Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Similar documents
In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Second Welfare Theorem

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

1 General Equilibrium

First Welfare Theorem

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

General Equilibrium with Production

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

4 Lecture Applications

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Notes on General Equilibrium

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Advanced Microeconomics

Microeconomics I. September, c Leopold Sögner

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Competitive Equilibrium

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Discussion Papers in Economics

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

3.2 THE FUNDAMENTAL WELFARE THEOREMS

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Lecture 7: General Equilibrium - Existence, Uniqueness, Stability

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Introductory Microeconomics

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1)

Preferences and Utility

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Market Failure: Externalities

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an exchange economy

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

Technology 1. that describes the (net) output of the L goods of the production process of the firm. By convention,

Public Goods and Private Goods

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Welfare Economics: Lecture 12

Note on social choice allocation in exchange economies with Cobb-Douglas preferences

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

General Equilibrium and Welfare

5.1 THE ROBINSON CRUSOE ECONOMY

Chapter 4: Production Theory

Adding Production to the Theory

5. Externalities and Public Goods

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Economics th April 2011

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

PhD Qualifier Examination

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Existence of Equilibria with a Tight Marginal Pricing Rule

Walrasian Equilibrium in an exchange economy

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand

PS4-Solution. Mehrdad Esfahani. Fall Arizona State University. Question 1 Question 2 Question 3 Question 4 Question 5

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Substitute Valuations, Auctions, and Equilibrium with Discrete Goods

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses

Transcription:

Microeconomics II MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Problem 1 Consider an economy 1 1, with one firm (or technology and one consumer (firm owner, as in the textbook (MWG section 15.C. The set of feasible consumption allocations is F := { x R 2 + : x i2 f ( L x1, x1 L } This set is nonempty (it contains x = (ω, 0, convex (it is the intersection of two convex sets, R 2 + and the lower contour set of a concave function over the domain [0, L], compact (0 x ( L, f( L, f is a continuous function. Define P x = { x R 2I + : u(x > u(x } where x is a Pareto efficient allocation relative to F, hence it is on the boundary of F (otherwise, it would contradict production efficiency, namely it would be that x has been obtained by picking a production pair in the interior of the production possibility set Y of this economy. P x, containing consumption bundles strictly preferred to x, is nonempty and convex; moreover, it does not intersect F. By the separating hyperplane theorem, there exists a c R and a vector p R 2 such that p x c for all x P x, and p x c for all x F. Since x belongs to the boundary of F, p x c = p x, for all x P x. Letting individual wealth be w := p x, the latest implies that x is expenditure minimizing at (p, w. Notice that if x = (x 1, x 2 =: ( L z, q are in P x, they are not in F; implying ( z, q is not an element of Y. Hence, given x = (x 1, x 2 =: ( L z, q, 1

2 p x p x for all x P x, is equivalent to p ( L z, q ( L z, q, or to p ( z, q ( z, q whenever ( z, q is not in Y. The latest establishes that ( z, q is profit maximizing at p: π(p = p ( z, q. Finally, we can check that indeed w is the sum of the endowment value and profits evaluated at p, w := p x = p 1 ( L z + p 2 q = p 1 L + p ( z, q = p 1 L + π(p Problem 2 Economy 2 by 1 1. Define the set of feasible allocations, A, the set of consumption-feasible allocations, F. For I = 2, ω is the aggregate endowments vector. (z, y > 0, f( = { A := (x, (z, y R 2I + R 2 + : i x i2 y + ω 2, y f(z, i x i1 ω 1 z } F := { x R 2I + : i x i2 f ( ω 1 i x i1 + ω 2, i x i1 ω 1 } 2. The picture of the set F is drawn using X to denote aggregate consumption, and ω to denote aggregate endowments. 3. The set of Pareto efficient allocations is, O := {x F : u i (x u i (x all i, u h (x > u h (x some h, only if x not in F} At an efficient allocation, the corresponding individual MRS s equalize and are equal to the MRT. By contradiction, suppose that at an efficient allocation, there exists a commodity pari (x 1, x 2 and some i such that the corresponding marginal rats differ, say MRS i > MRT. Then, two are the interesting cases: i agents have equalized MRSs but these are above MRT, ii for some agents i, j, MRS i > MRS j = MRT. Case ii we know is incompatible with

3 X 2 f(ω 1 + ω 2 f(ω 1 -X 1 F ω 1 X 1 Figure 1: The upper envelope of F identifies production efficient bundles of aggregate consumption. Pareto efficiency; this would define a failure of efficiency in the distribution of the resources available for consumption. Case i denotes an inefficiency in the way production is organized; precisely (on a plane (x 1, x 2, MRS > MRT with MRS i = MRS for all i, detects an overproduction of 2 (and an underproduction of 1 relative to the efficient level. Indeed, even if the allocation proposed does not waste resources (i.e. it is on the frontier of the economy production possibility set, a different choice is feasible and welfare improving. To see this, notice that to have an extra marginal unit of good 1 each consumer is willing to give up MRS units of good 2; to produce an extra unit of good 1 (in an productive efficient way it is required to give up only MRT of good 2. Thus we can take out from a consumer only MRT < MRS of 2 and give him an extra marginal unit of 1, making him better-off, without affecting the others. This contradicts the assert that the initial allocation was Pareto efficient. Clearly, in an economy with J > 1, the above changes of output may also correspond to a reallocation of factors of productions among different technologies/firms j, not only to different sectors. 4. An economy is an element of Ξ := I = L = 2, J = 1. Let p 1 = 1, and p := p 2. ( {u i, X i, ω i, θ i } I i=1, {Y j} J j=1, where

4 A competitive equilibrium of an economy ξ in Ξ is a price p > 0 such that (x i1 (p ω i1 z(p = 0 i=1,2 This is a Cobb-Douglas economy. Individual demand is x i1 (p, w i = αw i, where w i = w i (p := p ω i + π(pθ i. x i2 (p, w i = (1 α w i p To recover individual wealth at p, solve the firm s optimal problem. π(p = max z>0 p z z to find y(p = p/2, z(p = (p/2 2 and π(p = (p/2 2. Compute (w i i : w 1 (p = 1 + π(p/2 = 1 + (1/8p 2, w 1 (p = p + π(p/2 = p + (1/8p 2. Compute the aggregate demand of good 1: i x i1(p, w i = α i w i x i1 (p, w i = α (1 + p + 14 p2 Impose market clearing: Yielding, i i=1,2 ( p 2 (x i1 (p 1 = 0 2 ( α 4 + 1 p 2 + αp + α 1 = 0 4 For α = 2/3, the latter polynomial has a single positive root, p =.4. By substitution in the above demand and supply functions, you can recover the equilibrium allocation: x 1 = (0.68, 0.28, x 2 = (0.85, 0.35, y = 1.2, z = 1.44. The preference parameter α = 2/3 reveals both consumers have a stronger taste for good 1. In equilibrium, the technology is used to reduce the aggregate consumption of good 2 and increase that of good 1, with respect to the initial aggregate endowment of (1, 1. This is supported by a price p = p 2 /p 1 =.4 < 1.

5 Problem 3 1. U is convex if utilities are strictly-quasi concave. Let X i be convex, u i : X i R, the function u i is concave iff for any x, x X, u i (x θ θu i (x+ (1 θu i (x for any θ [0, 1], where x θ := θx+(1 θx. Suppose this holds for all individuals i, and assume (x, y, (x, y are two feasible allocations, in A. For every i define x i,θ := θx i + (1 θx i, and define y θ in the same way. The new allocation (x θ, y θ is in A, by the convexity of the latest set. U(x θ = (..., u i (x i,θ,... (..., θu i (x i + (1 θu i (x i,... = θ (..., u i (x i,... + (1 θ (..., u i (x i,... = θu(x + (1 θu(x 2. Take utilities which are quasi-concave but not strictly-quasi concave. For example, X i = R + for all i = 1, 2 { x 0.5 u i (x i = i : if x i > 1 x i : if 0 x i 1 Letting ω = 2 be the total resources of x, the Pareto frontier is a curve intersecting the vertical axis (u 2 in 2, with graph { 2 u1 for 0 u 1 1 u 2 = 2 (u 1 2 for u 1 > 1 The upper envelope of the following graph is a non-concave Pareto frontier.

Figure 2: Non-concave Pareto frontier 6