Hybrid Atlas Model. of financial equity market. Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3

Similar documents
Stable Diffusions Interacting through Their Ranks, as Models of Large Equity Markets

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

LOCAL TIMES OF RANKED CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES

A Second-Order Model of the Stock Market

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University

Convex polytopes, interacting particles, spin glasses, and finance

TRANSPORT INEQUALITIES FOR STOCHASTIC

Walsh Diffusions. Andrey Sarantsev. March 27, University of California, Santa Barbara. Andrey Sarantsev University of Washington, Seattle 1 / 1

Competing Brownian Particles

EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS. Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF. Talk at the University of Michigan

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

Geometry of functionally generated portfolios

On a class of stochastic differential equations in a financial network model

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage

Stochastic Portfolio Theory: An Overview

Exact Simulation of Multivariate Itô Diffusions

VOLATILITY AND ARBITRAGE

RESEARCH STATEMENT ANDREY SARANTSEV

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance

Optimal Arbitrage under Constraints

DIVERSITY AND RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN EQUITY MARKETS

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( )

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

ON THE FIRST TIME THAT AN ITO PROCESS HITS A BARRIER

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

P i [B k ] = lim. n=1 p(n) ii <. n=1. V i :=

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

Large deviations and averaging for systems of slow fast stochastic reaction diffusion equations.

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula

Strong Markov property of determinantal processes associated with extended kernels

Asymptotic Coupling of an SPDE, with Applications to Many-Server Queues

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

On the dual problem of utility maximization

Strong Markov property of determinatal processes

Optional decomposition for continuous semimartingales under arbitrary filtrations *

On countably skewed Brownian motion

Research Article Existence and Uniqueness Theorem for Stochastic Differential Equations with Self-Exciting Switching

Reversible Coalescing-Fragmentating Wasserstein Dynamics on the Real Line

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula

Branching Brownian motion seen from the tip

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times.

BERNOULLI ACTIONS AND INFINITE ENTROPY

Small-time asymptotics of stopped Lévy bridges and simulation schemes with controlled bias

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus

Supplement A: Construction and properties of a reected diusion

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Bridging the Gap between Center and Tail for Multiscale Processes

ON THE DIFFUSION OPERATOR IN POPULATION GENETICS

Gradient Estimation for Attractor Networks

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Bessel-like SPDEs. Lorenzo Zambotti, Sorbonne Université (joint work with Henri Elad-Altman) 15th May 2018, Luminy

Random Process Lecture 1. Fundamentals of Probability

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations

Introduction to Random Diffusions

n! (k 1)!(n k)! = F (X) U(0, 1). (x, y) = n(n 1) ( F (y) F (x) ) n 2

Practical conditions on Markov chains for weak convergence of tail empirical processes

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 26 Sep 2018

Optimal transportation and optimal control in a finite horizon framework

On the submartingale / supermartingale property of diffusions in natural scale

Unspanned Stochastic Volatility in the Multi-Factor CIR Model

Stochastic Differential Equations.

Maximum pressure policies for stochastic processing networks

Poisson random measure: motivation

p 1 ( Y p dp) 1/p ( X p dp) 1 1 p

FE 5204 Stochastic Differential Equations

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility

Two Brownian Particles with Rank-Based Characteristics and Skew-Elastic Collisions

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Modelling of Dependent Credit Rating Transitions

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

Introduction to self-similar growth-fragmentations

Convex Geometry. Carsten Schütt

Trading strategies generated by Lyapunov functions

Reflected Brownian Motion

Consistency of the maximum likelihood estimator for general hidden Markov models

A variational formula for risk-sensitive control

Path Decomposition of Markov Processes. Götz Kersting. University of Frankfurt/Main

A relative entropy characterization of the growth rate of reward in risk-sensitive control

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

Dirichlet uniformly well-approximated numbers

Spectral properties of Markov operators in Markov chain Monte Carlo

Heavy Tailed Time Series with Extremal Independence

Lecture 2. We now introduce some fundamental tools in martingale theory, which are useful in controlling the fluctuation of martingales.

SMSTC (2007/08) Probability.

Numerical Methods with Lévy Processes

Ruin probabilities in multivariate risk models with periodic common shock

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Transcription:

Hybrid Atlas Model of financial equity market Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3 1 University of California, Santa Barbara 2 Columbia University, New York 3 INTECH, Princeton November 2009

2 Outline Introduction Hybrid Atlas model Martingale Problem Stability Effective dimension Rankings Long-term growth relations Portfolio analysis Stochastic Portfolio Theory Target portfolio Universal portfolio Conclusion

3 Flow of Capital Figure: Capital Distribution Curves (Percentage) for the S&P 500 Index of 1997 (Solid Line) and 1999 (Broken Line).

Log-Log Capital Distribution Curves Figure: Capital distribution curves for 1929 (shortest curve) - 1999 (longest curve), every ten years. Source Fernholz( 02). What kind of models can describe this long-term stability?

A Model of Rankings [Hybrid Atlas model] Capital process X := {(X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), 0 t < }. Order Statistics: X (1) (t) X (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Log capital Y := log X : Y (1) (t) Y (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Dynamics of log capital: d Y (k) (t) = (γ + γ i + g k ) d t + σ k d W i (t) if Y (k) (t) = Y i (t) ; for 1 i, k n, 0 t <, where W ( ) is n dim. B. M. company name i kth ranked company Drift ( mean ) γ i g k Diffusion ( variance ) σ k > 0 Banner, Fernholz & Karatzas ( 05), Chatterjee & Pal ( 07, 09), Pal & Pitman ( 08). 5

A Model of Rankings [Hybrid Atlas model] Capital process X := {(X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), 0 t < }. Order Statistics: X (1) (t) X (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Log capital Y := log X : Y (1) (t) Y (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Dynamics of log capital: d Y (k) (t) = (γ + γ i + g k ) d t + σ k d W i (t) if Y (k) (t) = Y i (t) ; for 1 i, k n, 0 t <, where W ( ) is n dim. B. M. company name i kth ranked company Drift ( mean ) γ i g k Diffusion ( variance ) σ k > 0 Banner, Fernholz & Karatzas ( 05), Chatterjee & Pal ( 07, 09), Pal & Pitman ( 08). 5

A Model of Rankings [Hybrid Atlas model] Capital process X := {(X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), 0 t < }. Order Statistics: X (1) (t) X (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Log capital Y := log X : Y (1) (t) Y (n) (t) ; 0 t <. Dynamics of log capital: d Y (k) (t) = (γ + γ i + g k ) d t + σ k d W i (t) if Y (k) (t) = Y i (t) ; for 1 i, k n, 0 t <, where W ( ) is n dim. B. M. company name i kth ranked company Drift ( mean ) γ i g k Diffusion ( variance ) σ k > 0 Banner, Fernholz & Karatzas ( 05), Chatterjee & Pal ( 07, 09), Pal & Pitman ( 08). 5

6 Illustration (n = 3) of interactions through rank Time X 3 (t)>x 1 (t)>x 2 (t) X 1 (t)>x 3 (t)>x 2 (t) x 1 > x 3 > x 2 x 3 > x 1 > x 2 x 1 > x 2 > x 3 X 1 (t)>x 2 (t)>x 3 (t) x 3 > x 2 > x 1 x 2 > x 1 > x 3 X 3 X 2 X 1 x 2 > x 3 > x 1 Paths in R + Time. A path in different wedges of R n. Symmetric group Σ n of permutations of {1,..., n}. For n = 3, {(1, 2, 3), (1, 3, 2), (2, 1, 3), (2, 3, 1), (3, 1, 2), (3, 2, 1)}.

6 Illustration (n = 3) of interactions through rank Time X 3 (t)>x 1 (t)>x 2 (t) X 1 (t)>x 3 (t)>x 2 (t) x 1 > x 3 > x 2 x 3 > x 1 > x 2 x 1 > x 2 > x 3 X 1 (t)>x 2 (t)>x 3 (t) x 3 > x 2 > x 1 x 2 > x 1 > x 3 X 3 X 2 X 1 x 2 > x 3 > x 1 Paths in R + Time. A path in different wedges of R n. Symmetric group Σ n of permutations of {1,..., n}. For n = 3, {(1, 2, 3), (1, 3, 2), (2, 1, 3), (2, 3, 1), (3, 1, 2), (3, 2, 1)}.

Vector Representation d Y (t) = G(Y (t))d t + S(Y (t))dw (t) ; 0 t < Σ n : symmetric group of permutations of {1, 2,..., n}. For p Σ n define wedges (chambers) R p := {x R n : x p(1) x p(2) x p(n) }, R n = p Σn R p, (the inner points of R p and R p are disjoint for p p Σ n ), Q (i) k : = {x R n : x i is ranked kth among (x 1,..., x n )} = {p : p(k)=i} R p ; 1 i, k n, n j=1 Q(j) k = R n = n l=1 Q(i) l and R p = n k=1 Q(p(k)) k. G(y) = p Σ n (g p 1 (1) + γ 1 + γ,..., g p 1 (n) + γ n + γ) 1 Rp (y), S(y) = p Σ n diag(σ p 1 (1),..., σ p 1 (n) ) }{{} s p 1 Rp (y) ; y Rn. 7

Vector Representation d Y (t) = G(Y (t))d t + S(Y (t))dw (t) ; 0 t < Σ n : symmetric group of permutations of {1, 2,..., n}. For p Σ n define wedges (chambers) R p := {x R n : x p(1) x p(2) x p(n) }, R n = p Σn R p, (the inner points of R p and R p are disjoint for p p Σ n ), Q (i) k : = {x R n : x i is ranked kth among (x 1,..., x n )} = {p : p(k)=i} R p ; 1 i, k n, n j=1 Q(j) k = R n = n l=1 Q(i) l and R p = n k=1 Q(p(k)) k. G(y) = p Σ n (g p 1 (1) + γ 1 + γ,..., g p 1 (n) + γ n + γ) 1 Rp (y), S(y) = p Σ n diag(σ p 1 (1),..., σ p 1 (n) ) }{{} s p 1 Rp (y) ; y Rn. 7

8 Martingale Problem Theorem [Krylov( 71), Stroock & Varadhan( 79), Bass & Pardoux( 87)] Suppose that the coefficients G( ) and a( ) := SS ( ) are bounded and measurable, and that a( ) is uniformly positive-definite and piecewise constant in each wedge. For each y 0 R n there is a unique one probability measure P on C([0, ), R n ) such that P(Y 0 = y 0 ) = 1 and t f (Y t ) f (Y 0 ) L f (Y s ) d s ; 0 0 t < is a P local martingale for every f C 2 (R 2 ) where L f (x) = 1 n 2 i,j=1 a ij(x)d ij f (x) + n i=1 G i(x)d i f (x) ; x R n. This implies that the hybrid Atlas model is well-defined.

9 Model Market capitalization X follows Hybrid Atlas model: the log capitalization Y i = log X i of company i has drift γ + g k + γ i and volatility σ k, when company i is k th ranked, i.e., Y Q (i) k for 1 k, i n. d Y i (t) = ( γ + + n k=1 n k=1 g k 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) + γ i )d t k σ k 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d W i (t) ; 0 t <. k

10 Model assumptions Market capitalization X follows Hybrid Atlas model: the log capitalization Y i = log X i of company i has drift γ + g k + γ i and volatility σ k, when company i is k th ranked, i.e., Y Q (i) k for 1 k, i n. Assume σ k > 0, (g k, 1 k n), (γ i, 1 i n) and γ are real constants with stability conditions n n g k + γ i = 0, k=1 i=1 k (g l +γ p(l) ) < 0, k = 1,..., n 1, p Σ n. l=1 γ i = 0, 1 i n, g 1 = = g n 1 = g < 0, g n = (n 1)g > 0. γ i = 1 (2i)/(n + 1), 1 i n, g k = 1, k = 1,..., n 1, g n = n 1.

10 Model assumptions Market capitalization X follows Hybrid Atlas model: the log capitalization Y i = log X i of company i has drift γ + g k + γ i and volatility σ k, when company i is k th ranked, i.e., Y Q (i) k for 1 k, i n. Assume σ k > 0, (g k, 1 k n), (γ i, 1 i n) and γ are real constants with stability conditions n n g k + γ i = 0, k=1 i=1 k (g l +γ p(l) ) < 0, k = 1,..., n 1, p Σ n. l=1 γ i = 0, 1 i n, g 1 = = g n 1 = g < 0, g n = (n 1)g > 0. γ i = 1 (2i)/(n + 1), 1 i n, g k = 1, k = 1,..., n 1, g n = n 1.

10 Model assumptions Market capitalization X follows Hybrid Atlas model: the log capitalization Y i = log X i of company i has drift γ + g k + γ i and volatility σ k, when company i is k th ranked, i.e., Y Q (i) k for 1 k, i n. Assume σ k > 0, (g k, 1 k n), (γ i, 1 i n) and γ are real constants with stability conditions n n g k + γ i = 0, k=1 i=1 k (g l +γ p(l) ) < 0, k = 1,..., n 1, p Σ n. l=1 γ i = 0, 1 i n, g 1 = = g n 1 = g < 0, g n = (n 1)g > 0. γ i = 1 (2i)/(n + 1), 1 i n, g k = 1, k = 1,..., n 1, g n = n 1.

Model Summary The log-capitalization Y = log X follows d Y i (t) = ( γ + + n k=1 n k=1 g k 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) + γ i )d t k σ k 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d W i (t) ; 0 t < k where σ k > 0, (g k, 1 k n), (γ i, 1 i n) and γ are real constants with stability conditions n n g k + γ i = 0, k=1 i=1 k (g l +γ p(l) ) < 0, k = 1,..., n 1, p Σ n. l=1

Stochastic stability The average Y ( ) := n i=1 Y i( ) / n of log-capitalization: dy (t) = γ d t + 1 n n n k=1 σ k 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d W i (t) k i=1 }{{} d B k (t) is a Brownian motion with variance rate n k=1 σ2 k /n2 drift γ by the Dambis-Dubins-Schwartz Theorem. Proposition Under the assumptions the deviations Ỹ ( ) := (Y 1 ( ) Y ( ),..., Y n ( ) Y ( )) from the average are stable in distribution, i.e., there is a unique invariant probability measure µ( ) such that for every bounded, measurable function f we have the Strong Law of Large Numbers 1 T lim f (Ỹ T T (t)) d t = f (y)µ(d y), 0 Π where Π := {y R n : y 1 + + y n = 0}. a.s.

Stochastic stability The average Y ( ) := n i=1 Y i( ) / n of log-capitalization: dy (t) = γ d t + 1 n n n k=1 σ k 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d W i (t) k i=1 }{{} d B k (t) is a Brownian motion with variance rate n k=1 σ2 k /n2 drift γ by the Dambis-Dubins-Schwartz Theorem. Proposition Under the assumptions the deviations Ỹ ( ) := (Y 1 ( ) Y ( ),..., Y n ( ) Y ( )) from the average are stable in distribution, i.e., there is a unique invariant probability measure µ( ) such that for every bounded, measurable function f we have the Strong Law of Large Numbers 1 T lim f (Ỹ T T (t)) d t = f (y)µ(d y), 0 Π where Π := {y R n : y 1 + + y n = 0}. a.s.

13 Average occupation times Especially taking f ( ) = 1 Rp ( ) or 1 (i) Q ( ), we define from µ k the average occupation time of X in R p or Q (i) k : 1 T θ p := µ(r p ) = lim 1 Rp (X(t))d t T T θ k,i := µ(q (i) k ) = lim T 1 T 0 T 0 1 (i) Q (X(t))d t, 1 k, i n, k since 1 Rp (Ỹ ( )) = 1 R p (X( )) and 1 (i) Q (X( )) = 1 (i) k Q (Ỹ ( )). By k definition 0 θ k,i = {p Σ n:p(k)=i} θ p 1 for 1 k, i n, n l=1 θ l,i = n j=1 θ k,j = 1 for 1 k, i n. What is the invariant distribution µ?

Attainability One-dimensional Brownian motion attains the origin infinitely often. Two-dimensional Brownian motion does not attain the origin. Does the process X( ) attain the origin? t t X(t) = X(0) + b(x(s)) d s + σ(x(s))d W (s) 0 0 where b and σ are bounded measurable functions. Friedman( 74), Bass & Pardoux( 87).

15 Effective Dimension Let us define effective dimension ED( ) by ED(x) = trace(a(x)) x 2 x A(x)x where A( ) = σ( )σ( ). ; x R n \ {0}, Proposition Suppose X(0) 0. If inf x R n \{0} ED(x) 2, then X( ) does not attain the origin. If sup x R n \{0} ED(x) < 2 and if there is no drift, i.e., b( ) 0, then X( ) attains the origin. Exterior Dirichlet Problem by Meyers and Serrin( 60). Removal of drift by Girsanov s theorem. If there is drift, take [trace(a(x))+x b(x)] x 2 x A(x)x.

16 Triple collision Now consider triple collision: { Xi (t) = X j (t) = X k (t) for some t > 0, 1 i < j < k n }. What is the probability of triple collision? Fix i = 1, j = 2, k = 3. Let us define the sum of squared distances: s 2 (x) := (x 1 x 2 ) 2 +(x 2 x 3 ) 2 +(x 3 x 1 ) 2 = x DD x ; x R n, where (n 3) matrix D is defined by D := (d 1, d 2, d 3 ) with d 1 := (1, 1, 0,..., 0), d 2 := (0, 1, 1, 0,..., 0), d 3 := ( 1, 0, 1,..., 0). Z := {x R n : s(x) = 0 }.

Define the local effective dimension: R(x) := trace(d A(x)D) x DD x x DD A(x)DD x ; x R n \ Z. Proposition Suppose s(x(0)) 0. If inf x R n \Z R(x) 2, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 0. If sup x R n \Z R(x) < 2 and if there is no drift, i.e., b( ) 0, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 1. R( ) 2 for n dim. BM, i.e., A( ) I. If there is drift, take [trace(d A(x)D)+x DD b(x)] x DD x x DD A(x)DD x. Idea of Proof: a comparison with Bessel process with dimension two. 17

Define the local effective dimension: R(x) := trace(d A(x)D) x DD x x DD A(x)DD x ; x R n \ Z. Proposition Suppose s(x(0)) 0. If inf x R n \Z R(x) 2, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 0. If sup x R n \Z R(x) < 2 and if there is no drift, i.e., b( ) 0, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 1. R( ) 2 for n dim. BM, i.e., A( ) I. If there is drift, take [trace(d A(x)D)+x DD b(x)] x DD x x DD A(x)DD x. Idea of Proof: a comparison with Bessel process with dimension two. 17

Define the local effective dimension: R(x) := trace(d A(x)D) x DD x x DD A(x)DD x ; x R n \ Z. Proposition Suppose s(x(0)) 0. If inf x R n \Z R(x) 2, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 0. If sup x R n \Z R(x) < 2 and if there is no drift, i.e., b( ) 0, then P(X 1 (t) = X 2 (t) = X 3 (t) for some t 0) = 1. R( ) 2 for n dim. BM, i.e., A( ) I. If there is drift, take [trace(d A(x)D)+x DD b(x)] x DD x x DD A(x)DD x. Idea of Proof: a comparison with Bessel process with dimension two. 17

18 Rankings Recall Y (1) ( ) Y (2) ( ) Y (n) ( ). Let us denote by Λ k,j (t) the local time accumulated at the origin by the nonnegative semimartingale Y (k) ( ) Y (j) ( ) up to time t for 1 k < j n. Theorem[Banner & Ghomrasni ( 07)] For a general class of semimartingale Y ( ), the rankings satisfy d Y (k) (t) = n i=1 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d Y i (t) k + (N k (t)) 1[ n l=k+1 k 1 ] d Λ k,l (t) d Λ l,k (t) l=1 where N k (t) is the cardinality {i : Y i (t) = Y (k) (t)}.

19 Rankings Recall Y (1) ( ) Y (2) ( ) Y (n) ( ). Let us denote by Λ k,j (t) the local time accumulated at the origin by the nonnegative semimartingale Y (k) ( ) Y (j) ( ) up to time t for 1 k < j n. Lemma Under the non-degeneracy condition σ k > 0 for k = 1,..., n, dy (k) (t) = ( γ + g k + + 1 2 n i=1 for k = 1,..., n, 0 t T. ) γ i 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) d t + σ k d B k (t) k ] [ d Λ k,k+1 (t) d Λ k 1,k (t) Idea of Proof: a comparison with a Bessel process with dimension one to show Λ k,l ( ) 0, k l 2..

19 Rankings Recall Y (1) ( ) Y (2) ( ) Y (n) ( ). Let us denote by Λ k,j (t) the local time accumulated at the origin by the nonnegative semimartingale Y (k) ( ) Y (j) ( ) up to time t for 1 k < j n. Lemma Under the non-degeneracy condition σ k > 0 for k = 1,..., n, dy (k) (t) = ( γ + g k + + 1 2 n i=1 for k = 1,..., n, 0 t T. ) γ i 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) d t + σ k d B k (t) k ] [ d Λ k,k+1 (t) d Λ k 1,k (t) Idea of Proof: a comparison with a Bessel process with dimension one to show Λ k,l ( ) 0, k l 2..

20 Long-term growth relations Proposition Under the assumptions we obtain the following long-term growth relations: Y i (T ) log X i (T ) lim = lim = γ T T T T Thus the model is coherent: = lim T log n i=1 X i(t ) T 1 lim T T log µ i(t ) = 0 a.s.; i = 1,..., n a.s. where µ i ( ) = X i ( )/(X 1 ( ) + + X n ( )). Moreover, n g k θ k,i + γ i = 0 ; i = 1,..., n. k=1

n g k θ k,i + γ i = 0 ; i = 1,..., n. k=1 The log-capitalization Y grows with rate γ and follows d Y i (t) = ( γ + + n k=1 n k=1 g k 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) + γ i )d t k σ k 1 (i) Q (Y (t))d W i (t) ; 0 t < k for i = 1,..., n. The ranking (Y (1) ( ),..., Y (n) ( )) follows dy (k) (t) = ( γ + g k + + 1 2 n i=1 for k = 1,..., n, 0 t <. ) γ i 1 (i) Q (Y (t)) d t + σ k d B k (t) k ] [ d Λ k,k+1 (t) d Λ k 1,k (t).

Semimartingale reflected Brownian motions The adjacent differences (gaps) Ξ( ) := (Ξ 1 ( ),..., Ξ n ( )) where Ξ k ( ) := Y (k) ( ) Y (k+1) ( ) for k = 1,..., n 1 can be seen as a semimartingale reflected Brownian motion (SRBM): Ξ(t) = Ξ(0) + ζ(t) + (I n Q)Λ(t) where ζ( ) := (ζ 1 ( ),..., ζ n ( )), Λ( ) := (Λ 1,2 ( ),..., Λ n 1,n ( )), ζ k ( ) := n i=1 0 1 (i) Q (Y (s)) d Y (s) k n i=1 0 1 (i) Q (Y (s)) d Y (s) k+1 for k = 1,..., n 1, and Q is an (n 1) (n 1) matrix with elements

23 Q := 0 1/2 1/2 0 1/2 1/2......... 0 1/2 1/2 0 Thus the gaps Ξ k := Y (k) ( ) Y (k+1) ( ) follow. Ξ(t) = Ξ(0) + ζ(t) }{{} + (I n Q)Λ(t) }{{} semimartingale reflection part In order to study the invariant measure µ, we apply the theory of semimartingale reflected Brownian motions developed by M. Harrison, M. Reiman, R. Williams and others. In addition to the model assumptions, we assume linearly growing variances: σ 2 2 σ2 1 = σ2 3 σ2 2 = = σ2 n σ 2 n 1.

Invariant distribution of gaps and index Let us define the indicator map R n x p x Σ n such that x p x (1) x p x (2) x p(n), and the index process P t := p Y (t). Proposition Under the stability and the linearly growing variance conditions the invariant distribution ν( ) of (Ξ( ), P ) is ( ν(a B) = n 1 q Σ n k=1 ) 1 λ 1 q,k exp( λ p, z )d z p Σ A n for every measurable set A B where λ p := (λ p,1,..., λ p,n 1 ) is the vector of components λ p,k := 4( k l=1 g l + γ p(l) ) σk 2 + > 0 ; p Σ n, 1 k n 1. σ2 k+1 Proof: an extension from M. Harrison and R. Williams ( 87).

25 Average occupation time Corollary The average occupation times are ( θ p = n 1 q Σ n k=1 λ 1 q,k ) 1 n 1 j=1 λ 1 p,j and θ k,i = {p Σ n:p(k)=i} θ p for p Σ n and 1 k, i n. (1,10) (10,10) 0.15 If all γi = 0 and σ 2 1 = σ2 n, then θ k,i = n 1 for 1 k, i n. Heat map of θk,i when n = 10, σ 2 k = 1 + k, g k = 1 for k = 1,..., 9, g 10 = 9, and γ i = 1 (2i)/(n + 1) for i = 1,..., n. 0.05 0.1 (k,i) (1,1) 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 (10,1)

26 Market weights come from Pareto type Corollary The joint invariant distribution of market shares µ (i) ( ) := X (i) ( )/(X 1 ( ) + + X n ( )) ; i = 1,..., n has the density (m 1,..., m n 1 ) = λ p,1 λ p,n 1 θ p p Π n m λ p,1+1 1 m λ p,2 λ p,1 +1 2 m λ p,n 1 λ p,n 2 +1 n 1 0 < m n m n 1... m 1 < 1, m n = 1 m 1 m n 1. This is a distribution of ratios of Pareto type disribution. m λ p,n 1+1 n,

Expected capital distribution curves From the expected slopes E ν [ log µ (k) log µ (k 1) log(k+1) log k ] = Eν (Ξ k ) log(1+k 1 ) obtain expected capital distribution curves. e 1 e 1 we iv e 5 e 5 v Weight iii Weight e 10 i ii e 10 Rank 1 5 10 50 100 5001000 5000 Rank 1 5 10 50 100 5001000 5000 n = 5000, gn = c (2n 1), g k = 0, 1 k n 1, γ 1 = c, γ i = 2c, 2 i n, σ 2 k = 0.075 + 6k 10 5, 1 k n. (i) c = 0.02, (ii) c = 0.03, (iii) c = 0.04. (iv) c = 0.02, g 1 = 0.016, g k = 0, 2 k n 1, g n = (0.02)(2n 1) + 0.016, (v) g1 = = g 50 = 0.016, g k = 0, 51 k n 1, g n = (0.02)(2n 1) + 0.8.

28 Empirical data Variance Rate 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 Historical capital distribution curves. Data 1929-1999. Source: Fernholz ( 02) 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 Rank Growing variances. 1990-1999.

29 Capital Stocks and Portfolio Rules Market X = ((X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), t 0) of n companies log X i(t ) T T n X i (0) = G i (t)dt + S i,ν (t)dw ν (t), 0 0 ν=1 with initial capital X i (0) = x i > 0, i = 1,..., n, 0 T <. Define a ij ( ) = n ν=1 S iν( )S jν ( ) and A ij ( ) = 0 a ij(t)d t. Long only Portfolio rule π and its wealth V π. Choose π n + := {x R n : x i = 1, x i 0 } invest π i V π of money to company i for i = 1,..., n, i.e., π i V π /X i share of company i : n dv π (t) = i=1 V π (0) = w. π i (t)v π (t) dx i (t), 0 t <, X i (t)

29 Capital Stocks and Portfolio Rules Market X = ((X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), t 0) of n companies log X i(t ) T T n X i (0) = G i (t)dt + S i,ν (t)dw ν (t), 0 0 ν=1 with initial capital X i (0) = x i > 0, i = 1,..., n, 0 T <. Define a ij ( ) = n ν=1 S iν( )S jν ( ) and A ij ( ) = 0 a ij(t)d t. Long only Portfolio rule π and its wealth V π. Choose π n + := {x R n : x i = 1, x i 0 } invest π i V π of money to company i for i = 1,..., n, i.e., π i V π /X i share of company i : n dv π (t) = i=1 V π (0) = w. π i (t)v π (t) dx i (t), 0 t <, X i (t)

29 Capital Stocks and Portfolio Rules Market X = ((X 1 (t),..., X n (t)), t 0) of n companies log X i(t ) T T n X i (0) = G i (t)dt + S i,ν (t)dw ν (t), 0 0 ν=1 with initial capital X i (0) = x i > 0, i = 1,..., n, 0 T <. Define a ij ( ) = n ν=1 S iν( )S jν ( ) and A ij ( ) = 0 a ij(t)d t. Long only Portfolio rule π and its wealth V π. Choose π n + := {x R n : x i = 1, x i 0 } invest π i V π of money to company i for i = 1,..., n, i.e., π i V π /X i share of company i : n dv π (t) = i=1 V π (0) = w. π i (t)v π (t) dx i (t), 0 t <, X i (t)

30 Portfolios and Relative Arbitrage Market portfolio: Take π(t) = m(t) = (m 1 (t),, m n (t)) n + where m i (t) = X i (t) X 1 + X n (t), i = 1,..., n, 0 t <. Diversity weighted portfolio: Given p [0, 1], take π i (t) = (m i (t)) P p n j=1 (m for i = 1,..., n, 0 t <. j (t)) p Functionally generated portfolio (Fernholz ( 02) & Karatzas ( 08)). A portfolio π represents an arbitrage opportunity relative to another portfolio ρ on [0, T ], if P(V π (T ) V ρ (T )) = 1, P(V π (T ) > V ρ (T )) > 0. Can we find an arbitrage opportunity π relative to m?

30 Portfolios and Relative Arbitrage Market portfolio: Take π(t) = m(t) = (m 1 (t),, m n (t)) n + where m i (t) = X i (t) X 1 + X n (t), i = 1,..., n, 0 t <. Diversity weighted portfolio: Given p [0, 1], take π i (t) = (m i (t)) P p n j=1 (m for i = 1,..., n, 0 t <. j (t)) p Functionally generated portfolio (Fernholz ( 02) & Karatzas ( 08)). A portfolio π represents an arbitrage opportunity relative to another portfolio ρ on [0, T ], if P(V π (T ) V ρ (T )) = 1, P(V π (T ) > V ρ (T )) > 0. Can we find an arbitrage opportunity π relative to m?

31 Constant-portfolio For a constant-proportion π( ) π, [ n { V π Aii (t) ( (t) = w exp π i 2 +log Xi (t) )} 1 X i (0) 2 for 0 t <. i=1 n ] π i A ij (t)π j i,j=1 Here A ij ( ) = 0 a ij(t)d t and a ij ( ) = n ν=1 S iν( )S jν ( ), d Y (t) = G(Y (t))d t + S(Y (t))dw (t) ; 0 t <, G(y) = p Σ n (g p 1 (1) + γ 1 + γ,..., g p 1 (n) + γ n + γ) 1 Rp (y), S(y) = p Σ n diag(σ p 1 (1),..., σ p 1 (n) ) }{{} s p 1 Rp (y) ; y Rn.

32 Target Portfolio(Cover( 91) & Jamshidian( 92)) [ n { V π Aii (t) ( ( ) = w exp π i 2 +log Xi ( ) )} 1 X i (0) 2 i=1 n ] π i A ij ( )π j i,j=1 Target Portfolio Π (t) maximizes the wealth V π (t) for t 0: V (t) := max V π (t), π n + Π (t) := arg max V π (t), π n + where by Lagrange method we obtain Π i (t) = (2A ii (t) n j=1 1 ) 1 [ 2 n 2 A jj (t) n j=1 + 1 2 + 1 ( A ii (t) log Xi (t) ) ; 0 t <. X i (0) 1 ( A jj (t) log Xj (t) )] X j (0)

Asymptotic Target Portfolio Under the hybrid Atlas model with the assumptions 1 v(π) := lim T T log V π (T ) = γ + 1 ( n n π i a ii π i a ) ii π j 2 i=1 i=1 }{{} γπ where (a ij ) 1 i n is the (i,i) element of a 1 := lim T T T 0 (a ij (t)) 1 i,j n d t = p Σ n θ p s p s p. Asymptotic target portfolio maximizes the excess growth γπ : ( n n π := arg max π i a π n ii π i a ) ii π j. + We obtain π i = 1 [ 1 n 2 ( n 2 a ii 1 a j=1 jj i=1 ) 1 ] 33 i=1 = lim Π i (t) ; i = 1,..., n. t

Asymptotic Target Portfolio Under the hybrid Atlas model with the assumptions 1 v(π) := lim T T log V π (T ) = γ + 1 ( n n π i a ii π i a ) ii π j 2 i=1 i=1 }{{} γπ where (a ij ) 1 i n is the (i,i) element of a 1 := lim T T T 0 (a ij (t)) 1 i,j n d t = p Σ n θ p s p s p. Asymptotic target portfolio maximizes the excess growth γπ : ( n n π := arg max π i a π n ii π i a ) ii π j. + We obtain π i = 1 [ 1 n 2 ( n 2 a ii 1 a j=1 jj i=1 ) 1 ] 33 i=1 = lim Π i (t) ; i = 1,..., n. t

34 Universal Portfolio(Cover( 91) & Jamshidian( 92)) Universal portfolio is defined as π Π i ( ) := n i V π ( )dπ + V π ( )dπ, 1 i n, V bπ ( ) = n + V π ( )dπ n +. dπ n + Proposition Under the hybrid Atlas model with the model assumptions, 1 lim T T log V bπ (T ) V π (T ) = lim 1 T T log V bπ (T ) V (T ) = 0 P a.s.

34 Universal Portfolio(Cover( 91) & Jamshidian( 92)) Universal portfolio is defined as π Π i ( ) := n i V π ( )dπ + V π ( )dπ, 1 i n, V bπ ( ) = n + V π ( )dπ n +. dπ n + Proposition Under the hybrid Atlas model with the model assumptions, 1 lim T T log V bπ (T ) V π (T ) = lim 1 T T log V bπ (T ) V (T ) = 0 P a.s.

35 Conclusion Ergodic properties of Hybrid Atlas model Diversity weighted portfolio, Target portfolio, Universal portfolio. Further topics: short term arbitrage, generalized portfolio generating function, large market (n ), numéraire portfolio, data implementation. References: 1. arxiv: 0909.0065 2. arxiv: 0810.2149 (to appear in Annals of Applied Probability) Tomoyuki Ichiba (UCSB) ichiba@pstat.ucsb.edu