In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Similar documents
Practice Problems 2 (Ozan Eksi) ( 1 + r )i E t y t+i + (1 + r)a t

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Topic 6: Consumption, Income, and Saving

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Lecture 3: Dynamics of small open economies

Problem 1 (30 points)

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 3

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Advanced Macroeconomics

Problem Set # 2 Dynamic Part - Math Camp

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Concave Consumption Function and Precautionary Wealth Accumulation. Richard M. H. Suen University of Connecticut. Working Paper November 2011

Online Appendix for Precautionary Saving of Chinese and US Households

The marginal propensity to consume and multidimensional risk

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

1 Uncertainty. These notes correspond to chapter 2 of Jehle and Reny.

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Development Economics (PhD) Intertemporal Utility Maximiza

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

Macroeconomics Theory II

MSC Macroeconomics G022, 2009

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

1 Uncertainty and Insurance

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Lecture 1: Introduction

An approximate consumption function

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita.

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Dynamic Problem Set 1 Solutions

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Neoclassical Growth Model / Cake Eating Problem

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

The Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 21: Stochastic Dynamic Programming and Applications

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

The Real Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 2 - Solution

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Using Theory to Identify Transitory and Permanent Income Shocks: A Review of the Blundell-Preston Approach

Lecture 6: Recursive Preferences

1 The social planner problem

Advanced Macroeconomics

Economics 2010c: Lecture 3 The Classical Consumption Model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 2

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II)

Lecture 8. Applications of consumer theory. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: April 27, 2017

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Econ 504, Lecture 1: Transversality and Stochastic Lagrange Multipliers

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Incomplete Markets, Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Dynamics

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Recitation 7: Uncertainty. Xincheng Qiu

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

The Cake-Eating problem: Non-linear sharing rules

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Modern Macroeconomics II

1 The Basic RBC Model

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801

Caballero Meets Bewley: The Permanent-Income Hypothesis in General Equilibrium

Aiyagari-Bewley-Hugget-Imrohoroglu Economies

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Transcription:

PERMANENT INCOME AND OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION On the previous notes we saw how permanent income hypothesis can solve the Consumption Puzzle. Now we use this hypothesis, together with assumption of rational expectations, to analyze the optimal consumption decision of people A note In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = 1R u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now 0 We assume the population size is constant, i.e. n = 0 In this section we use discrete time and uncertainty for future, and try to maximize P U t = E t [ 1 1 ( 1 + )i u(c t+i )] i=0 When is small, e t can be written as (1 ). And this can approximated also by 1=(1 + ) (you can use = 0:02 to see this) 1

If there is an uncertainty for the state of the nature in the future, and if consumers faces an intertemporal budget constraint, they need to make some forecasts for the future states (for example for their future incomes, y t+i ). Rational-expectations assumption states that people use all available information to make optimal forecasts about the future. E t stands for this assumption There is also Adaptive Expectations, according to which people form their expectations about the future based on what has happened in the past c e t+1 = c e t + '(c t c e t) 2

Consumer Problem For i = 0; 1; 2; :::; 1, consumers maximize the utility function max c t+i P U t = E t [ 1 1 ( 1 + )i u(c t+i )] (1) i=0 subject to the series of budget constraints A t+i+1 = (1 + r)a t+i + y t+i c t+i (2) and the restriction that consumer s debt cannot grow at a rate greater than the nancial return r (No-Ponzi Game Condition) lim ( 1 i!1 1 + r )i A t+i 0 (3) Optimizing consumers do not leave positive assets when time goes to in nity. As a result, in the solution of the problem, equation (3) holds with strict equality (Transversality Condition) 3

Note: In the continuous time version of this problem we used Hamiltonian to solve it. In this discrete time case, we can either insert equation (2) inside equation (1) for c t+i, or constraint equation (1) with an equation obtained by combining series of budget constraints (2) and use the Lagrangian: I follow the 1st option Inserting equation (2) into equation (1) max U P t = E t [ 1 1 ( A t+i ; i=1;::;1 1 + )i u(a t+i+1 (1 + r)a t+i y t+i )] i=0 taking derivative with respect to A t+i+1 rearranging the equation 1 ( 1 + )i u 0 1 (c t+i ) + ( 1 + )i+1 u 0 (c t+i+1 )[ (1 + r)] = 0 E t u 0 (c t+i ) = 1 + r 1 + E tu 0 (c t+i+1 ) 4

since u 0 (c t ) is known at time t, E t u 0 (c t ) = u 0 (c t ) and we obtain the Euler Equation: u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + E tu 0 (c t+1 ) (4*) The Euler equation gives the dynamics of marginal utility in any two successive periods At the optimum, the agent is indi erent between consuming immediately one unit of the good, with marginal utility u 0 (c t ), and saving in order to consume 1 + r units in the next period This equation does not nd the level of consumption but only can describe the dynamics of consumption from one period to the next given that we specify a functional form for u(c). In order to nd the level of consumption, it is necessary to use consumption dynamics inside the present value budget constraint (as we did in the Ramsey Model) 5

A Note Similarity of equation (4): u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + E tu 0 (c t+1 ) (4) with its continuous time version: _c c = u0 (c) (r ) (5) u 00 (c)c Taylor Approximation: f(x + x) = f(x) + f 0 (x) 1! x + f 00 (x) x + ::: 2! Using the rst order approximation for u 0 (c t+1 ) in equation (4) u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + (u0 (c t ) + u 00 (c t )(c t+1 c t )) which can be simpli ed as c t+1 c t c t = u 0 (c t ) ( r u 00 (c t )c t 1 + r ) which is very similar to equation (5) given that 1 + r ' 1 6

1 - Quadratic Utility When we use a quadratic utility function: u(c) = c b=2 c 2, its derivative has a linear form: u 0 (c) = b c, which further implies that Using this equation in Euler equation E t u 0 (c t+1 ) = u 0 (E t (c t+1 )) u 0 (E t (c t+1 )) = 1 + 1 + r u0 (c t ) If we assume that r =, the above equation reduces to E t c t+1 = c t (7) This is the main implication of the intertemporal choice model with rational expectations and quadratic utility: the best forecast of next period s consumption is the current consumption 7

Note 1: In the next slide we derive the present value budget constraint and then use equation (7) to solve consumption (c) in terms of A and future y s. Just be aware that if the utility function is not quadratic, solving c requires a more complicated procedure. In that case we usually refer to a value function and the Bellman Equation Note 2: Equation (7) further implies that c t+1 = c t + u t+1 In this case consumption is a martingale, or a random walk (this means changes in the consumption is unpredictable at time t). 8

2 - Intertemporal (Present Value) Budget Constraint We need to compute the consumer s intertemporal budget constraint. Using the budget constraint (2) at time t c t = (1 + r)a t + y t A t+1 Substituting A t+1 for the period t + 2,we get c t = (1+r)A t +y t (c t+1 y t+1 + A t+2 ) 1 + r ) c t + c t+1 1 + r = y t+ y t+1 1 + r +(1+r)A t A t+2 1 + r Similarly c t + c t+1 1 + r + c t+2 (1 + r) 2 = y t + y t+1 1 + r + y t+2 (1 + r) 2 + (1 + r)a t A t+3 (1 + r) 2 Hence, in expected terms 1P 1 P ( 1 + r )i E t c t+i = 1 1 ( 1 + r )i E t y t+i + (1 + r)a t (8) i=0 i=0 9

That is to say the present value of consumption ows from t up to 1 is equal to the consumer s total available resources. The later is given by the sum of the initial nancial wealth A t and the present value of future labor incomes from t up to 1 1 & 2 - Quadratic Utility and Intertemporal Budget Constraint With the quadratic utility we obtained E t c t+1 = c t : Substituting this into equation (9) and dividing by (1 + r) gives 1 r c t = A t + 1 1P 1 ( 1 + r 1 + r )i E t y t+i A t + H t i=0 where H t is the human wealth and is equal to the present value of future expected labor incomes. Thus, c t = r(a t + H t ) y P t That is to say the amount of consumption at t is the annuity value of total life-time wealth: r(a t + H t ). That return is de ned as permanent income, y P t 10

(In the absence of taxes) disposable income at time t is the following y D t = ra t + y t Then we can write that s t = y D t c t = y D t y P t = (ra t + y t ) (ra t + rh t ) = y t rh t = y T t People consume on the basis of their life-time income (yt P ). If today s income (yt D ) is more than this amount, it is called transitory income (yt T ) and is saved (borrowed if yt T is negative) r 1P 1 P Saving can also be written as: s t = y t ( 1 + r 1 + r )i E t y t+i = 1 1 ( 1 + r )i E t y t+i Consumer save to face expected future declines of labor income ( saving for a rainy day ) Let s assume the following rst-order autoregressive process generating income for consumers i=0 y t+1 = y t + (1 )y + " t+1 E t (" t+1 ) = 0 i=1 11

where 0 1 is a parameter and y denotes the unconditional mean of income, implying that r c t+1 = c t + ( 1 + r )" t+1 1 = 0. In this case y t+1 = y + " t+1. The innovation in current income is purely transitory. Thus it does not a ect the level of income in future periods. For an innovation " t+1, the consumer s human wealth changes by " t+1 =(1 + r). This change in H t+1 determines a variation of permanent income, and we get low marginal propensity to consume r c t+1 = c t + ( 1 + r )" t+1 2 = 1. In this case y t+1 = y t + " t+1. The innovation in current income is permanent, causing an equal change of all future incomes. The change in human wealth is " t+1 =r and the variation in permanent income and consumption is " t+1 c t+1 = c t + " t+1 12

The excess smoothness of consumption If the reaction of consumption to unanticipated changes in income is too smooth, this phenomenon is called excess smoothness. The following section deals with the role of a precautionary saving motive in shaping this reaction The Role of Precautionary Saving - Microeconomic Foundations Suppose r = and the Euler equation becomes: E t u 0 (c t+1 ) = u 0 (c t ) Suppose further that at time t income is y and at time t + 1 it is either y A or y B ; where the average of these numbers is y With the quadratic utility function, marginal utility of consumption coincides with the marginal utility of expected consumption. Hence, when c t = E t (c t+1 ) : E t u 0 (c t+1 ) = u 0 (E t (c t+1 )) = u 0 (c t ) The consumer at time t does not need to save any, as the average of future consumption is just equal to today s consumption, and the Euler Equation is satis ed 13

If the utility function is not quadratic; the situation is di erent. Jensen s inequality states that given a strictly convex function f(x) of a random variable x, E(f(x)) > f(e(x)) If the utility function is such that the marginal utility is a convex function of consumption (i.e. with risk aversion u 00 (c) < 0 and convex marginal utility u 000 (c) > 0), then when c t = E t (c t+1 ) : E t u 0 (c t+1 ) > u 0 (E t (c t+1 )) = u 0 (c t ): Hence, the Euler equation is satis ed only if c t < E t (c t+1 ) This is called a prudent behavior, and de nes the situation that consumers reacts to an increase in uncertainty by saving more (precautionary saving). Under uncertainty about future incomes, the consumer fears low-income states and adopts a prudent behavior, saves in the current period in order to increase expected future consumption. This is illustrated with the following gure 14

This gure shows that E t u 0 (c t+1 ) = [u 0 (y A t+1) + u 0 (y B t+1)]=2 > u 0 (y) = u 0 (c t ) Hence Euler equation is not satis ed at E t (c t+1 ) = c t. But if people save at time t, then E t u 0 (c t+1 ) = [u 0 (y A t+1 + s t ) + u 0 (y B t+1 + s t )]=2 = u 0 (y s t ) = u 0 (c t ) Carroll 1997 and 2001 papers show that precautionary (or bu er-stock) saving is consistent with the empirical facts about consumption to income pro le of households 15

The de nition of the coe cient measuring prudence is similar to that of riskaversion coe cients: however, the latter is related to the curvature of the utility function (the second derivative), whereas prudence is determined by the curvature of marginal utility (the third derivative) The Coe cient of Relative Prudence= The Coe cient of Absolute Prudence= @u 00 (c) u 00 (c) @c c @u 00 (c) u 00 (c) @c = u000 (c)c u 00 (c) = u000 (c) u 00 (c) 16

Non-Quadratic Utility Functions Remember the present value budget constraint and the Euler equation 1P 1 P ( 1 + r )i E t c t+i = 1 1 ( 1 + r )i E t y t+i + (1 + r)a t (PVBC) i=0 i=0 u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + E tu 0 (c t+1 ) (Euler) Together with the quadratic utility function, u(c) = c b=2c 2, the Euler equation implies that (when r = ) E t c t+1 = c t. Inserted this into the PVBC enabled us to solve optimal consumption decision of consumers at each point in time in terms of their wealth and income gains (we have even de ned an income process and solved the problem completely). When the utility function is not quadratic, the Euler equation does not give such straight relationship between consumption at di erent periods; hence, we need to apply di erent solution method A Note: Quadratic utility function implies that consumer is indi erent between choosing certain future income and or an uncertain future income mean of which is equal to certain one. This property is called Certainty Equivalence 17

Dynamic Programming: Value Function and Bellman Equation A-Under Certainty on Future Income Flows Remember that for the quadratic utility function we de ned human wealth H t as 1 1P 1 ( 1 + r i=0 1 + r )i y t+i = H t and eventually we found that 1 r c t = A t + H t We will again solve c t in terms of A t and H t. Consumer s total wealth is P W t = 1 1 ( 1 + r )i y t+i + (1 + r)a t = (1 + r)(a t + H t ) i=0 where W t measures the stock of total wealth at the end of period t before consumption c t occurs. As a result W t+i+1 = (1 + r)(w t+i c t+i ) (10) 18

Consumer Problem For i = 0; 1; 2; :::; 1, consumers maximize the utility function max c t+i P U t = [ 1 1 ( 1 + )i u(c t+i )] (1) i=0 subject to the series of budget constraints W t+i+1 = (1 + r)(w t+i c t+i ) (10) and the restriction that the consumer s wealth cannot be negative (the No-Ponzi Game Condition) lim W T +1 0 (3) T!1 Now we will solve consumption in terms of total wealth: c t (W t ). In the Dynamic Programming problem W t+i is called as the state variable (showing the state, well being, of consumers), and c t+i is the control variable Consumers get utility u() from consuming c. But since they are able to a ord c as they have wealth, W, there should be a function, that we call V (), that 19

would give correspondence of W in terms of utility. Hence the consumer problem at the nal period T; instead of u(c t (W t )), can be written as V T (W T ); which is called the Value Function As a result, the consumer problem in period T max c T 1 (u(c T 1 ) + 1 1 + V T (W T )) 1 can be written as given W T 1 ; choosing c T 1 determines W T ; which determines the utility for the rest of the periods The same procedure can be applied to earlier periods recursively (backward recursion). In general, the problem can be written in terms of the Bellman equation: V t (W t ) = max(u(c t ) + 1 c t 1 + V t+1(w t+1 )) subject to W t+1 = (1 + r)(w t c t ) 20

FOC w.r.t. c t gives FOC w.r.t. W t gives u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + V 0 t+1(w t+1 ) (11) V 0 t (W t ) = 1 + r 1 + V 0 t+1(w t+1 ) (12) Actually there are two additional terms coming from the derivative of c t w.r.t. W t, but they cancel out due to the rst FOC Combining (11) and (12) gives u 0 (c t ) = V 0 t (W t ) Inserting this equation into (11) gives the Euler equation u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + u0 (c t+1 ) A Note: Since time is in nite, the iteration of Bellman equation reaches a unique V () that is invariant over time 21

B- Uncertainty on Future Income Flows Under uncertainty the solution procedure illustrated above is still appropriate. Let s assume there is uncertainty for the future labor income but not for the interest rate This time, instead of W t, the state variable at time t is the consumer s certain amount of resources at the end of t: (1 + r)a t + y t : As a result the Bellman Equation is V t [(1 + r)a t + y t ] = max c t fu(c t ) + 1 1 + E tv t+1 [(1 + r)a t+1 + y t+1 ]g As it is seen, since there is uncertainty for future incomes, there is an expectation term, E t This equation is subject to A t+1 = (1 + r)a t + y t c t 22

FOC w.r.t. c t gives FOC w.r.t. A t gives Combining (13) and (14) gives: u(c t ) = 1 + r 1 + E tv 0 t+1[(1 + r)a t+1 + y t+1 ] (13) V 0 t () = 1 + r 1 + E tv 0 t+1() (14) u 0 (c t ) = V 0 t () Inserting this into the equation (14) gives the Euler equation u 0 (c t ) = 1 + r 1 + E tu 0 (c t+1 ) 23

Consumption and Financial Returns We leave the assumption that the consumer uses a single nancial asset with a certain return r: Instead, a consumer can invest his savings in n nancial assets with uncertain returns. The chosen portfolio allocation will depend on the characteristics of the consumer s utility function (in particular the degree of risk aversion) and of the distribution of asset returns. We will nd the price for assets. This model is the basic version of the consumption-based capital asset pricing model (CCAPM) With the new hypothesis of n nancial assets with uncertain returns, the consumer s budget constraint must be reformulated accordingly np A j t+i+1 = P n (1 + r j t+i+1 )Aj t+i + y t+i c t+i j=1 j=1 This equation says that consumers wealth comes from n nancial assets, and after added by labor income and substracted by consumption, can be invested on n di erent assets as well. The return for asset A j t+i at at the period t + i is not known at that period. Therefore, we denote it by r j t+i+1 at the period t + i 24

When Euler equation is solved for each r j, we get which can be written as u 0 (c t ) = 1 1 + E t[(1 + r j t+1 )u0 (c t+1 )] 1 = E t [(1 + r j t+1 ) 1 u 0 (c t+1 ) 1 + u 0 (c t ) ] E t[(1 + r j t+1 )M t+1] where M t+1 is the stochastic discount factor : the discounted ratio of marginal utilities of consumption in any two subsequent periods We know that multiplication of two random variables can be written as 1 = E t [(1 + r j t+1 )M t+1] = E t (1 + r j t+1 )E t(m t+1 ) + cov t (r j t+1 ; M t+1)] then E t (1 + r j t+1 ) = 1 E t (M t+1 ) [1 cov t(r j t+1 ; M t+1)] 25

For the safe asset (r 0 ) considered in the previous sections, this reduces to 1 + rt+1 0 1 = E t (M t+1 ) subtracting this equation from the previous one gives E t (r j t+1 ) r0 t+1 = (1 + r 0 t+1)cov t (r j t+1 ; M t+1) (9) The stochastic discount factor, M t+1 = 1 u 0 (c t+1 ) ; together with (9) gives the 1 + u 0 (c t ) main result from the model with risky nancial assets: An asset j whose return has a negative covariance with M t+1 yields an expected return higher than r 0 To see this suppose M t+1 is high (i.e. u 0 (c t+1 ) is high relative to u 0 (c t )). This means c t+1 is low relative to c t at equilibrium. When the return of an asset j is negatively correlated with M t+1, it gives low return when c t+1 is already low. Then the agent holds this asset only if such risk is appropriately compensated by a premium, given by an expected return higher than the risk-free rate r 0 return (i.e. E t (r j t+1 ) r0 t+1 > 0) 26