Stochastic orders: a brief introduction and Bruno s contributions. Franco Pellerey

Similar documents
Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository

Stochastic Comparisons of Weighted Sums of Arrangement Increasing Random Variables

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Reliability of Coherent Systems with Dependent Component Lifetimes

Stochastic Comparisons for Time Transformed Exponential Models

On the Convolution Order with Reliability Applications

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables

AGING FUNCTIONS AND MULTIVARIATE NOTIONS OF NBU AND IFR

S7. Copulas, Markov Operators and Mass Transportation

Some Recent Results on Stochastic Comparisons and Dependence among Order Statistics in the Case of PHR Model

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas

Copulas and Measures of Dependence

A Brief Introduction to Copulas

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

A measure of radial asymmetry for bivariate copulas based on Sobolev norm

Ordering Extremes of Interdependent Random Variables

Estimation of multivariate critical layers: Applications to rainfall data

On the Conditional Value at Risk (CoVaR) from the copula perspective

Modelling Dependence with Copulas and Applications to Risk Management. Filip Lindskog, RiskLab, ETH Zürich

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums

Simulating Exchangeable Multivariate Archimedean Copulas and its Applications. Authors: Florence Wu Emiliano A. Valdez Michael Sherris

, respectively, and a joint distribution function H(x,y) = PX [ xy, y]

Statistics and Probability Letters

Clearly, if F is strictly increasing it has a single quasi-inverse, which equals the (ordinary) inverse function F 1 (or, sometimes, F 1 ).

Copulas. Mathematisches Seminar (Prof. Dr. D. Filipovic) Di Uhr in E

A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables

Copulas with given diagonal section: some new results

Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures

DISPERSIVE FUNCTIONS AND STOCHASTIC ORDERS

Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence

A New Extended Mixture Model of Residual Lifetime Distributions

Received: 20 December 2011; in revised form: 4 February 2012 / Accepted: 7 February 2012 / Published: 2 March 2012

Correlation & Dependency Structures

A SHORT NOTE ON MULTIVARIATE DEPENDENCE MODELING

Reducing Model Risk With Goodness-of-fit Victory Idowu London School of Economics

Journal of Multivariate Analysis

Tail Dependence of Multivariate Pareto Distributions

REMARKS ON TWO PRODUCT LIKE CONSTRUCTIONS FOR COPULAS

COPULA-BASED DENSITY WEIGHTING FUNCTIONS

A family of transformed copulas with singular component

GENERAL MULTIVARIATE DEPENDENCE USING ASSOCIATED COPULAS

Quasi-copulas and signed measures

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups

Correlation: Copulas and Conditioning

ASSOCIATIVE n DIMENSIONAL COPULAS

On the Choice of Parametric Families of Copulas

Semi-parametric predictive inference for bivariate data using copulas

Estimation Under Multivariate Inverse Weibull Distribution

Construction and estimation of high dimensional copulas

Estimating Bivariate Tail: a copula based approach

Modelling and Estimation of Stochastic Dependence

ESTIMATING BIVARIATE TAIL

Copulas and dependence measurement

Non parametric estimation of Archimedean copulas and tail dependence. Paris, february 19, 2015.

On Some Properties of the Discrete NBU Class Based On Generating Function Order

EVANESCE Implementation in S-PLUS FinMetrics Module. July 2, Insightful Corp

Multivariate Distribution Models

Some stochastic inequalities for weighted sums

Sklar s theorem in an imprecise setting

The Supermodular Stochastic Ordering

ON UNIFORM TAIL EXPANSIONS OF BIVARIATE COPULAS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

2.6 Logarithmic Functions. Inverse Functions. Question: What is the relationship between f(x) = x 2 and g(x) = x?

Modelling Dependent Credit Risks

Behaviour of multivariate tail dependence coefficients

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds

Copulas. MOU Lili. December, 2014

Convolution Based Unit Root Processes: a Simulation Approach

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 3 Apr 2019

Stochastic orders of variability

Probability Distributions and Estimation of Ali-Mikhail-Haq Copula

I N S T I T U T D E S T A T I S T I Q U E B I O S T A T I S T I Q U E E T S C I E N C E S A C T U A R I E L L E S (I S B A)

MA/ST 810 Mathematical-Statistical Modeling and Analysis of Complex Systems

Lifetime Dependence Modelling using a Generalized Multivariate Pareto Distribution

A New Generalized Gumbel Copula for Multivariate Distributions

Dependence and Order in Families of Archimedean Copulas

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

On Conditional Value at Risk (CoVaR) for tail-dependent copulas

Total positivity in Markov structures

Bivariate Rainfall and Runoff Analysis Using Entropy and Copula Theories

A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks

Stochastic Orders in Heterogeneous Samples with Applications

Dependence. Practitioner Course: Portfolio Optimization. John Dodson. September 10, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline.

Extreme Value Analysis and Spatial Extremes

On the Estimation and Application of Max-Stable Processes

Stochastic Comparisons of Order Statistics from Generalized Normal Distributions

Multivariate survival modelling: a unified approach with copulas

FRÉCHET HOEFFDING LOWER LIMIT COPULAS IN HIGHER DIMENSIONS

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks

MULTIVARIATE EXTREME VALUE ANALYSIS UNDER A

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications

COMPARING APPROXIMATIONS FOR RISK MEASURES RELATED TO SUMS OF CORRELATED LOGNORMAL RANDOM VARIABLES MASTERARBEIT

Approximation of multivariate distribution functions MARGUS PIHLAK. June Tartu University. Institute of Mathematical Statistics

How to select a good vine

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 9 Jan 2016

Chance Constrained Data Envelopment Analysis The Productive Efficiency of Units with Stochastic Outputs

The Cox-Aalen Models as Framework for Construction of Bivariate Probability Distributions, Universal Representation

Elements of Financial Engineering Course

THIELE CENTRE for applied mathematics in natural science

Transcription:

Stochastic orders: a brief introduction and Bruno s contributions. Franco Pellerey

Stochastic orders (comparisons) Among his main interests in research activity A field where his contributions are still highly considered and cited

Stochastic orders (comparisons) Among his main interests in research activity A field where his contributions are still highly considered and cited In this presentation: A short introduction to the subject A description of some of his contributions An example of recent applications of his studies

Stochastic orders: what are they? Assume you have two random variables X and Y describing, e.g., two amounts of money you can get through two different financial investments.

Stochastic orders: what are they? Assume you have two random variables X and Y describing, e.g., two amounts of money you can get through two different financial investments. Assume you have to choose among X and Y.

Stochastic orders: what are they? Assume you have two random variables X and Y describing, e.g., two amounts of money you can get through two different financial investments. Assume you have to choose among X and Y. FIRST CASE X = Y = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 { 2 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 E[Y ] = 2.5

Stochastic orders: what are they? Assume you have two random variables X and Y describing, e.g., two amounts of money you can get through two different financial investments. Assume you have to choose among X and Y. FIRST CASE X = Y = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 { 2 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 E[Y ] = 2.5 Here Y is better than X.

Stochastic orders: what are they? SECOND CASE X = Y = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 { 0 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 E[Y ] = 1.5

Stochastic orders: what are they? SECOND CASE X = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 Y = { 0 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[Y ] = 1.5 Here X is better than Y (but nor for everybody, and not always).

Stochastic orders: what are they? SECOND CASE X = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 Y = { 0 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[Y ] = 1.5 Here X is better than Y (but nor for everybody, and not always). THIRD CASE X = 1 with probability 1 E[X ] = 1 Y = { 0 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[Y ] = 1.5

Stochastic orders: what are they? SECOND CASE X = { 1 with probability 1/2 2 with probability 1/2 E[X ] = 1.5 Y = { 0 with probability 1/2 3 with probability 1/2 E[Y ] = 1.5 Here X is better than Y (but nor for everybody, and not always). THIRD CASE X = 1 with probability 1 E[X ] = 1 { 0 with probability 1/2 Y = E[Y ] = 1.5 3 with probability 1/2 Here we can not immediately assert which one is the best choice.

Stochastic orders: what are they? Thus, we have to introduce new criteria to choose among different alternatives, taking into account our needs. Stochastic orders

Stochastic orders: what are they? Thus, we have to introduce new criteria to choose among different alternatives, taking into account our needs. Stochastic orders In fact, a long list of different stochastic orders have been defined, and applied, in a variety of fields (economics and finance, engineering, medicine, etc.) They are based on comparisons between: The location, or magnitude, of the random variables to be compared (mainly considered in reliability and survival analysis) Ex: X is better than Y if P[X > t] P[Y > t] for all t R (usual stochastic order)

Stochastic orders: what are they? The expectations E[u(X )] and E[u(Y )] of functions of the involved variables (mainly considered in risk theory) Ex: X is better than Y if E[u(X )] E[u(Y )] for every increasing and concave utility function u (increasing concave order)

Stochastic orders: what are they? The expectations E[u(X )] and E[u(Y )] of functions of the involved variables (mainly considered in risk theory) Ex: X is better than Y if E[u(X )] E[u(Y )] for every increasing and concave utility function u (increasing concave order) Their variability Ex: X is more dispersed than Y if X = φ(y ) for some dispersive function φ, i.e., such that φ(x 2 ) x 2 φ(x 1 ) x 1 whenever x 1 x 2 (dispersive order).

Stochastic orders: what are they? The expectations E[u(X )] and E[u(Y )] of functions of the involved variables (mainly considered in risk theory) Ex: X is better than Y if E[u(X )] E[u(Y )] for every increasing and concave utility function u (increasing concave order) Their variability Ex: X is more dispersed than Y if X = φ(y ) for some dispersive function φ, i.e., such that φ(x 2 ) x 2 φ(x 1 ) x 1 whenever x 1 x 2 (dispersive order). Moreover, stochastic orders have been defined in order to provide comparisons in multivariate contexts;

Stochastic orders: what are they? The expectations E[u(X )] and E[u(Y )] of functions of the involved variables (mainly considered in risk theory) Ex: X is better than Y if E[u(X )] E[u(Y )] for every increasing and concave utility function u (increasing concave order) Their variability Ex: X is more dispersed than Y if X = φ(y ) for some dispersive function φ, i.e., such that φ(x 2 ) x 2 φ(x 1 ) x 1 whenever x 1 x 2 (dispersive order). Moreover, stochastic orders have been defined in order to provide comparisons in multivariate contexts; comparisons of stochastic processes.

Stochastic comparisons of stochastic processes B.B. and Marco Scarsini. Convex orderings for stochastic processes. Comment. Math. Univ. Carolin. 32 (1991), no. 1, 115 118. B.B. and Marco Scarsini. On the comparison of pure jump processes. RAIRO Rech. Opér. 26 (1992), no. 1, 41 55. B.B., Erhan Cinlar and Marco Scarsini. Stochastic comparisons of Itô processes. Stochastic Process. Appl. 45 (1993), no. 1, 1 11. B.B. and Marco Scarsini. Positive dependence orderings and stopping times. Ann. Inst. Statist. Math. 46 (1994), no. 2, 333 342.

Multivariate stochastic models B.B. and Fabio Spizzichino. Stochastic comparisons for residual lifetimes and Bayesian notions of multivariate ageing. Adv. in Appl. Probab. 31 (1999), no. 4, 1078 1094. B.B. and Fabio Spizzichino. Dependence and multivariate aging: the role of level sets of the survival function. System and Bayesian reliability, 229 242, Ser. Qual. Reliab. Eng. Stat., 5, World Sci. Publ., 2001. B.B., Subhash Kochar and Fabio Spizzichino. Some bivariate notions of IFR and DMRL and related properties. J. Appl. Probab. 39 (2002), no. 3, 533 544. B.B. and Fabio Spizzichino. Bivariate survival models with Clayton aging functions. Insurance Math. Econom. 37 (2005), no. 1, 6 12. B.B. and Fabio Spizzichino. Relations among univariate aging, bivariate aging and dependence for exchangeable lifetimes. J. Multivariate Anal. 93 (2005), no. 2, 313 339.

Lifetimes and stochastic orders Let X and Y represent the lifetimes of two items, or individuals. Recall: X is said to be smaller in the usual stochastic order than Y if and only if P[X > t] P[Y > t] for all t R +, or, equivalently, if and only if E[φ(X )] E[φ(Y )] for every increasing function φ.

Lifetimes and stochastic orders Let X and Y represent the lifetimes of two items, or individuals. Recall: X is said to be smaller in the usual stochastic order than Y if and only if P[X > t] P[Y > t] for all t R +, or, equivalently, if and only if E[φ(X )] E[φ(Y )] for every increasing function φ. Apart the usual stochastic order, other comparisons are commonly considered in survival analysis. In particular, different orders have been defined and studied to compare residual lifetimes, i.e., to compare the variables [X t X > t] and [Y t Y > t], for t R +. Among them, the hazard rate order, the mean residual life order, the likelihood ratio order, etc.

Lifetimes and stochastic orders Let X and Y represent the lifetimes of two items, or individuals. Recall: X is said to be smaller in the usual stochastic order than Y if and only if P[X > t] P[Y > t] for all t R +, or, equivalently, if and only if E[φ(X )] E[φ(Y )] for every increasing function φ. Apart the usual stochastic order, other comparisons are commonly considered in survival analysis. In particular, different orders have been defined and studied to compare residual lifetimes, i.e., to compare the variables [X t X > t] and [Y t Y > t], for t R +. Among them, the hazard rate order, the mean residual life order, the likelihood ratio order, etc. By means of these orders, it is possible to provide a list of alternative characterizations of aging, i.e., of the effect of the age in the residual lifetime of the items.

Lifetimes and stochastic orders Let X and Y represent the lifetimes of two items, or individuals. Recall: X is said to be smaller in the usual stochastic order than Y if and only if P[X > t] P[Y > t] for all t R +, or, equivalently, if and only if E[φ(X )] E[φ(Y )] for every increasing function φ. Apart the usual stochastic order, other comparisons are commonly considered in survival analysis. In particular, different orders have been defined and studied to compare residual lifetimes, i.e., to compare the variables [X t X > t] and [Y t Y > t], for t R +. Among them, the hazard rate order, the mean residual life order, the likelihood ratio order, etc. By means of these orders, it is possible to provide a list of alternative characterizations of aging, i.e., of the effect of the age in the residual lifetime of the items. Ex: X has Increasing Hazard Rate (IHR) if [X t 1 X > t 1 ] st [X t 2 X > t 2 ] for all 0 t 1 t 2, i.e., if the residual lifetime of X stochastically decreases with the age.

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio)

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Analysis of lifetimes models and aging in multivariate contexts;

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Analysis of lifetimes models and aging in multivariate contexts; Criteria for the stochastic comparison of residual lifetimes based on survivals at different ages.

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Analysis of lifetimes models and aging in multivariate contexts; Criteria for the stochastic comparison of residual lifetimes based on survivals at different ages. Thanks to their studies, now we have

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Analysis of lifetimes models and aging in multivariate contexts; Criteria for the stochastic comparison of residual lifetimes based on survivals at different ages. Thanks to their studies, now we have A clear understanding of the effects of mutual dependence between items on their aging

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Analysis of lifetimes models and aging in multivariate contexts; Criteria for the stochastic comparison of residual lifetimes based on survivals at different ages. Thanks to their studies, now we have A clear understanding of the effects of mutual dependence between items on their aging A clear understanding of the relationships between univariate aging, multivariate aging and dependence

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Ex: As a natural extension of the concept of univariate IHR aging to the bivariate case, one can consider the following:

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Ex: As a natural extension of the concept of univariate IHR aging to the bivariate case, one can consider the following: The random vector (X, Y ) satisfies the Bivariate Increasing Hazard Rate (BIHR) property if, and only if, for all 0 t 1 t 2, [(X t 1, Y t 1 ) {X > t 1, Y > t 1 }] st [(X t 2, Y t 2 ) {X > t 2, Y > t 2 }].

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Ex: As a natural extension of the concept of univariate IHR aging to the bivariate case, one can consider the following: The random vector (X, Y ) satisfies the Bivariate Increasing Hazard Rate (BIHR) property if, and only if, for all 0 t 1 t 2, [(X t 1, Y t 1 ) {X > t 1, Y > t 1 }] st [(X t 2, Y t 2 ) {X > t 2, Y > t 2 }]. In a similar way, by reversing the inequality, one can define the corresponding negative aging property Bivariate Decreasing Hazard Rate (BDHR).

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Ex: As a natural extension of the concept of univariate IHR aging to the bivariate case, one can consider the following: The random vector (X, Y ) satisfies the Bivariate Increasing Hazard Rate (BIHR) property if, and only if, for all 0 t 1 t 2, [(X t 1, Y t 1 ) {X > t 1, Y > t 1 }] st [(X t 2, Y t 2 ) {X > t 2, Y > t 2 }]. In a similar way, by reversing the inequality, one can define the corresponding negative aging property Bivariate Decreasing Hazard Rate (BDHR). Let us say now that the lifetimes X and Y have positive dependence if large (respectively, small) values of X tend to go together (in some stochastic sense) with large (respectively, small) values of Y. Similarly define the negative dependence: if large (respectively, small) values of X tend to go together (in some stochastic sense) with small (respectively, large) values of Y. [Formal definitions can be given by means of the copula of the vector (X, Y ).]

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Bruno and Fabio formalized the following relationships (and similar ones).

Contributions by Bruno (and Fabio) Bruno and Fabio formalized the following relationships (and similar ones). positive dependence + univariate negative aging multivariate negative aging; positive dependence + multivariate positive aging univariate positive aging; etc.. multivariate positive aging + univariate negative aging negative dependence;

Recently... Also, they shown, through counterexamples, but also clearly explaining why, we have

Recently... Also, they shown, through counterexamples, but also clearly explaining why, we have multivariate positive aging + univariate positive aging positive dependence

Recently... Even if based on stochastic orders, Bruno and Fabio concentrated their studies on applications of comparisons in multivariate aging and survival models, without realizing the effects of their results in other fields. Like, for example, their possible applications in the analysis of the properties of Joint Stochastic Orders.

Recently... Even if based on stochastic orders, Bruno and Fabio concentrated their studies on applications of comparisons in multivariate aging and survival models, without realizing the effects of their results in other fields. Like, for example, their possible applications in the analysis of the properties of Joint Stochastic Orders. Defined and studied for the first time by Shantikumar and Yao (1991), Bivariate characterization of some stochastic order relations. Adv. in Appl. Prob., 23, 642 659, the joint stochastic orders have been introduced in order to compare, marginally, univariate lifetimes, but taking into account their possible mutual dependence.

Recently... Ex: Consider a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent lifetimes. It is possible to compare the corresponding residual lifetimes considering the inequalities [X t X > t] st [Y t Y > t] for all t R + (hazard rate order, hr ). This is a comparison based on the marginal distributions of X and Y.

Recently... Ex: Consider a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent lifetimes. It is possible to compare the corresponding residual lifetimes considering the inequalities [X t X > t] st [Y t Y > t] for all t R + (hazard rate order, hr ). This is a comparison based on the marginal distributions of X and Y. Otherwise, it is possible to compare their residual lifetimes taking into account survivals of both, i.e., consider the following inequalities: [X t {X > t, Y > t}] st [Y t {X > t, Y > t}] for all t R +. This is a joint stochastic order based on the joint distribution of (X, Y ) (joint weak hazard rate order, hr:wj ).

Recently... Ex: Consider a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent lifetimes. It is possible to compare the corresponding residual lifetimes considering the inequalities [X t X > t] st [Y t Y > t] for all t R + (hazard rate order, hr ). This is a comparison based on the marginal distributions of X and Y. Otherwise, it is possible to compare their residual lifetimes taking into account survivals of both, i.e., consider the following inequalities: [X t {X > t, Y > t}] st [Y t {X > t, Y > t}] for all t R +. This is a joint stochastic order based on the joint distribution of (X, Y ) (joint weak hazard rate order, hr:wj ). It can be shown that the stochastic orders above are not equivalent, i.e., X hr Y X wj:hr Y. Actually, the equivalence holds if, and only if, X and Y are independent.

Recently... Because of its properties, the joint weak hazard rate order has interesting applications is different fields, like in reliability (optimal allocation of components), in actuarial sciences, in portfolio theory or in medicine (crossover clinical trials).

Recently... Because of its properties, the joint weak hazard rate order has interesting applications is different fields, like in reliability (optimal allocation of components), in actuarial sciences, in portfolio theory or in medicine (crossover clinical trials). Ex: Let (X, Y ) be such that X hr:wj Y. It can be shown that in this case E[g(X, Y )] E[g(Y, X )] for all function g : R 2 R such that g(x, y) = g(x, y) g(y, x) is supermodular in the set U = {(x, y) R 2, x y}.

Recently... Consider now a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent financial returns, and consider the two portfolios Z 1 = αy + (1 α)x and Z 2 = (1 α)y + αx, α [0, 1].

Recently... Consider now a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent financial returns, and consider the two portfolios Z 1 = αy + (1 α)x and Z 2 = (1 α)y + αx, α [0, 1]. Because of the previous property, for α 1/2 one has X hr:wj Y = E[u(Z 1 )] E[u(Z 2 )] for every logarithmic utility function u (like, e.g., u(t) = ln(1 + t)). [The proof easily follows letting g(x, y) = u(αy + (1 α)x).]

Recently... Consider now a pair (X, Y ) of non-independent financial returns, and consider the two portfolios Z 1 = αy + (1 α)x and Z 2 = (1 α)y + αx, α [0, 1]. Because of the previous property, for α 1/2 one has X hr:wj Y = E[u(Z 1 )] E[u(Z 2 )] for every logarithmic utility function u (like, e.g., u(t) = ln(1 + t)). [The proof easily follows letting g(x, y) = u(αy + (1 α)x).] Another interesting property of the joint weak hazard rate order is that it is closed with respect to mixtures (while the standard hazard rate order is not)

Recently... Studying the properties of this particular order, we verified that a relationship between the joint weak hazard rate order and the standard hazard rate order can be stated by making use of a notion defined and analyzed by Bruno and Fabio in their works.

Recently... Studying the properties of this particular order, we verified that a relationship between the joint weak hazard rate order and the standard hazard rate order can be stated by making use of a notion defined and analyzed by Bruno and Fabio in their works. Definition A bivariate copula C : [0, 1] 2 [0, 1] is called supermigrative (submigrative) if it is symmetric, i.e. C(u, v) = C(v, u) for every (u, v) [0, 1] 2, and it satisfies for all u v and γ (0, 1). C(u, γv) ( ) C(γu, v)

Recently... As shown by Bruno and Fabio, examples of copulas satisfying the supermigrative property are the Archimedean ones having log-convex inverse generators. Thus, e.g., the Gumbel-Hougaard copula, and the Frank and Clayton copulas with positive value of the parameter θ. The Farlie-Gumbel-Morgenstern copula, with posite value of the parameter, satisfies this property as well.

Recently... It can be shown that the following holds.

Recently... It can be shown that the following holds. Theorem Let the survival copula C (X,Y ) of (X, Y ) be supermigrative. Then X hr Y = X hr:wj Y. Viceversa, if the survival copula C (X,Y ) of (X, Y ) is submigrative, then X hr:wj Y = X hr Y.

A final remark Results similar to the previous one can be proved also for the other well-know joint orders.

A final remark Results similar to the previous one can be proved also for the other well-know joint orders. Definition Let D be the set of functions D = {g g : R 2 R}. We denote: G hr = {g D g(x, y) g(y, x) is non-decreasing in x y x}; G lr = {g D g(x, y) g(y, x) for all y x}.

A final remark Results similar to the previous one can be proved also for the other well-know joint orders. Definition Let D be the set of functions D = {g g : R 2 R}. We denote: G hr = {g D g(x, y) g(y, x) is non-decreasing in x y x}; G lr = {g D g(x, y) g(y, x) for all y x}. Definition Given two random variables X and Y as above, X is said to be greater than Y in the joint hazard rate order (denoted X hr:j Y ) if E[g(X, Y )] E[g(Y, X )] for all g G hr ; in the joint likelihood ratio order (denoted X lr:j Y ) if E[g(X, Y )] E[g(Y, X )] for all g G lr.

A final remark Recall the definition of standard joint likelihood ratio: X lr Y [X t t X t + s] st [Y t t Y t + s] for all t R, s R +.

A final remark Recall the definition of standard joint likelihood ratio: X lr Y [X t t X t + s] st [Y t t Y t + s] for all t R, s R +. Theorem Let (X, Y ) be a random vector with an absolutely continuous survival copula Ĉ(X,Y ). Assume that Ĉ (X,Y ) is exchangeable (symmetric); The density ĉ (X,Y ) (u, v) is non-increasing in u and non-decreasing in v for all u v. Then X lr [ hr ] Y implies X lr:j [ hr:j ] Y.

A final remark The second assumption appearing in this statement has an immediate interpretation: it essentially means that for every point (u, v) below the diagonal and for any point (û, ˆv) contained in the closed triangle with vertices (u, v), (u, u) and (v, v) it holds ĉ (X,Y ) (û, ˆv) ĉ (X,Y ) (u, v) (and similarly for points above the diagonal).

A final remark Roughly speaking, it is satisfied by copulas having probability mass mainly concentrated around the diagonal, thus describing positive dependence, as the copulas having density uniformly distributed on regions like the ones shown in the following figure.

A final remark Roughly speaking, it is satisfied by copulas having probability mass mainly concentrated around the diagonal, thus describing positive dependence, as the copulas having density uniformly distributed on regions like the ones shown in the following figure. Such an assumption can be further weakened in order to let the relation X lr Y X lr:j Y be satisfied also for survival copulas having a singularity on the diagonal v = u, like Cuadras-Augé copulas or Frechét copulas.

A final remark Roughly speaking, it is satisfied by copulas having probability mass mainly concentrated around the diagonal, thus describing positive dependence, as the copulas having density uniformly distributed on regions like the ones shown in the following figure. Such an assumption can be further weakened in order to let the relation X lr Y X lr:j Y be satisfied also for survival copulas having a singularity on the diagonal v = u, like Cuadras-Augé copulas or Frechét copulas. A larger class of copulas satisfying this property has been defined and studied in Durante (2006), A new class of symmetric bivariate copulas, J of Nonparametrical Statistics, 18, 499 510.