Appendix to. The Agglomeration of Exporters by Destination

Similar documents
Exporting Spatial Externalities

Important Developments in International Coke Markets

The study of Geography and the use of geographic tools help us view the world in new ways.

Study Guide Unit 6 Economics and Development

Unit 6: Industrialization and Development Part 3-4

Gravity Analysis of Regional Economic Interdependence: In case of Japan

World Industrial Regions

Explain the impact of location, climate, natural resources, and population distribution on Europe. a. Compare how the location, climate, and natural

CLASS XII GEOGRAPHY (029) SAMPLE QUESTION PAPER ( ) Time allowed - 3 Hrs. Max. Marks 70

Nation: geographic area that is dominated by a large population that shares a common history and culture, ie. Kurds and Palestinians.

YANNICK LANG Visiting Student

THE GRAVITY MODEL OF INTERREGIONAL TRADE: CASE OF EASTERN SIBERIA

Melting Ice Caps: Implications for Asia-North America Linkages and the Panama Canal

Chapter 12. Key Issue Three: Why do business services locate in large settlements?

Location Patterns of Manufacturing Industries in Tunisia

Geography for Life Activities

Central Valley School District Social Studies Curriculum Map Grade 7. August - September

CENTRAL ASIAN REPUBLICS AND THEIR NEW TRANSPORT DEMANDS

Export Destinations and Input Prices. Appendix A

WORLD GEOGRAPHY INSTRUCTIONAL PACING GUIDE

September 14, 2013 Objective: How does geography impact history? What important features exist that have shaped societies?

Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy

Introducing Railway Time in the Balkans

Port basin choice with Russian container trade

MONGOLIA S COKING COAL EXPORT POTENTIALS IN NORTHEAST ASIA. Dr. ENKHBOLD Voroshilov. Director, Mongolian Development Strategy Institute (NGO)

Cross-Border Infrastructure Connectivity: Needs, Facts and Challenges

CAN SOLAR ACTIVITY INFLUENCE THE OCCURRENCE OF ECONOMIC RECESSIONS? Mikhail Gorbanev January 2016

AAG CENTER FOR GLOBAL GEOGRAPHY EDUCATION Internationalizing the Teaching and Learning of Geography

Why has globalisation brought such large increases in exports to some countries and not to others?

A Study on Trade of Complementarity among Xinjiang and Its Neighboring Countries

World Geography Fall 2013 Semester Review Project

Impact of Container Ports on Economic Development:- A Comparative Study Among Selected Top Seven Container Ports in India

Global Data Catalog initiative Christophe Charpentier ArcGIS Content Product Manager

Reshaping Economic Geography

LEIBNIZ INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT

LEARNING OUTCOMES SST (G1-G12)

the regional nearest neighbor tests and by the first order nearest neighbor measures.

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors

HUMAN GEOGRAPHY. G. Fedorov * V. Korneevets * SOCIOECONOMIC TYPOLOGY OF RUSSIA S COASTAL REGIONS. Introduction

East View Cartographic

Map List. 560 World World Physical World Physical-Pacific & Atlantic Region World Landforms World Ocean Floor 10

THE FIVE THEMES OF GEOGRAPHY U N I T O N E

HOTEL BUSINESS AND TOURISM INSTITUTE RUSSIAN SEGMENT OF THE SILK ROAD

LOUISIANA STUDENT STANDARDS FOR SOCIAL STUDIES THAT CORRELATE WITH A FIELD TRIP TO DESTREHAN PLANTATION KINDERGARTEN

Chapter 9: Looking Beyond Poverty: The Development Continuum

External Backward Linkage and External Forward Linkage. in Asian International Input-Output Table

Figure 10. Travel time accessibility for heavy trucks

GDP growth and inflation forecasting performance of Asian Development Outlook

Key Issue 1: Where Is Industry Distributed?

Modeling the economic growth of Arctic regions in Russia

Gravity Equation. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. April Sharif U. of Tech. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh (Sharif U. of Tech.) Gravity Equation April / 16

LOCATIONAL PREFERENCES OF FDI FIRMS IN TURKEY

Socials Studies. Chapter 3 Canada s People 3.0-Human Geography

Economic and Social Council

Convergence and spatial interactions: evidence from Russian regions

MARS AREA SCHOOL DISTRICT CURRICULUM GRADE: Grade 4

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad and Karim Foda

International Economic Geography- Introduction

Paramonov, Igor (2012). North American Integration: NAFTA and Beyond. The Business Review, Cambridge. Vol.20, Num. 2, Dec. 2012, pp

By Geri Flanary To accompany AP Human Geography: A Study Guide 3 rd edition By Ethel Wood

Global. Shift. Global. Peter Dicken. Webs. Gordon Winder. Global. Webs

MNES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY TOPIC 3A: INTERNAL ORGANIZATION OF MNE ACTIVITIES

The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Agricultural and Food Trade

Application of eigenvector-based spatial filtering approach to. a multinomial logit model for land use data

FORECAST ERRORS IN PRICES AND WAGES: THE EXPERIENCE WITH THREE PROGRAMME COUNTRIES

IEEE..- AD-A INDICATORS OF COMPARATIVE EAST-EST ECONOMIC STRENGTH 171

Supplementary Appendix for Power, Proximity, and Democracy: Geopolitical Competition in the International System

Students will able to: Define Geography Explain the 5 Themes Analyze the 5 Themes with an example

Prentice Hall World Cultures: A Global Mosaic 2004 Correlated to: Wisconsin Model Academic Standards for Social Studies (By the end of Grade 12)

FINLAND, A COOL ARCTIC COUNTRY WITH SNOW-HOW

First Nine Weeks Exam

Networks and International Trade: APractitioner sperspective

AP Human Geography AP EXAM Free Response Questions and Possible Future Questions

Cities, Countries, and Population

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Trade Integration and Industrial Specialization in Central Europe

Proposed AKS for 6 th Grade Social Studies

2Russian Regional Growth

The Spatial Information Corridor Contributes to UNISPACE+50. JIANG HUI Director of Internation Cooperation Department

Borchert s Epochs of American Urbanization

The ESPON Programme. Goals Main Results Future

Use Eaton Kortum model to look at very cool data

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad, Karim Foda, and Ethan Wu

Charting Employment Loss in North Carolina Textiles 1

Article: National Geographic Department

The Soviet Union and its Geographical Problems

CONTENTS. Acknowledgements... i-ii Contents... iii-viii List of Tables, Maps, Graphs & Figures... ix-x Abbreviations... xi-xiii Preface...

Space of flows. Institute of Geography and Spatial Organization, Polish Academy of Sciences. Ministry of Development, Republic of Poland

If you are looking for a book Finland Map in pdf format, then you have come on to loyal website. We furnish complete option of this ebook in doc,

Alleghany County Schools Curriculum Guide GRADE/COURSE: World Geography

Optimizing forecasts for inflation and interest rates by time-series model averaging

Purchasing power parity: A nonlinear multivariate perspective. Abstract

Global activity distribution patterns of top international Chinese contractors Chuan Chen1, a, Hongjiang Li1, b and Igor Martek2, c

Poland, European Territory, ESPON Programme Warsaw, 2 July 2007 STRATEGY OF THE ESPON 2013 PROGRAMME

2012 State of the Region Address. Michael C. Carroll, Ph.D. Center for Regional Development Bowling Green State University

AP Human Geography Free Response Questions Categorized

Cotton Economics Research Institute CERI Outlook Report

Chapter 8. Political Geography

Blooms: Knowledge Learning Objective: Understand how states and nations are organized.

Korea's Nord Politics and New Direction of Geography Education in Korea

Transcription:

Appendix to The Agglomeration of Exporters by Destination Andrew J. Cassey and Katherine N. Schmeiser September 2012 A The political organization of Russia and the location of ports and products In 2003, Russia had 89 federal regions. These regions were separated into 49 oblasts (provinces), 21 republics, 6 krais (territories), 10 okrugs (autonomous districts), 1 autonomous oblast, and 2 federal cities (Moscow and St. Petersberg). The divisions are based on ethnic groups and history. Each region has equal representation in the Federal Assembly, though there are differences in autonomy. However these differences are minor (and decreasing over time) because each region is attached to one of eight federal districts administered by an envoy of Russia s President. The districts are designed to oversee regional compliance with federal laws. Most taxes are set federally. In 2003, regions could set corporate property tax, gambling business tax, and transport tax within bounds established federally (CTEC 2006, p. 955). Exports of goods from Russia are subject to a value-added tax of 0% throughout Russia (p. 960), except on some exports of oil and natural gas. Export customs duty rates are set federally as well (p. 961). We show that the location of Russian exporters can neither be accounted for by the location of export commodities nor the location of borders and ports. 1

Russia s major manufacturing industries are: all forms of machine building from rolling mills to high-performance aircraft and space vehicles; defense industries including radar, missile production, and advanced electronic components, shipbuilding; road and rail transportation equipment; communications equipment; agricultural machinery, tractors, and construction equipment; electric power generating and transmitting equipment; medical and scientific instruments; consumer durables, textiles, foodstuffs, and handicrafts. Russia s largest export commodities are: petroleum products, wood and wood products, metals, chemicals, and a wide variety of civilian and military manufactures. Products such as petroleum, wood, metals, and chemicals need to be processed to become manufactured goods. Therefore it is possible that the location of exports is the same as the location of the refineries and processing plants for these goods. Though many exporters are located in the same region as a major port, there are regions that are not close to a major port in the top quintile of the number of exporting firms. The largest ports are Azov (Rostov, Black Sea), Kaliningrad (Kaliningrad, Baltic Sea), Nakhodka and Vostochny (Primorsky, Sea of Japan, largest), Novorossiysk (Krasnordar, Black Sea, largest), Primorsk (Leningrad, Baltic Sea, largest, lots of oil), and Saint Petersburg (Saint Petersburg, Baltic Sea). Cassey (2011) documents that access to water is an important predictor of U.S. state exports. 2

Figure 1: Number of exporting firms, by region. Cut-offs correspond to quintiles so that there are an equal number of regions in each category. B Russian exporters and exports First, consider the number of exporting firms by region. Figure 1 shows that the regional concentration of Russian manufacturing exporters is diverse. The majority of exporters are located either around Moscow and St. Petersburg or the Kazakhstan/Mongolia/China border. Nine regions did not have any reported exporting firms in 2003. Figure 1 shows that in Russia, as elsewhere, many exporting firms are located near major ports. However, the figure also shows that there are regions with many exporting firms that are not located near a major port. The top destinations for Russian exports in 2003 were, in order: China, United States, United Kingdom, Japan, Ukraine, Kazakhstan, Turkey, 3

Netherlands, Germany, and Iran. Of these, only Ukraine and Kazakstan were part of the Soviet Union. Additionally, Russia does not currently have a Warsaw Pact nation as a top destination. (Soviet trade was with countries of similar ideology such as Yugoslavia and Poland.) While the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (Comecon) from 1949-1991 facilitated economic exchanges with Eastern Bloc countries and other socialist countries, because we do not see current evidence of favored trade relations with former Soviet or Eastern bloc countries, we do not treat them any differently than Western countries. In a robust check in the main paper, we remove Warsaw Pact and Former Soviet Union countries from our analysis. Federal laws in Russia severely limit the ability of Russian firms to change region (Botolf 2003). Because of this, firms choose how much to export to each country in the world, taking their location as given. Furthermore, because the Soviet Union did not trade with western countries, we believe it is likely that the Soviet central planners chose firm locations for reasons other than the expansion of trade (Bradshaw 2008; Huber, Nagaev, and Wörgötter 1997). Other evidence that international trade with Western countries was not important in Soviet economic planning is that the large Pacific port of Vladivostok, home of the Soviet Pacific Fleet, was closed to foreign vessels until 1991. C Exports in the context of output If external geography played no role in the location of exporters, the pattern of region-country aggregate exports (X i j ) would be identical to the pattern of regional production (Y i ) with some randomness. In this case, the destination of 4

Russian sales would not matter for the location of Russian exporters. To show that this does not hold, we conduct two simple tests. The first test is to run the following regression: logx i j = 5.40 (0.386) + 0.44 (0.046) logy i (1) N = 2985, R 2 = 0.03, RMSE = 2.62 The index i runs over the set of Russia s regions and the index j runs over the set of countries in the world. Standard errors are robust and indicates the estimated coefficient is significantly different from zero with 99% confidence. The extremely low explanatory power as given by the R 2 indicates that the pattern of production in Russia does not account for the pattern of exports in the data. The second test is to compare the ratio of exports from each Russian region to the ratio of GDP from each region to Russia. We modify the familiar concept of location quotient to put Russian exports by region into the context of overall economic activity, LQ i = X / i Yi X Y. If the LQ is greater than 1 then the region s export share to the world is larger than it s share of GDP. This indicates the region is relatively specialized in exporting in comparison to overall economic activity. The strength of this approach is that it controls for the geography of economic activity within Russia, The average LQ i is 1.454 with standard deviation 0.489. But though the average LQ i is not significantly different from one, the regions with the largest 5

Figure 2: Regional firm distribution, regions weighted by exports. LQ i are several times the standard deviation. Though most region s LQ i is around 1, there are many that are in the right tail. Thus there are regions in Russia that are heavily concentrated in exporting compared to overall output and regions that do not export anything at all. Because we only consider manufacturing activity, we repeat the proceeding exercise by scaling the regional GDP data by the share that is from industry. The results (not reported) are not qualitatively different from before. Therefore, we have documented that Russian exporters are not simply located in the geographic pattern of industrial economic activity. We also use the balls & bins method of Armenter and Koren (2010) to assign firms to each region. We show a histogram in figure 2 of regional firm distribution and then test to see if the actual distribution is different than one with firms distributed randomly across bins (weighted by regional exports). We use a 6

two-sample Komorgorov-Smirnov test for equality and reject that the samples are the same with an exact p-value of 0.013. D Robustness One feature of the Russian export data is the high frequency of zeros. There are 89 regions in Russia and we have 2003 GDP data (IMF 2006) and distance for 175 countries. Therefore, there are 15,575 possible observations. Of these, only 2991 have positive exports, or 19%. (We also lose some observations because of missing regional GDP data from Russia.) Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) show that an OLS estimator on a gravity-type equation as we have in the main paper can bias estimates when there are many zeros in the data. We follow them and use the poisson quasi-maximum likelihood estimator. ( X i j = exp Y i Y j X i j Y i Y j = exp 20.06 (1.189) 12.695 (1.231) logd 1.04 89 (0.150) i j + i=2 N = 15400, AIC = 526.00 (.804 (0.119) logd logw N = 2985, AIC = 456.00 i j 175 κ i S i + j=2 δ j T j )..116 89 (0.027) i j + i=2 175 κ i S i + j=2 δ j T j ). Though the estimates for the regression with the agglomeration term change quantitatively, the are the same qualitatively. The agglomeration term is economically and statistically significant. Importantly, the model with the agglomeration term has a lower Akaike Information Criterion than the model without the term, indicating the model with agglomeration is preferred. However, region-country observations of zero exports also have zero weight for those 7

exports. Santos Silva and Tenreyro do not consider the model where zeros occur on both the left and right hand side of the regression. E Application to U.S. state exports Though we established the facts about agglomeration of exporters around the destination of their shipments and motived our model using transaction-level customs data from Russia, there is nothing in the reduced form equation that requires customs data. Therefore, we take our model to another regional export data set. The data set is the Origin of Movement (OM) export data for U.S. states. We do this to check that our previous results are applicable to a wider set of countries than Russia because of possible idiosyncratic issues with the Russian data. A detailed description of the OM data is in Cassey (2009). Because of his findings on data quality, we limit our observations to manufactured exports only. We also restrict our sample to 2003 to match the Russian data. The same sample of countries is used except that Russia as a destination replaces the United States. Also there are 22 observations which have positive export sales but a weight of zero. We do not use these observations. The results are reported in table 1. Beginning with the benchmark gravity equation in column (A), we find the estimated coefficient on distance is much larger than for the Russian data. For us, the relevant statistic is ˆ R 2 =.54. In Column (B), when we apply the U.S. data to our gravity equation including aggregate weight, the ˆ R 2 increases from.54 to.75, an increase of 40.2%. (The results for the data pooled over 1997 to 2008 are essentially the same.) As with 8

Table 1: OLS estimates on U.S. data Var. (A) (B) (C) D i j 2.05 0.95 1.50 (.137) (.102) (.124) W i j 0.433 (.006) lagw i j 0.243 (.010) N 7061 7061 2985 ˆR 2.54.75.60 RMSE 1.28 0.93 1.15 Notes: The benchmark gravity equation in (A): log X i j Y i Y j = α β 1 logd i j + 50 i=2 κ is i + 175 j=2 δ jt j + ε i j. Exporter and importer binary variables and a constant are estimated but not reported. Standard errors (in parentheses) are robust. Specification (B) adds the aggregate shipping weight. Specification (C) lags aggregate weight. indicate p-values less than.01. the Russian data, we can confidently reject that η = 0 (F(1,6835) = 81.87). Furthermore, the estimated coefficients using the U.S. data are similar to those using the Russian data whereas the same is not true for the benchmark. We estimate η = 0.454. Another encouraging result is that our estimate for γ is 0.95 and is again not statistically different from one, as with the Russian data in the main paper. Furthermore, our point estimate is close to the 0.99 to 1.10 range for U.S. data reported in Axtell (2001) whereas the benchmark is too high. Finally, with the U.S. data, we estimate σ = 1.5. One concern with the results so far is that they are driven by the mechanical relationship between export value and weight. We estimated coefficients at the product level and used aggregate weight less product weight in order to break this 9

relationship. Nevertheless, we take advantage of additional data for the U.S. and we follow Koenig (2009) and use aggregate export weight from the previous year, 2002. This severs any mechanical relationship since past aggregate weight cannot affect current export value in any way other than a reduction of the transaction costs of trade. We lose some observations compared to 2003 because those state country pairs did not trade in 2002. The results are reported in table 1 column (C). In this case, we find that our model accounts for 12% more variation in the data than the benchmark. The estimate on the aggregate weight term is statistically significant, though smaller than previously. Therefore, we find that the agglomeration term is important even if it is lagged one year. References Axtell RL (2001) Zipf distribution of U.S. firm sizes. Science 293(5536):1818 1820 Botolf P (2003) Divergence and dispersion in the Russian economy. Europe Asia Studies 55(8):1165 1185 Bradshaw M (2008) The geography of Russia s new political economy. New Political Economy 13(2):193 201 Cassey AJ (2009) State export data: Origin of movement vs. origin of production. Journal of Economic and Social Measurement 34(4):241 268, DOI 10.3233/JEM-2009-0323 Cassey AJ (2011) State foreign export pattern. Southern Economic Journal 78(2):308 328 10

Huber P, Nagaev S, Wörgötter A (1997) The changes in location of Russia industry in early transition 1987 1993, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna, East European Series no. 42 IMF (2006) World Economic Outlook Database. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, http: //www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2006/01/data/index.htm (accessed December 15, 2006) Koenig P (2009) Agglomeration and the export decisions of French firms. Journal of Urban Economics 66(3):186 195 Santos Silva JMC, Tenreyro S (2006) The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics 88(4):641 658 11