Empirical Macroeconomics

Similar documents
Empirical Macroeconomics

Empirical Macroeconomics

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

7. MULTIVARATE STATIONARY PROCESSES

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA)

13. Time Series Analysis: Asymptotics Weakly Dependent and Random Walk Process. Strict Exogeneity

5: MULTIVARATE STATIONARY PROCESSES

Introduction to Stochastic processes

9) Time series econometrics

Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series

TIME SERIES AND FORECASTING. Luca Gambetti UAB, Barcelona GSE Master in Macroeconomic Policy and Financial Markets

Macroeconomics Theory II

7 Introduction to Time Series

MA Advanced Econometrics: Applying Least Squares to Time Series

10) Time series econometrics

Some Time-Series Models

7 Introduction to Time Series Time Series vs. Cross-Sectional Data Detrending Time Series... 15

Econometrics I. Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics 25-1/25. Part 25: Time Series

Autoregressive and Moving-Average Models

Notes on Time Series Modeling

1 Introduction to Generalized Least Squares

1 Class Organization. 2 Introduction

ELEG 3143 Probability & Stochastic Process Ch. 6 Stochastic Process

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Covers Chapter 10-12, some of 16, some of 18 in Wooldridge. Regression Analysis with Time Series Data

Chapter 6. Random Processes

Class 1: Stationary Time Series Analysis

Introduction to ARMA and GARCH processes

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

Discrete time processes

Stationary and nonstationary variables

11/18/2008. So run regression in first differences to examine association. 18 November November November 2008

Univariate linear models

Lecture 3 Stationary Processes and the Ergodic LLN (Reference Section 2.2, Hayashi)

FINANCIAL ECONOMETRICS AND EMPIRICAL FINANCE -MODULE2 Midterm Exam Solutions - March 2015

Covariance Stationary Time Series. Example: Independent White Noise (IWN(0,σ 2 )) Y t = ε t, ε t iid N(0,σ 2 )

Econ 424 Time Series Concepts

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Generalized Least Squares

ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics

Empirical Macroeconomics

Autoregressive Moving Average (ARMA) Models and their Practical Applications

Lecture 3: Autoregressive Moving Average (ARMA) Models and their Practical Applications

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Trending Models in the Data

Single Equation Linear GMM with Serially Correlated Moment Conditions

Econometrics of Panel Data

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data

Review Session: Econometrics - CLEFIN (20192)

Macroeconomics Theory II

Introduction to Economic Time Series

Lecture#17. Time series III

Econ 423 Lecture Notes

Week 5 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Characterizing Cycles

Problem Set 2: Box-Jenkins methodology

Dynamic Regression Models (Lect 15)

E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity

Advanced Econometrics

1. Fundamental concepts

Chapter 2: Unit Roots

Università di Pavia. Forecasting. Eduardo Rossi

Introductory Workshop on Time Series Analysis. Sara McLaughlin Mitchell Department of Political Science University of Iowa

Module 9: Stationary Processes

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

LECTURES 2-3 : Stochastic Processes, Autocorrelation function. Stationarity.

Advanced Econometrics

Single Equation Linear GMM with Serially Correlated Moment Conditions

9. AUTOCORRELATION. [1] Definition of Autocorrelation (AUTO) 1) Model: y t = x t β + ε t. We say that AUTO exists if cov(ε t,ε s ) 0, t s.

Econometrics II Heij et al. Chapter 7.1

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Stochastic Processes

Ch. 15 Forecasting. 1.1 Forecasts Based on Conditional Expectations

Chapter 4: Models for Stationary Time Series

Structural VAR Models and Applications

VAR Models and Applications

ARDL Cointegration Tests for Beginner

GMM and SMM. 1. Hansen, L Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica, 50, p

F9 F10: Autocorrelation

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

APPLIED ECONOMETRIC TIME SERIES 4TH EDITION

Multivariate Time Series

Reliability and Risk Analysis. Time Series, Types of Trend Functions and Estimates of Trends

Ch. 14 Stationary ARMA Process

Chapter 3 - Temporal processes

1 Quantitative Techniques in Practice

Cointegration and Error-Correction

Vector autoregressions, VAR

Lecture 1: Stationary Time Series Analysis

Forecasting with ARMA

E 4160 Autumn term Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test

Statistical signal processing

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

Vector Auto-Regressive Models

Cointegration, Stationarity and Error Correction Models.

Ch.10 Autocorrelated Disturbances (June 15, 2016)

Transcription:

Empirical Macroeconomics Francesco Franco Nova SBE April 5, 2016 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 1/39

Growth and Fluctuations Supply and Demand Figure : US dynamics Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 2/39

Growth and Fluctuations Supply and Demand Figure : France dynamics Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 3/39

Growth and Fluctuations Supply and Demand Figure : France dynamics Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 4/39

Framework Time Series Hamilton, 1994, Time Series Analysis (di cult) Enders, Applied Econometric Time Series, 4th Edition (easier) Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 5/39

ARMA Processes Expectations, stationarity and ergodicity Suppose we observe a sample of size T of some random variables, say i.i.d t { 1, 2,..., T }, with t N(0, 2 ) which is only one possible outcome of the underlying stochastic process. Same for { } Πt= Π: one single realization. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 6/39

ARMA Processes Expectations, stationarity and ergodicity Now consider I realizations ) * y 1 Œ t t= Œ, ) yt 2 * Ó Ô Œ Œ t= Œ,..., yt I and select one observation t= Œ associated with the I realizations: Ó Ô yt 1, yt 2,...,yt I This is a sample of I realizations of the random variable Y t.this random variable has some density, f Yt (y t ) which is called unconditional density, for example for the Gaussian white noise. 1 2 f Yt (y t )= Ô 1 y 2 t 2 e 2 2fi Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 7/39

ARMA Processes Expectations The expectation ot the tth observation of a time series refers to the mean of this probability distribution E (Y t )= Œ Œ y t f Yt (y t )dy t which you might see as the probability limit of the ensemble average Iÿ E (Y t )=plim IæŒ (1/I) i=1 Y (i) t which is sometimes called the unconditional mean of Y t : E(Y t )=µ t (examples: Y t = + t, Y t = t + t ). Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 8/39

ARMA Processes Expectations The variance same examples. 0,t = E (Y t µ t ) 2 = Œ Œ (y t µ t ) 2 f Yt (y t )dy t Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 9/39

ARMA Processes Autocovariance Given a particular realization such as ) yt 1 * Œ t= Œ on a time series process consider xt 1 consisting of the [j + 1] most recent observations on y as of date tfor that realization: S T x 1 t = W U yt 1 yt 1 1... y 1 t j and think of each realization of y t as generating one particular value of the vector x t.thejthautocovariance of Y t is X V jt = E (Y t µ t )(Y t j µ t j )= Œ Œ Œ Œ... Œ Œ (y t µ t )(y t j µ t j ) f Yt,Y t 1,...,Y t j (y t, y t 1,...,y t j )dy t dy t 1...dy t j Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 10/39

ARMA Processes Autocovariance Notice it has the form of a covariance on lagged values. The Variance is the zero lag autocovariance. Again again examples. jt = plim IæŒ (1/I) Iÿ i=1 Ë Y (i) t ÈË µ t Y (i) È t j µ t j Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 11/39

ARMA Processes Stationarity If neither the mean µ t nor the autocovariances jt depend on the date t then the process for Y t is said to be covariance-stationary or weakly stationary. Consider the two examples. It follows that for a covariance statonary process j = j Strict sationarity is related to the joint distribution of Y t, Y t+j,... depending only on the intervals and not on t (higher moments) Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 12/39

ARMA Processes Ergodicity Consider the sample mean which in this case in not an ensemble average but rather a time average ȳ =(1/T ) whether time averages eventually converge to ensemble averages has to do with ergodicity. A Gaussian covariance-stationary process is ergodic for the mean if the autocovariances j goes to zero su ciently quickly for as j becomes large: q Œ j=0 j < Œ. Tÿ t=1 y 1 t Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 13/39

ARMA Processes Ergodicity Usually stationarity and ergodicity coincide but not always Y i t = µ i + t with µ generated from a N(0, 2 ) distribution. Which is covariance-stationary but not ergodic. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 14/39

ARMA Processes MA consider a MA(1) Y t = µ + t + t 1 Mean and Variance, autocovariances -> covariance-stationary and ergodicity condition is satisfied. E (Y t )=µ E (Y t µ) 2 = 1 1 + 22 2 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 15/39

ARMA Processes MA Autocovariance E (Y t µ)(y t 1 µ) = 2 Ergodicity Œÿ j = j=0 1 1 + 22 2 + - - 2- - - Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 16/39

ARMA Processes MA The autocorrelation of a covariance-stationary process (denoted fl j )isdefinedas fl j = j 0 first order autocorrelation 1 + 2 higher order autocorrelation are zero. max,min,same if is replaced by 1/ Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 17/39

ARMA Processes MA(Œ) Y t = µ + Œÿ  j t j j=0 condition for covariance-stationary is Œÿ Âj 2 < Œ j=0 with q Œ j=0  j < Œ we also have ergodicity. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 18/39

ARMA Processes AR(1) Consider Y t = c + fly t 1 + t Œÿ Y t = fl j (c + t j ) j=0 if fl Ø1 there is no covariance stationary process, if fl < 1there is a covariance stationary process that can be viewed as an MA(Œ). Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 19/39

ARMA Processes AR(1) The unconditional mean is µ = c 1 fl and the variance is while the autocovariance j = 2 1 fl 2 Ë È fl j /(1 fl 2 ) 2 you arrive at these formulas using the MA(Œ) or assumeing the AR(1) is covariance stationary. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 20/39

Wold s Decomposition Advantage of covariance-stationarity All of the covariance-stationary time-series can be written in the form Y t = Ÿ t + Œÿ  j t j j=0 with q Œ j=0  2 j < Œ and  0 = 1. The term t is white noise and represents the innovations t Y t Ê (Y t Y t 1, Y t 2,...) and Ÿ t is uncorrelated with t j for all j. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 21/39

Invertible Moving Average MA and AR Take a MA (for simplicity MA(1)) y t = t + t 1 y t =(1 + L) t provided < 1, you can multiply both sides by (1 + L) 1 and get (1 + L) 1 y t = t which is AR with infinite lags. 1 2 1 L + 2 L 2 3 L 3 +... y t = t Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 22/39

Likelihood Estimation Take a AR(1) Y t = c + fly t 1 + t the first observation Y 1 has a normal distribution (like ) with mean µ = c 1 fl and variance 2. The second observation Y 1 fl 2 2 conditional on Y 1 is a normal with mean c + fly t 1 and variance 2 and so for up to T the sample size, the likelihood is therefore f. YT,Y T 1,...,Y 1 (y T, y T 1,...,y 1 ; ) =f Y1 (y 1; ) and the log-likelihood TŸ t=2 f Yt y t 1 (y t y t 1 ; ) L( ) =log f Y1 (y 1; )+ Tÿ log f Yt Y t 1 (y t y t 1 ; ) t=2 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 23/39

Explaining the dynamics Shocks There are two types of disturbances a ecting unemployment and output: 1 The first has no long-run e ect on either unemployment or output 2 The second has no long-run e ect on unemployment, but may have a long-run e ect on output 3 Finally, these two disturbances are uncorrelated at all leads and lags Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 24/39

The Model MA(Œ) Let Y and U denote the logarithm of GNP and the level of the unemployment rate, e d and e S be the two disturbances. X =( Y, U), andlet =(e d, e s ). The vector moving average (VMA) representation of the postulated process: X t = A(0)Á t + A(1)Á t 1 +... Œÿ = A(j) t j j=0 with q Œ j=1 a 11 (j) =0andVar( ) =I Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 25/39

Wold representation Fundamental Since X is stationary, it has a Wold-moving average representation with Var(v) = X t = v t + Cv t 1 +.. + C k 1 v t k+1 +... Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 26/39

From Wold to Model Identification v = A(0) =A(0)A(0) Õ three restrictions Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 27/39

Identification In levels, we have: Y t = v 1t +(I 1 + C 1 )v 1t 1 +.. +(I 1 + C 1 +.. + C k 1 )v t k +... LR =(I + C + C 2 +...)A(0) =(I C) 1 A(0) LR has the following interpretation: C LR11 :LRe LR = d on Y LR 21 :LR e d on U LR 12 :LR e d on Y LR 22 :LR u s on U D Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 28/39

IRF X t+s = i = s 1 ÿ i=0 C i A(0) t+s i Ë È (C) i A(0) you want to study ˆX t+s ˆ t = s Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 29/39

Variance Decomposition FEV D = E t0 5 1 X t0 +s X t0 +s 21 X t0 +s X 2 6 Õ t0 +s = s 1 ÿ t=0 C t C Õ t =AA Õ = n vars ÿ j=1 a j a Õ j Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 30/39

Estimation by VAR Invertibility Take a MA (for simplicity MA(1)) y t = v t + c 1 v t 1 y t =(1 + c 1 L) v t provided c 1 < 1, you can multiply both sides by (1 + c 1 L) 1 and get (1 + c 1 L) 1 y t = v t which is VAR with infinite lags. This generalize to matrices. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 31/39

Estimation by VAR Fundamentalness You can only recover shocks with c 1 < 1. Consider the MA y t = u t + 1 c 1 u t 1 1 2 2 with v 2 = 1 c1 2 u, then the two MA (invertible and not invertible have the same moments). The problem is that if your model is an MA non invertible, by estimating the VAR you are going to recover the shocks of the invertible MA, you get v and not u. Theu are not fundamental. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 32/39

Unit root Non stationarity In the OLS estimation of an AR(1) y t = fly t 1 + t with t iid N! 0, 2" and y 0 = 0 the OLS estimate of fl is given by ˆfl = q nt=1 y t 1 y t q nt=1 y 2 t 1 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 33/39

Unit root Non stationarity If fl < 1, then Ô n (ˆfln fl) æ N 10, 1 fl 22 But if this result was valid when fl = 1 then the distribution would have variance zero. (Theory in Hamilton chap 17). We need to find a suitable non degenrate distribution to test hypotesis H 0 : fl = 1 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 34/39

Unit root Augmented Dickey-Fuller we fit y t = + y t 1 + t + kÿ j y t j + e t j=1 via OLS. the test statistic for H 0 : = 0isZ t = ˆ /ˆ.Critical values. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 35/39

Unit root Augmented Dickey-Fuller Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 36/39

Autocorrelation Test Definition Á t is not iid since it is correlated with some Á t s. Does not change the consistency result but now the OLS estimator is ine cient and you should use GLS. You can use a test of autocorrelation H 0 : no autocorrelation H 1 : autocorrelation 1 Estimate fl = corr(ˆá t, ˆÁ t 1 ) and use a t-test on fl 2 Durbin-Watson: DW 2 2fl. Reject H 0 if DW Æ 1.5. Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 37/39

Heteroskedasticity Phillips Perron PP correct both autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity but fits: y t = + fly t 1 + t + t Phillips-Perron test for unit root Number of obs = 259 Newey-West lags = 1 Interpolated Dickey-Fuller Test 1% Critical 5% Critical 10% Critical Statistic Value Value Value Z(rho) -0.703-20.307-14.000-11.200 Z(t) -2.300-3.459-2.880-2.570 MacKinnon approximate p-value for Z(t) = 0.1720 lrgnp Coef. Std. Err. t P> t [95% Conf. Interval] lrgnp L1..9973338.0010155 982.14 0.000.9953341.9993335 _cons.030857.0087953 3.51 0.001.013537.0481769 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 38/39

Stationary Check code for tests on unemployment Augmented Dickey-Fuller test for unit root Number of obs = 257 Interpolated Dickey-Fuller Test 1% Critical 5% Critical 10% Critical Statistic Value Value Value Z(t) -3.669-3.459-2.880-2.570 MacKinnon approximate p-value for Z(t) = 0.0046 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 39/39