Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Similar documents
Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Internation1al Trade

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Trade Policies, Firm Heterogeneity, and Variable Markups

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

competition: the choice of scope

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Online Appendix for Trade Policy under Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Quality Heterogeneity and Misallocation: The Welfare Benefits of Raising your Standards Other VES Preferences

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Granular Comparative Advantage

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Trade Liberalization and Pollution in Melitz-Ottaviano Model

Non-Homothetic Gravity

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

International Trade. Lecture 4: the extensive margin of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 17

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Granular Comparative Advantage

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Monopolistic Competition in Trade III Trade Costs and Gains from Trade

The Impact of Trade Liberalization on Industrial Productivity

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane?

Monopolistic Competition Model with Endogeneous Investments: the case of Closed Economy

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Eaton Kortum Model (2002)

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Imperfect Competition and Misallocations

International Trade 31E00500

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption

Modeling firms locational choice

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Trade and the Environment: The Role of Firm Heterogeneity

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Welfare in the Eaton-Kortum Model of International Trade

Misallocation Under Trade Liberalization

Trade, Wages, and Productivity

Modeling Technological Change

Topics in Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory: On the Causes and Consequences of Income Growth and Uncertainty

Globalization and Individual Gains from Trade (revised version)

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices

Trade, wages, and productivity

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Class Notes on New Economic Geography Models

CEP Discussion Paper No 1206 April 2013

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Trade, wages, and productivity

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Trade, wages and productivity. Working Paper Research. by Kristian Behrens, Giordano Mion, Yasusada Murata and Jens Südekum.

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture VII: Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

Does Improved Market Access Raise Plant-Level Productivity? Alla Lileeva. Daniel Trefler

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Advanced Microeconomics

Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Quantifying the Losses from International Trade

Quality and Gravity in International Trade

Trade, Firm Selection, and Innovation: the Competition Channel

The Elusive Pro-Competitive Effects of Trade

Trade Models with Heterogeneous Firms: What About Importing?

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

ENTRY, EXIT AND MISALLOCATION FRICTIONS JOB MARKET PAPER 1

Multiple-Quality Cournot Oligopoly and the Role of Market Size

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect

Competitive Equilibrium

1. Money in the utility function (start)

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Trade and Domestic Policies in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Transcription:

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20

& & 2 / 20

My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20

Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) set up a model similar to Melitz (2003) featuring monopolistic competition firm heterogeneity & 4 / 20

Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) set up a model similar to Melitz (2003) featuring monopolistic competition firm heterogeneity In addition, they model a linear demand system (with a homogenous good) endogenous markups, which respond to the toughness of competition in the market (feedback channel) & 4 / 20

Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) set up a model similar to Melitz (2003) featuring monopolistic competition firm heterogeneity In addition, they model a linear demand system (with a homogenous good) endogenous markups, which respond to the toughness of competition in the market (feedback channel) This new, highly tractable framework allows market size differences to play a role incorporates all (conventional) channels for welfare gains allows for analysis of various trade liberalization scenarios between several asymmetric countries & 4 / 20

I Preferences L consumers in each country share preferences U = q0 c + α qi c i Ω di 1 2 γ i Ω (q c i ) 2 di 1 2 η ( qi c i Ω over a continuum of differentiated varieties q i, i Ω and a homogenous good q 0 (numeraire with q c 0 > 0 by assumption). ) 2 di γ > 0 is the degree of product differentiation between varieties, so if γ 0 consumers only care about total consumption of all varieties Q c = i Ω qc i di α, η > 0 govern substitutability between q i & q 0, α or η = relative increase in demand for Q c & 5 / 20

II Demand Each consumer maximizes U s. t. the budget constraint = inverse demand: p i = α γq c i ηq c for all q c i > 0 Hence, we arrive at the linear market demand system: q i Lqi c = αl ηn + γ L γ p i + ηn L ηn + γ γ p, i Ω, where N is the measure of consumed varieties (Ω Ω) and p = 1 N i Ω p i di is the average price. & 6 / 20

II Demand Each consumer maximizes U s. t. the budget constraint = inverse demand: p i = α γq c i ηq c for all q c i > 0 Hence, we arrive at the linear market demand system: q i Lqi c = αl ηn + γ L γ p i + ηn L ηn + γ γ p, i Ω, where N is the measure of consumed varieties (Ω Ω) and p = 1 N i Ω p i di is the average price. In contrast to CES preferences, the price elasticity of demand ɛ = ( q i / pi)(p i /q i ) = [(p max /p i ) 1] 1 is not exclusively determined by product differentiation γ. & p max is the upper price bound, where demand for q i equals 0. 6 / 20

III Welfare Plugging qi c into U yields the following expression for welfare (indirect utility): U = I c + 1 2 ( η + γ ) 1 (α p) 2 + 1 N N 2 γ σ2 p, I c denotes the income of the consumer σ 2 p is the variance of prices & 7 / 20

III Welfare Plugging qi c into U yields the following expression for welfare (indirect utility): U = I c + 1 2 ( η + γ ) 1 (α p) 2 + 1 N N 2 γ σ2 p, I c denotes the income of the consumer σ 2 p is the variance of prices Welfare U rises with decreases in the average price p & increases in the variance of prices σ 2 p increases in N = love of variety 7 / 20

IV Production Markets for labor & the homogenous good: Each consumer inelastically supplies 1 unit of labor L, which is the only input factor of production. q 0 produced with constant returns to scale at unit cost assuming perfect competition for L & q 0 = w = 1 & 8 / 20

IV Production Markets for labor & the homogenous good: Each consumer inelastically supplies 1 unit of labor L, which is the only input factor of production. q 0 produced with constant returns to scale at unit cost assuming perfect competition for L & q 0 = w = 1 Monopolistic competition in the differentiated sector: After having incurred sunk entry cost f E (R & D), firms draw their marginal cost c (unit labor requirement) from the distribution G(c) with support on [0, c M ]. Then, they find out whether they can produce or not. Production technology is also CRS (no fixed prod. cost) & 8 / 20

V Firm Performance Firms which can cover their marginal cost c produce the profit-maximizing quantity q(c) = L γ [p(c) c], otherwise they exit. The firm with cost c D is just indifferent whether to produce: p(c D ) = p max = c D (< c M by ass.) & 9 / 20

V Firm Performance Firms which can cover their marginal cost c produce the profit-maximizing quantity q(c) = L γ [p(c) c], otherwise they exit. The firm with cost c D is just indifferent whether to produce: p(c D ) = p max = c D (< c M by ass.) Then, each firm s performance depends only on its cost draw c and the cutoff c D : p(c) = 1 2 (c D + c) µ(c) = 1 2 (c D c) q(c) = L 2γ (c D c) r(c) = p(c)q(c) = L 4γ (c2 D c2 ) π(c) = r(c) q(c)c = L 4γ (c D c) 2 & 9 / 20

VI & Zero expected profits in equilibrium = Free entry (FE): cd 0 π(c) dg(c) = L 4γ cd 0 (c D c) 2 dg(c) = f E. & 10 / 20

VI & Zero expected profits in equilibrium = Free entry (FE): cd 0 π(c) dg(c) = L 4γ cd 0 (c D c) 2 dg(c) = f E. Using these results, we can determine the cutoff: c D = 1 (γα + ηn p) ηn + γ and the zero cutoff profit (ZCP) condition: N = 2γ η α c D c D c, where c = [ c D 0 c dg(c)]/g(c D) is the average cost of surviving firms. This yields the equilibrium number of firms N and entrants N E = N/G(c D ). & 10 / 20

VII Parametrization of Technology Assuming productivity 1/c is Pareto distributed implies the power cost distribution of surviving firms: ( ) c k G(c) =, c [0, c D ] c D & 11 / 20

VII Parametrization of Technology Assuming productivity 1/c is Pareto distributed implies the power cost distribution of surviving firms: ( ) c k G(c) =, c [0, c D ] c D Given this assumption, the cost cutoff is: [ 2(k + 1)(k + 2)γ(cM ) k f E c D = L ] 1 k+2 The zero cutoff profit (ZCP) condition then implies: & N = 2(k + 1)γ η α c D c D 11 / 20

VIII Outcome The cutoff c D uniquely determines the averages of all firm-level performance measures: c = k k+1 c D p = 2k+1 µ = 1 2 2k+2 c D 1 k+1 c D q = r = L 2γ L 2γ π = f E (c M ) k (c D ) k 1 k+1 c D = (k+2)(c M) k f (c D ) k+1 E 1 k+2 (c D) 2 = (k+1)(c M) k f (c D ) k E & 12 / 20

VIII Outcome The cutoff c D uniquely determines the averages of all firm-level performance measures: c = k k+1 c D p = 2k+1 µ = 1 2 2k+2 c D 1 k+1 c D q = r = L 2γ L 2γ π = f E (c M ) k (c D ) k 1 k+1 c D = (k+2)(c M) k f (c D ) k+1 E 1 k+2 (c D) 2 = (k+1)(c M) k f (c D ) k E...as well as welfare, which increases with a lower cutoff c D : U = 1 + 1 ( 2η (α c D) α k + 1 ) k + 2 c D & 12 / 20

I 2 countries indexed l, h = H, F (for simplicity, can be extended) that only differ in size L l and trade barriers (same preferences and technology) per-unit trade costs τ l > 1 (no fixed export costs) & 13 / 20

I 2 countries indexed l, h = H, F (for simplicity, can be extended) that only differ in size L l and trade barriers (same preferences and technology) per-unit trade costs τ l > 1 (no fixed export costs) Due to CRS and segmented markets, firms maximize domestic and export profits independently s. t. the same demand condition as in the closed economy. This leads to the following cutoff rules: cd l = pl max c l X = pmax/τ h h = cd h /τ h for firms exporting from l to h As before, cutoffs summarize all performance measures, in particular: p l D (c) = 1 2 (cl D + c) pl X (c) = 1 2 (cl X + c) & 13 / 20

II Assuming Pareto productivity distribution, free entry implies: L l (c l D )k+2 + L h ρ h (c h D )k+2 = γφ, where φ 2(k + 1)(k + 2)(c M ) k f E (technology index) and ρ l (τ l ) k (0, 1) measures freeness of trade. & 14 / 20

II Assuming Pareto productivity distribution, free entry implies: L l (c l D )k+2 + L h ρ h (c h D )k+2 = γφ, where φ 2(k + 1)(k + 2)(c M ) k f E (technology index) and ρ l (τ l ) k (0, 1) measures freeness of trade. This system of equations can be solved for the cutoffs: ] 1 k+2, l = H, F. c l D = [ γφ L l 1 ρ h 1 ρ l ρ h The mass of firms N l in the open economy is then given by & N l = 2(k + 1)γ η α c l D c l D 14 / 20

III The expressions for all average firm performance measures are analogous to the closed economy and so is the term for welfare: U l = 1 + 1 2η (α cl D ) ( α k + 1 ) k + 2 cl D & 15 / 20

III The expressions for all average firm performance measures are analogous to the closed economy and so is the term for welfare: U l = 1 + 1 2η (α cl D ) ( α k + 1 ) k + 2 cl D Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) show that c l X < cl D, so only relatively more productive firms export. Furthermore, it can be shown that in the trade equilibrium reciprocal dumping occurs: px l (c)/τ h < pd l (c), c cl X. This arises due to the homogenous good and equals a no-arbitrage condition. & 15 / 20

IV The cost cutoff is lower in the open economy: c l D < c D Similar outcome as in Melitz (2003), but through a different channel: [...] import competition increases competition in the domestic product market, shifting up residual demand price elasticities for all firms at any given demand level. This forces the least productive firms to exit. [...] the increased competition induces a downward shift in the distribution of markups across firms. Although only relatively more productive firms survive (with higher markups than the less productive firms who exit), the average markup is reduced. The distribution of prices shifts down due to the combined effect of selection and lower markups. [...] average firm size and profits increase - as does product variety. & 16 / 20

IV [...] In this model, welfare gains from trade thus come from a combination of productivity gains (via selection), lower markups (pro-competitive effect), and increased product variety. Hence, the model captures altogether: pro-competitive effect selection (& reallocation) effect variety effect = combined modelling of all these welfare channels in one framework! & 17 / 20

IV [...] In this model, welfare gains from trade thus come from a combination of productivity gains (via selection), lower markups (pro-competitive effect), and increased product variety. Hence, the model captures altogether: pro-competitive effect selection (& reallocation) effect variety effect = combined modelling of all these welfare channels in one framework! Market size still matters, as trade barriers preclude full integration of markets: If L H > L F, then ceteris paribus c H D < cf D. & 17 / 20

Bilateral (symmetric) liberalization decrease in symmetric trade costs τ H = τ F = τ increases competition in both markets: cd H, cf D =... = U & 18 / 20

Bilateral (symmetric) liberalization decrease in symmetric trade costs τ H = τ F = τ increases competition in both markets: cd H, cf D =... = U Unilateral liberalization (of country H) τ H or ρ H while ρ F = const. = c H D & cf D The liberalizing country suffers a welfare loss while its trading partner gains! In the short run, the pro-competitive effect drives down cd H, but in the long run the relocation of firms from H to F causes cd H & cf D & 18 / 20

Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6):1695 1725. Melitz, M. J. and Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2008). Market size, trade, and productivity. Review of Economic Studies, 75(1):295 316. Ottaviano, G. I. P., Taglioni, D., and Mauro, F. D. (2009). The euro and the competitiveness of european firms. Economic Policy, 24(57):553. & 19 / 20

Thank you for your attention! & 20 / 20