 x), x < 1/2. What x maximizes Rawlsian welfare? What selections of x are Pareto optimal? How does economics work? Economics has two modes: Positive: how the world is Normative: how the world should be Especially in a class like this one, it is easy to confuse a few things: The consequences of equilibrium analyses are intended to be positive claims, not normative ones: the concept of a price-taking equilibrium is not prescriptive, it is an attempt to describe how the world works 11

When we do welfare and efficiency analyses, we are saying, if you are a profit-maximizer/utilitarian/rawlsian/etc, the best thing to do is X, not X is what everyone should do In (actual) social science, you need to conceptualize the world to understand it, but also to understand how that model or theory leads to conclusions. Do not assume the conclusions you prefer and attempt to justify them. 12