MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. January 25, 2012

Similar documents
MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015

Bayesian Optimization

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 18, 2015

Optimizing allocations

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson.

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. September 7, 2011

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I

Modern Portfolio Theory with Homogeneous Risk Measures

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION

Dependence. MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. September 11, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline.

Dependence. Practitioner Course: Portfolio Optimization. John Dodson. September 10, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline.

Optimal Investment Strategies: A Constrained Optimization Approach

Attilio Meucci. Issues in Quantitative Portfolio Management: Handling Estimation Risk

Market Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitiative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 8, Market Risk. John Dodson.

Introduction to Computational Finance and Financial Econometrics Probability Theory Review: Part 2

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 3, 2010

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 17: Fortune s Formulas

Duality Methods in Portfolio Allocation with Transaction Constraints and Uncertainty

Better than Dynamic Mean-Variance Policy in Market with ALL Risky Assets

January 29, Introduction to optimization and complexity. Outline. Introduction. Problem formulation. Convexity reminder. Optimality Conditions

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. January 28, 2015

FIN 550 Practice Exam Answers. A. Linear programs typically have interior solutions.

Evaluating allocations

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Introduction & Random Variables. John Dodson. September 3, 2008

Z = (X Loc X) (DisSq X) 1 (X Loc X).

Stochastic Programming Math Review and MultiPeriod Models

Randomized Coordinate Descent Methods on Optimization Problems with Linearly Coupled Constraints

Review of Optimization Methods

Markowitz Efficient Portfolio Frontier as Least-Norm Analytic Solution to Underdetermined Equations

Lagrange duality. The Lagrangian. We consider an optimization program of the form

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Lagrangian Duality. Richard Lusby. Department of Management Engineering Technical University of Denmark

Econ 424 Review of Matrix Algebra

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage

Robust Efficient Frontier Analysis with a Separable Uncertainty Model

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Introduction Eigen Values and Eigen Vectors An Application Matrix Calculus Optimal Portfolio. Portfolios. Christopher Ting.

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 2

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Multivariate Distributions

Professional Portfolio Selection Techniques: From Markowitz to Innovative Engineering

Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions

Robustness in Stochastic Programs with Risk Constraints

University of Bergen. The index tracking problem with a limit on portfolio size

FIN 550 Exam answers. A. Every unconstrained problem has at least one interior solution.

The Dual of the Maximum Likelihood Method

MOSEK Modeling Cookbook Release 3.0. MOSEK ApS

Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency

Robust Markowitz portfolio selection. ambiguous covariance matrix

Lagrange Relaxation and Duality

Robustness and bootstrap techniques in portfolio efficiency tests

A Minimax Theorem with Applications to Machine Learning, Signal Processing, and Finance

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Combinatorial Data Mining Method for Multi-Portfolio Stochastic Asset Allocation

Discussion Papers in Economics

Multivariate Stress Scenarios and Solvency

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Handout 1: Introduction to Dynamic Programming. 1 Dynamic Programming: Introduction and Examples

Lecture 8 Plus properties, merit functions and gap functions. September 28, 2008

Lagrangian Duality. Evelien van der Hurk. DTU Management Engineering

Robust Optimization: Applications in Portfolio Selection Problems

15.S24 Sample Exam Solutions

CAUSAL MODELING WITH APPLICATIONS TO THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET. A Dissertation BRIAN DAVID DEATON

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

J. Marín-Solano (UB), M. Bosch-Príncep (UB), J. Dhaene (KUL), C. Ribas (UB), O. Roch (UB), S. Vanduffel (KUL)

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Convex optimization problems. Optimization problem in standard form

Lagrange Duality. Daniel P. Palomar. Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST)

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Constrained Optimization and Lagrangian Duality

Miloš Kopa. Decision problems with stochastic dominance constraints

Measuring the informativeness of economic actions and. market prices 1. Philip Bond, University of Washington. September 2014

Existence of Equilibrium and Zero-Beta Pricing Formula in the Capital Asset Pricing Model with Heterogeneous Beliefs *

Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

4. Convex optimization problems

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

FINM6900 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets

Empirical properties of large covariance matrices in finance

Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS

Robust Growth-Optimal Portfolios

A SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY MEASURE

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Mechanics of linear quadratic Gaussian rational. inattention tracking problems

IE 5531: Engineering Optimization I

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Regression: Ordinary Least Squares

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Time Series Models for Measuring Market Risk

Solutions and Proofs: Optimizing Portfolios

Support Vector Machines

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Appendix - E-Companion

Transcription:

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation January 25, 2012

Optimizing Allocations Once we have 1. chosen the markets and an investment horizon 2. modeled the markets 3. agreed on an objective with the client 4. designed an index of satisfaction We are almost ready to determine the optimal portfolio The last item we need to consider before proceeding with the mechanical exercise of optimization is the domain of possible allocations, C Wealth Constraint One constraint that almost always applies is the wealth constraint C = {α p T α = w T } for given initial wealth w T.

Secondary In addition to or instead of the wealth constraint, other constraints may be relevant transactions costs exogenous risk measures and limits prohibition against short positions Each binding constraint has a corresponding shadow cost reflecting the fact that the otherwise unconstrained optimal portfolio is not feasible. Professional investment management is largely about managing constraints. N.B.: The form and complexity of the constraints determines the form and complexity of the optimization techniques required.

Problem The optimal portfolio, if it exists, is defined by α = arg max α C S(α) Constrained optimization in general is a hard problem. There are several classes that are more tractable. Convex Programming If the objective Q is convex, and the constraints can be represented by the intersection of sets L = {z Az = a} and V = {z F (z) 0} for convex F ( ), the problem arg min z L V Q(z) has a solution, although it may be difficult or expensive to determine. This is another reason we should choose an index of satisfaction that is concave.

If the index of satisfaction is consistent with stochastic dominance, we may be able to replace the original hard problem with two simpler problems. Stochastic Dominance An allocation α is said to weakly dominate an allocation β if F Ψα (ψ) F Ψβ (ψ) ψ in support and an index of satisfaction is consistent with weak stochastic dominance if S(α) S(β). value-at-risk and expected shortfall are both consistent with weak stochastic dominance In particular, if Sd Ψ α = Sd Ψ β but E Ψ α > E Ψ β then S(α) > S(β)

Two-Step Procedure As long as the index of satisfaction is consistent with weak stochastic dominance, we can exclude from consideration in the search for the optimal portfolio any portfolio that is not on the efficient frontier, defined by 1. α (v) = arg max α C E Ψ α var Ψ α v The optimal portfolio is therefore the solution to a one-dimensional unconstrained problem, 2. v = arg max v S (α (v)) which can be found numerically, viz. α = α (v ). This framework presents an enormous computational improvement, and justifies choosing an index of satisfaction that is consistent with weak stochastic dominance.

For a single, affine constraint, such as the wealth constraint, the efficient frontier can be derived analytically. First we introduce the dual problem αdual (e) = arg min d α=c α E M e α (cov M) α The constraints can be handled by introducing two (scalar) Lagrange multipliers, λ and µ. min α,λ,µ α (cov M) α λ ( α d c ) µ ( α E M e ) Any solution to this for c > 0 (see Appendix 6.3) can be expressed as a linear combination of two portfolios, α SR = c (cov M) 1 E M d (cov M) 1 E M α MV = c (cov M) 1 d d (cov M) 1 d

The efficient frontier consists of all portfolios α MV + β (α SR α MV ) β 0 N.B.: These portfolios are orthogonal, in the sense that cov (Ψ αsr Ψ αmv, Ψ αmv ) = 0 Sharpe Ratio Portfolio The portfolio α SR is the unique portfolio that maximizes the Sharpe Ratio. α SR = arg max d α=c E Ψ α Sd Ψ α Minimum Variance Portfolio The portfolio α MV is the globally minimum variance portfolio within the feasible set. If there is an investment that is risk-free relative to the objective, e.g. cash or a benchmark-neutral allocation, then it will consist of this.

The first step of the two-step procedure requires the mean and covariance of the market vector, regardless of the form of the index of satisfaction. Therefore, let us review these quantities for the standard log-normal model P T +τ = p T e X with X N (µ, Σ) where the exponentiation and is component-wise. Recalling that φ X (t) = e iµ t 1 2 t Σt, we can get Mean E P T +τ = p T e µ+ 1 2 diag Σ Covariance cov P T +τ = (E P T +τ ) (E P T +τ ) (e Σ 11 )

The efficient frontier depends in a non-trivial way upon the investment horizon, τ. Say you had a model for the invariants X N (µ, Σ) based on a sampling period of τ, but you were interested in a different investment horizon τ. We know that X is additive, while e X is not. In particular, µ+ 1 2 diag Σ E P T + τ = p T e τ τ cov P T + τ = (E P T + τ ) (E P T + τ ) (e τ τ Σ 11 ) which leads to a different solutions for α SR and maybe α MV. This is not apparent in the traditional analysis in terms of continuous returns and underscores the importance of choosing an appropriate investment horizon.

When the investor s objective is relative, the wealth constraint is of the form d α = 0. In this case, the minimum variance portfolio is trivial, α MV = 0; but the solution for the maximum Sharpe Ratio portfolio fails (since c = 0). In place, we can use α SR = (cov M) 1 ( ) d (cov M) 1 d E M d (cov M) 1 (E M) d and all efficient portfolios have the same Sharpe Ratio (termed the Information Ratio in the relative setting). Implied Benchmark The efficient frontier for the absolute objective is the same as the efficient frontier for the objective relative to the global minimum-variance portfolio α MV.