Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Similar documents
Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

1 General Equilibrium

1 Second Welfare Theorem

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Second Welfare Theorem

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Mathematics 530. Practice Problems. n + 1 }

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Existence of Equilibria with a Tight Marginal Pricing Rule

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Competitive Equilibrium when Preferences Change over Time

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0}

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Sums of sets, etc.

SOME RESULTS CONCERNING THE MULTIVALUED OPTIMIZATION AND THEIR APPLICATIONS

TEXTO PARA DISCUSSÃO. No Heckscher-Ohlin explained by Walras. Yves Balasko

Whitney topology and spaces of preference relations. Abstract


Optimality Conditions for Nonsmooth Convex Optimization

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

First Welfare Theorem

Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

POLARS AND DUAL CONES

Advanced Microeconomics

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

On the existence of price equilibrium in economies with excess demand functions

Homework 4, 5, 6 Solutions. > 0, and so a n 0 = n + 1 n = ( n+1 n)( n+1+ n) 1 if n is odd 1/n if n is even diverges.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Mathematics II, course

When are Sums Closed?

2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013

Theorems. Theorem 1.11: Greatest-Lower-Bound Property. Theorem 1.20: The Archimedean property of. Theorem 1.21: -th Root of Real Numbers

Patryk Pagacz. Equilibrium theory in infinite dimensional Arrow-Debreu s model. Uniwersytet Jagielloński

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

On John type ellipsoids

Trading factors: Heckscher-Ohlin revisited

Lecture 7: General Equilibrium - Existence, Uniqueness, Stability

Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

18 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences

Competitive Markets with Externalities

HW 4 SOLUTIONS. , x + x x 1 ) 2

Elements of Convex Optimization Theory

Introduction to Topology

Strictly monotonic preferences on continuum of goods commodity spaces

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 8, 4/8/10

Economics 201B. Nonconvex Preferences and Approximate Equilibria

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

WORKING PAPER NO. 443

Trading factors: Heckscher-Ohlin revisited

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

A NICE PROOF OF FARKAS LEMMA

The existence of equilibrium in a simple exchange model

Topology, Math 581, Fall 2017 last updated: November 24, Topology 1, Math 581, Fall 2017: Notes and homework Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

A Characterization of Polyhedral Convex Sets

MATH 51H Section 4. October 16, Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous:

Topological properties

Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class

15 Real Analysis II Sequences and Limits , Math for Economists Fall 2004 Lecture Notes, 10/21/2004

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES

MICROECONOMIC THEORY I PROBLEM SET 1

On the survival and Irreductibility Assumptions for Financial Markets with Nominal Assets

Geometry and topology of continuous best and near best approximations

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

THE OBJECTIVE OF A PRIVATELY OWNED FIRM UNDER IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Jensen s inequality for multivariate medians

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

1 Directional Derivatives and Differentiability

Constructive Proof of the Fan-Glicksberg Fixed Point Theorem for Sequentially Locally Non-constant Multi-functions in a Locally Convex Space

Volume 31, Issue 3. Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis

Chapter 2: Preliminaries and elements of convex analysis

Maths 212: Homework Solutions

Transcription:

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess demand correspondence, which may have been derived from consumers with non-monotone preference relations. 1 Introduction We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess demand correspondence, which may have been derived from consumers with non-monotone preference relations. Several points are noteworthy on this theorem. First, the notion of an equilibrium price vector is an exact one, so that the demand is no more or no less than supply, and hence prices may be negative. Second, the set of prices on which the excess demands are well defined are convex and relatively open. This is a highly non-trivial assumption. Third, only a rather weak condition is imposed on the boundary behavior of the excess demand correspondence. 2 Definitions and Result Let L be a positive integer and w R L. Let be the Euclidean norm on R L and assume that w = 1. Define H = p R L p w = 1. The interpretation is that L is the number of commodities; w is the direction along which the utility levels of some group of consumers of strictly positive measure can be strictly increased; and H is the set of normalized price vectors. Theorem 1 Let P H and ζ : P R L be a correspondence satisfying the following properties. 1. P is a nonempty, convex, and open subset of H containing w. 2. ζ is nonempty-, convex-, and compact-valued and upper hemi-continuous. 3. ζ satisfies the strict Walras law, that is, p z = 0 for every p P and z ζ(p). 1

4. There exists a nonempty and compact subset V of P such that the set p P min max v z < 0 (1) is included in a compact subset of P. Then there exists a p P such that 0 ζ(p ). The first condition may appear to be standard. Note however that P may not be bounded, and that the convexity and openness are non-trivial conditions on the domain of the aggregate excess demand correspondence. The second condition needs no comment. In the third condition, the Walras law is in the strict form, so that we require the strict equality p z = 0 rather than the weak inequality p z 0. The maximum in (1) of the last condition is indeed attained because V is compact. The minimum is also attained because the function z max v V v z is continuous and ζ(p n ) is compact. Note that negative prices are allowed throughout this set of conditions. Proof of Theorem 1. The proof method is more or less the same as in Hüsseinov (1999). We assume throughout this section that P, ζ, and V satisfy the conditions of Theorem 1. Let P be a compact subset of P that includes p P min max v z < 0. Since P is relatively open in H and P V w is a compact subset of P, there exists a convex and compact subset Q of P such that the relative interior of Q with respect to H includes P V w. By Proposition 3 of Hildenbrand (1974, I.B), there exists a convex and compact subset Z of R L such that ζ(p) Z for every p Q. Following the construction of Debreu (1956), we can show that there exists a (p, z ) Q Z such that z ζ(p ) and p z p z (2) for every p Q. Suppose that there is no c R such that z = cw. Then the set argmax p Q p z is included in the relative boundary of Q with respect to H. In particular, p belongs to the relative boundary of Q with respect to H. Also, p z < p z = 0 for every p in the relative interior of Q with respect to H. Since V is included in the relative interior of Q with respect to H, this implies that max v V v z < 0 and hence p P. But since P is also in the relative interior of Q with respect to H, this implies that p is in the relative interior of Q with respect to H, which is a contradiction. Hence there exists a c R such that z = cw. By the strict Walras Law and p w = 1, if we take the inner products of both sides with p, then we obtain 0 = c. Hence z = 0 and 0 ζ(p ). /// Remark 1 While it is desirable to dispense with the assumption that P is relatively open and convex, it is impossible to do so entirely. There is an economy with a continuum of consumers 2

such that P is not relatively open, and in fact there is no equilibrium. For example, the aggregate (mean) excess demand function of Example 10 of Hara (2004) is well defined under a price vector p R 2 if and only if p 1 > 0 and p 2 0. In fact, then, it is a (single-valued) function given by ( ) p 2 ζ(p) = p 1, 1. Any candidate w for the application of the theorem must satisfy w 1 > 0 and w 2 0. But then p R 2 p 1 > 0, p 2 0, and p w = 1 is not relatively open, because its relative boundary contains (1/p 1, 0). This set could be relatively open if w = (0, 1), in which case it would be p R 2 p 1 > 0 and p 2 = 1. But this set does not contain any positive multiple of p = (1, 0). 3 Existence of a Numeraire Vector Recall that the vector w have two properties in the theorem. First, an equilibrium price vector, if any, is assumed to give a positive value to the commodity vector w. Second, if the price vector equals w, then the excess demands must be well defined. In the case of strongly monotone preference relations, w can be taken to be (1, 1,..., 1) and V can be taken to be the singleton w. Then the boundedness from below and the standard boundary behavior condition, z n as n, where z n ζ(p n ) and (p n ) n is an escaping sequence of strictly positive price vectors, implies Condition 4 of Theorem 1. For some cases of non-monotone preference relations, w may be taken to be w = (1, 0,..., 0) or even involving some negative coordinates. We now show that there is no essential loss of generality in normalizing prices so that some vector, under which the aggregate excess demand exists, serves as the numeraire. For this result, we need to be explicit on conditions for the consumers consumption sets and preference relations. Proposition 2 Suppose that the consumers consumption sets are R+ L and preference relations are complete, transitive, continuous, and globally non-satiated. Let P R L be the set of all price vectors under which the aggregate excess demands exist. If P is convex, then there exists a w P such that p w > 0 for every p P. Proof of Proposition 2. By the completeness, transitivity, and continuity, P R++. L Suppose that there exists a p P such that p, p P. Then, for every consumer a, there exists a utility maximizing consumption vector for each of the two budget sets, x R+ L p x p e(a) and x R+ L ( p) x ( p) e(a) = x R+ L p x p e(a). By transitivity, at least one of the two vectors is a utility-maximizing consumption vector on the entire R+. L But this contradicts the global non-satiation property. Hence if p P, then p P. 3

By homogeneity, P 0 is a cone. Since P is convex and includes R++, L P 0 is a closed and convex cone with a nonempty interior. Since, as proved in the last paragraph, p P for every p P, P 0 is a pointed cone, that is, it does not contain any line. Now denote by cl P the closure of P, then cl P is a closed convex cone with a nonempty interior. It need not be pointed, so we denote by M the largest linear subspace included in P and by N the orthogonal complement of M. Then cl P = M + (N cl P ) and N cl P is a pointed cone with a nonempty interior in N. By the separating hyperplane theorem being applied within N, there exists a w N such that p w > 0 for every p N cl P with p 0. Then let w N be the orthogonal projection of w onto N cl P. Then p w p w and hence p w > 0 for every p N cl P with p 0. Since N cl P is pointed, there exists a δ > 0 such that p w > δ for every p N cl P with p = 1. Thus there exists a w N, sufficiently close to w, such that w belongs to the interior of N cl P in N, and hence of N P by the convexity of P, and p w > δ/2 for every p N cl P with p = 1. Thus w P and p w > 0 for every p P. /// 4 Other Types of Boundary Behaviors The condition of the boundary behavior that we imposed in Theorem 1 is that there exist a nonempty and compact subset V of P such that the set p P min max v z < 0 is included in a compact subset of P. In this section we give two sufficient conditions for this one that are more along the lines of the existing literature. The result is the following. Proposition 3 If V is a nonempty and compact subset of P and the set is compact, then the set p P min max v z < 0 is compact as well. p P min max v z 0 This proposition follows immediately from the fact that p P min max v z < 0 is a subset of p P min max v z 0. The second sufficient condition for the boundary behavior of Theorem 1 is in terms of sequences of price vectors. Definition 4 Let P be a subset of H and let (p n ) n be an arbitrary sequence in P. Then (p n ) n is escaping in P if for every compact subset C of P there exist an N such that p n C for every n > N. According to this definition, the elements of an escaping sequence in P would eventually go outside any compact set. To give the idea of what escaping sequences are like, it would be helpful to give some preliminary results. Lemma 5 Let P be a subset of H and let (p n ) n be an arbitrary sequence in P. 4

1. If (p n ) n is divergent, that is, p n as n, then (p n ) n is escaping in P. 2. Suppose that (p n ) n converges to some p H (with respect to the topology of the entire H). Then (p n ) n is escaping in P if and only if p P. 3. Suppose that P is a bounded and open subset of H. Then (p n ) n is escaping if and only if all of its cluster points belong to the (relative) boundary of P. Proposition 6 If V is a non-empty and compact subset V of P and, for every escaping sequence (p n ) n in P, then the set p P lim sup n min max v z 0 min max v z > 0, (3) is compact. By this proposition and Proposition 3, we can conclude that the condition (3) is sufficient for the boundary condition of Theorem 1. Proof of Proposition 6. Denote by P the set p P min max v z 0 and let (p n ) n be a sequence in P. It suffices to show that (p n ) n has a subsequence convergent in P. For each n, let z n ζ(p n ) satisfy max v V v z n 0. If (p n ) n is an escaping sequence, then Condition 4 of Theorem 1 implies that min max v z > 0 for infinitely many n. But this contradicts the hypothesis that (p n) n is a sequence in P. Hence (p n ) n is not an escaping sequence. Thus, there exist a compact set C P and a subsequence (p kn ) n such that p kn C for every n. For each n, let z kn ζ(p kn ) satisfy max v V v z k n 0. Since ζ is convex- and compact-valued and upper hemi-continuous, by Theorem 1 of Hildenbrand (1974, I.B), there exists a subsequence ((p jn, z jn )) n of ((p kn, z kn )) n that converges to some (p, z) C R L with z ζ(p). Then max v V v z 0 and hence p P. This completes the proof. /// References [1] Gerard Debreu, 1956, Market equilibrium, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 42, 876 878. [2] Chiaki Hara, 2004, Existence of equilibria and core convergence in economies with bads, Cambridge Working Paper Series in Economics 0413. [3] Werner Hildenbrand, 1974, Core and Equilibria of a Large Economy, Princeton University Press. [4] Farhad Hüsseinov, 1999, Boundary behavior of excess demand and existence of equilibrium, Journal of Economic Theory, 87, 434 449. [5] Wilhelm Neuefeind, 1980, Notes on existence of equilibrium proofs and the boundary behavior of supply, Econometrica 48, 1831 1837. 5