A NetLogo Model for the Study of the Evolution of Cooperation in Social Networks

Similar documents
Epidemic spreading and cooperation dynamics on homogeneous small-world networks

Emergence of Cooperation in Heterogeneous Structured Populations

A new route to the evolution of cooperation

Research Article Snowdrift Game on Topologically Alterable Complex Networks

Dynamics and Chaos. Melanie Mitchell. Santa Fe Institute and Portland State University

Evolutionary prisoner s dilemma game on hierarchical lattices

Evolutionary games on complex network

Networks and sciences: The story of the small-world

Complex networks and evolutionary games

Damon Centola.

VII. Cooperation & Competition

Instability in Spatial Evolutionary Games

MATCHING STRUCTURE AND THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION IN THE PRISONER S DILEMMA

Meaning, Evolution and the Structure of Society

Evolution of Cooperation in Continuous Prisoner s Dilemma Games on Barabasi Albert Networks with Degree-Dependent Guilt Mechanism

Evolutionary Games on Networks. Wen-Xu Wang and G Ron Chen Center for Chaos and Complex Networks

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 12: Generalized Random Graphs

evolutionary dynamics of collective action

Application of Evolutionary Game theory to Social Networks: A Survey

Evolution of cooperation. Martin Nowak, Harvard University

Complexity in social dynamics : from the. micro to the macro. Lecture 4. Franco Bagnoli. Lecture 4. Namur 7-18/4/2008

Evolutionary Game Theory and Frequency Dependent Selection

Psychology 4590 Evolutionary Psychology Spring, 2004

Evolution of Diversity and Cooperation 2 / 3. Jorge M. Pacheco. Departamento de Matemática & Aplicações Universidade do Minho Portugal

arxiv:q-bio/ v1 [q-bio.pe] 24 May 2004

Graph topology and the evolution of cooperation

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 9 Jun 2006

Alana Schick , ISCI 330 Apr. 12, The Evolution of Cooperation: Putting gtheory to the Test

Understanding and Solving Societal Problems with Modeling and Simulation

EVOLUTIONARY GAMES WITH GROUP SELECTION

The Evolution of Cooperation in Self-Interested Agent Societies: A Critical Study

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 27 May 2016

Asymmetric cost in snowdrift game on scale-free networks

Self-organized scale-free networks

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 7 Aug 2012

On the evolution of reciprocal cooperation

Evolution of Cooperation in Evolutionary Games for Heterogeneous Interactions

Policing and group cohesion when resources vary

Repeated Games and Direct Reciprocity Under Active Linking

Evolving network with different edges

Communities and Populations

ABSTRACT: Dissolving the evolutionary puzzle of human cooperation.

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

Replicator Dynamics of Co Evolving Networks

Sociobiological Approaches. What We Will Cover in This Section. Overview. Overview Evolutionary Theory Sociobiology Summary

Anthropology 562: Introduction to Evolutionary Anthropology

CENTRAL OR POLARIZED PATTERNS IN COLLECTIVE ACTIONS

Reciprocity in evolving social networks

CRITICAL BEHAVIOR IN AN EVOLUTIONARY ULTIMATUM GAME WITH SOCIAL STRUCTURE

Emergence of Cooperation and Evolutionary Stability in Finite Populations

Evolutionary Game Theory

Behavior of Collective Cooperation Yielded by Two Update Rules in Social Dilemmas: Combining Fermi and Moran Rules

Anthro 101: Human Biological Evolution. Lecture 11: Cooperation, Intelligence, Communication, Culture, & Human Behavior. Prof.

Living in groups 1. What are three costs and three benefits of living in groups?

Topic 7: Evolution. 1. The graph below represents the populations of two different species in an ecosystem over a period of several years.

arxiv: v1 [q-bio.pe] 20 Feb 2008

Globalization-polarization transition, cultural drift, co-evolution and group formation

Cooperation Achieved by Migration and Evolution in a Multilevel Selection Context

The Evolution of Mind and Morality: 19th-21st Centuries. Winter, 2007

AIS 2016 AIS 2014 AIS 2015

Evolutionary Bargaining Strategies

Network Science (overview, part 1)

Dynamic-persistence of cooperation in public good games when group size is dynamic

Genetic stability and territorial structure facilitate the evolution of. tag-mediated altruism. Lee Spector a and Jon Klein a,b

THE EMERGENCE AND EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS

Opinion Dynamics on Triad Scale Free Network

Université Libre de Bruxelles

Collective Evolution of Turn-taking Norm in Dispersion Games

Random Boolean Networks and Evolutionary Game Theory

Lindsell, E. A. B., & Wiesner, K. (2014). Entanglement gives rise to Pareto optimality in the generalised quantum Hawk-Dove Game. arxiv.

Cultural Dissemination using a Quantum Model

1989 Human Behavior and Evolution Society

Resource heterogeneity can facilitate cooperation

Phase transitions in social networks

[in press, July, 2006: In W. A. Darity (Ed.), International Encyclopedia of Social Sciences (2 nd ed.). New. Genetic Determinism

Evolution of a social network: The role of cultural diversity

Spatial three-player prisoners dilemma

Group Formation: Fragmentation Transitions in Network Coevolution Dynamics

Dynamic Models of Segregation in Small-World Networks

Kalle Parvinen. Department of Mathematics FIN University of Turku, Finland

Growing a Network on a Given Substrate

Costly Signals and Cooperation

Numerical Study of Game Theory

Evolution of motivations and behavioral responses! Integrating the proximate and ultimate causes of behavior!

Scale-invariant behavior in a spatial game of prisoners dilemma

Evolution of cooperation in adaptive social networks

Lecture VI Introduction to complex networks. Santo Fortunato

Complex Systems Theory and Evolution

Physica A. Promoting cooperation by local contribution under stochastic win-stay-lose-shift mechanism

The Paradox of Cooperation Benets

Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462)

Topology-independent impact of noise on cooperation in spatial public goods games

Defensive Environmentalists and the Dynamics of Global Reform By Thomas K. Rudel

Evolutionary Games and Computer Simulations

Deterministic scale-free networks

Diversity-optimized cooperation on complex networks

arxiv: v4 [cs.dm] 20 Nov 2017

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 18 Dec 2007

Decision Making and Social Networks

6. Evolu)on, Co- evolu)on (and Ar)ficial Life) Part 1

Transcription:

A NetLogo Model for the Study of the Evolution of Cooperation in Social Networks Gregory Todd Jones Georgia State University College of Law Interuniversity Consortium on Negotiation and Conflict Resolution Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods gtjones@gsu.edu Abstract Cooperation has played a key role in the evolution of various species, from single-celled organisms without any cognitive capacity whatsoever, to diverse species of birds and fish, from non-human primates such as chimpanzees and capuchin monkeys to humans, where the role of cooperation may have been most evolutionarily significant. Arriving at a coherent understanding of how cooperation can evolve in the face of self-regarding agents remains one of the most formidable challenges to those that study the management of conflict. At the same time, the study of network theory, complex systems, and nonlinear dynamics has pervaded all of science. Indeed, E. O. Wilson, who once characterized the evolution of cooperation as one of the greatest challenges for modern biology, more recently made a more emphatic appeal for research on complex systems. And yet, remarkably little work has been done that investigates the evolution of cooperation using network theory and the tools of complex systems analysis. Our work seeks to make contributions at the intersection of these two important areas of study. Contact: Gregory Todd Jones Interuniversity Consortium on Negotiation and Conflict Resolution Georgia State University College of Law Atlanta, GA 30303 Tel: 404-651-2377 Fax: 404-463-9789 Email: gtjones@gsu.edu Key Words: Cooperation; Reciprocity; Social Networks; Heterogeneity; NetLogo

A NetLogo Model for the Study of the Evolution of Cooperation in Social Networks Gregory Todd Jones C ooperation has played a key role in the evolution of various species, from single-celled organisms without any cognitive capacity whatsoever, to diverse species of birds and fish, from non-human primates such as chimpanzees and capuchin monkeys to humans, where the role of cooperation may have been most evolutionarily significant (Hammerstein, 2003). And yet arriving at a coherent understanding of how cooperation can evolve in the face of self-regarding agents remains one of the most formidable challenges to those that study the management of conflict. At the same time, the study of network theory, complex systems, and nonlinear dynamics has pervaded all of science. We personally feel the consequences of the power of networks, (Strogatz, 2001) as in 1996 when two faulty power lines in Oregon brought about wide-spread blackouts in 11 US states and two Canadian provinces, in 2000 when the Love Bug worm spread through the Internet causing billions of dollars of damage worldwide, and in 2001 when 19 terrorists who were part of the al-qaeda network hijacked four commercial passenger jet airliners and used them to bring down the twin towers of the World Trade Center and seriously damage the Pentagon, killing nearly three thousand people. Indeed, E. O. Wilson, who once characterized the evolution of cooperation as one of the greatest challenges for modern biology (Wilson, 2000), more recently made a more emphatic appeal for research on complex systems. The greatest challenge today, not just in cell biology and ecology, but in all of science, is the accurate and complete description of complex systems. Scientists have broken down many kinds of systems. They think they know most of the elements and forces. The next task is to reassemble them, at least in mathematical models that capture the key properties of the entire ensembles. (Wilson, 1998, p. 85). (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) Figure 1 Schematic illustration of various network architectures, all with 25 nodes, roughly in ascending order of heterogeneity. (a) Fully connected network. (b) Ring lattice with all nodes connected to its neighbors out to some range k (here k = 3). (c) Small world network starting with ring lattice and adding shortcut links between random pairs of nodes. (d) Random network constructed with connection probability, p =.15. (e) Scale-free network constructed by attaching nodes at random to previously existing nodes, where the probability of attachment is proportional to the degree (connectedness) of the target node, i.e., the rich get richer.

And yet, remarkably little work has been done that investigates the evolution of cooperation using network theory and the tools of complex systems analysis. Our work seeks to make contributions at the intersection of these two important areas of study. The Predictions of Evolutionary Game Theory Scholars from fields as diverse as anthropology, biology, sociology, ecology, economics, management, psychology, political science, law, mathematics and physics frequently rely on evolutionary game theory as a common mathematical framework for investigations into the evolution of cooperation (Santos, Rodriguez & Pacheco, 2005; Maynard-Smith, 1982; Gintis, 2000). Quite often, the prisoners dilemma (PD) (Axelrod & Hamilton, 1981) is employed as a model of cooperation between individuals in circumstances where individual interests conflict with those of the group. Axelrod s original simulations (Axelrod, 1984) posed all agents against all others (and thus corresponded to mean field approximations) without the evolutionary dynamics that would have made his results more universally applicable. In fact, it was subsequently shown that in well-mixed populations, replicator dynamics result in domination by defectors (Gintis, 2000), as is predicted by the Nash equilibrium in the game. Correlated association (Skyrms, 1996), where agents have a higher probability of interacting with similar agents, offers more hope for the survival of cooperation. One way in which this association is possible is when the games take place in spatially structured populations that limit the possibilities of interaction (Nowak & May, 1992). Figure 2 Reciprocity Emerging. Random network of 200 agents constructed with connection probability, p =.01. Agents are sized proportional to degree. After 5 generations of 10 PD games with deterministic imitation, reciprocating strategies (yellow agents) are emerging towards population dominance. Structured populations have been investigated on rings and regular lattices as well as more complex network architectures (Figure 1), however, most of the work that has considered the effects of these network dynamics has been limited to simple, single-round PD games where agents employ one of only two strategies cooperation or defection (Nowak & May, 1992; Nowak, Bonhoeffer & May, 1994; Pakdaman & Mestivier, 2001; Vainstein & Arenzon, 2001; Holme, Trusina, Kim &

Minnhagen, 2003; Pacheco & Santos, 2005; Duran & Mulet, 2005; Santos & Pachecco, 2005). As one-shot games, there is no chance of two agents facing each other again, no need for memory of previous interactions, and no opportunity for reciprocity. The Evolution of Social Structure Modern living affords present day humans a bounty of benefits that reduce morbidity and mortality, offer comforts that would seem astonishing to most of our ancestors, and all but eliminate the threats of most predators (Buss, 2000). Along with these benefits, however, have emerged discrepancies between modern and ancestral environments that may present us with a variety of unanticipated ills. Humans evolved in small groups, consisting of approximately 150 individuals (Dunbar, 1993) largely made up of extended kin networks. There is mounting evidence that social networks in this environment of evolutionary adaptedness (EEA) (Bowlby, 1969) were largely egalitarian (Kanazawa, 2001) with a structure that would most closely approximate a homogeneous regular lattice (Figure 1) with a characteristic single-peak degree distribution (Santos & Pacheco, 2006). On the other hand, evidence also suggests that many natural, social, and technological networks analyzed today are more heterogeneous exhibiting multi-peaked degree distributions (Santos & Pacheco, 2006; Barabasi & Albert, 1999; Amaral, Scala, Figure 3 A Modern Network. Scale-free network of 500 agents. After 5 generations of 10 PD games with deterministic imitation, niches of various strategies, including reciprocators (yellow agents), survive in equilibrium, but defectors (red agents) dominate from the most highly connected hub. Barthelelemy & Stanley, 2000; Albert & Barabasi, 2002; Dorogotsev & Mendes, 2003). Much of social structure is determined to conform to either small world networks (Watts & Strogatz, 1998; Figure 1) or scale-free networks (Barabasi & Albert, 1999; Figures 1 & 3). It appears that the characteristic social structure of humans has changed significantly in the 10,000 years since the Pleistocene epoch (the EEA). And given that the human brain, and its associated psychological mechanisms adapted to the EEA, has not changed much during the same time frame, it may be that cooperation and conflict behaviors in the current environment are maladaptive (Kanazawa, 2001).

Reciprocity in Social Networks In this work, we demonstrate a NetLogo (Wilensky, 1999) model developed to expand upon the investigations of network dynamics in the simple PD game by studying the repeated game with memory, giving rise to the possibility of reciprocity. Fully connected networks (Figure 1a) provide the baseline case in which the dominance of defection characteristic of mean field simulations is not surprising. Ring lattices (Figure 1b) provide prototypical homogeneous spatial structure. Small world networks (Figure 1c) and scale-free networks (Figures 1e & 3) provide variants of heterogeneous spatial structure. Random networks (Figures 1d & 2) provide controllable, intermediate levels of heterogeneity. References Albert R. & Barabasi, A. L. Statistical Mechanics of Complex Networks. Review of Modern Physics 74, 47-97 (2002). Amaral, L. A. N., Scala, A., Barthelelemy, M. & Stanley, H. E. Classes of Small-World Networks. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 97, 11149-11152 (2000). Axelrod, R. & Hamilton, W. D. The Evolution of Cooperation. Science 211, 1390 (1981). Axelrod, R. The Evolution of Cooperation (Basic Books, New York, NY, 1984). Barabasi, A. L. & Albert, R. Emergence of Scaling in Random Networks. Science 286, 509-512 (1999). Bowlby, J. Attachment and Loss (Basic Books, New York, NY, 1969). Buss, D. M. The Evolution of Happiness. American Psychologist 55, 15-23 (2000). Dorogotsev, S. N. & Mendes, J. F. F. Evolution of Networks: From Biological Nets to the Internet and WWW (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2003). Dunbar, R. I. M. Coevolution of Neocortical Size, Group Size, and Language in Humans. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16, 681-735 (1993). Duran, O. & Mulet, R. Evolutionary Prisoners Dilemma in Random Graphs. Physica D 208, 257-265 (2005). Gintis, H. Game Theory Evolving (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2000). Hammerstein, P. Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2003). Holme, P., Trusina, A., Kim, B. J. & Minnhagen, P. Prisoners Dilemma in Real-World Acquaintance Networks: Spikes and Quasiequilibria Induced by the Interplay between Structure and Dynamics. Physical Review E 68, 030901 (2003).

Kanazawa, S. Where Do Social Structures Come From? Advances in Group Processes 18, 161-183 (2001). Maynard-Smith, J. Evolution and the Theory of Games (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 1982). Nowak, M & May, R. M. Evolutionary Games and Spatial Chaos. Nature 359, 826-829 (1992). Nowak, M. A., Bonhoffer, S., May, R. M. Spatial Games and the Maintenance of Cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 91, 4877-4881 (1994). Pacheco, J. M. & Santos, F. C. Network Dependence of the Dilemmas of Cooperation in Science of Complex Networks: From Biology to the Internet and WWW, edited by J. F. F. Mendes (AIP, Melville, NY, 2005). Pakdaman, K. & Mestivier, D. External Noise Synchronizes Forced Oscillators. Physical Review E 64, 030901 (2001). Santos, F. C., Rodrigues, J. F. & Pacheco, J. M. Graph Topology Plays a Determinate Role in the Evolution of Cooperation. Proceedings of the Royal Society B (published online 2005). Santos, F. C. & Pacheco, J. M. Scale-Free Networks Provide a Unifying Framework for the Emergence of Cooperation. Physical Review Letters 95, 098104 (2005). Santos, F. C. & Pacheco, J. M. A New Route to the Evolution of Cooperation. Journal of Evolutionary Biology 19, 726-733 (2006). Skyrms, B. Evolution of the Social Contract (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 1996). Strogatz, S. H. Exploring Complex Networks. Nature 410, 268-276 (2001). Vainstein, M. H. & Arenzon, J. J. Disordered Environments in Spatial Games. Physical Review E 64, 051905 (2001). Watts, D. & Strogatz, S. H. Collective Dynamics of 'Small-World' Networks. Nature 393, 440-442 (1998). Wilensky, U. NetLogo. http://ccl.northwestern.edu/netlogo. Center for Connected Learning and Computer-Based Modeling. Northwestern University, Evanston, IL (1999). Wilson, E. O. Consilience (Knopf, New York, 1998). Wilson, E. O. Sociobiology: The New Synthesis, Twenty-fifth Anniversary Edition (Belknap Press, New York, 2000).