Guessing with negative feedback : an experiment. Angela Sutan, Marc Willinger ESC & LAMETA Dijon - Montpellier

Similar documents
Boundary and interior equilibria: what drives convergence in a beauty contest?

Boundary and interior equilibria: what drives convergence in a beauty contest?

Nobuyuki Hanaki Angela Sutan Marc Willinger. Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series. GREDEG WP No

arxiv: v2 [cs.gt] 13 Dec 2014

The strategic environment effect in beauty contest games

The Heterogeneous Expectations Hypothesis: Some Evidence from the Lab

Level K Thinking. Mark Dean. Columbia University - Spring 2017

Simple Forecasting Heuristics that Make us Smart: Evidence from Different Market Experiments

Learning to Forecast with Genetic Algorithms

Behavioural & Experimental Macroeconomics: Some Recent Findings

On p-beauty Contest Integer Games

Finite Mixture Analysis of Beauty-Contest Data from Multiple Samples

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004

Strategic Uncertainty in Non-renewable Resource Markets: a Level-k Approach

Advanced Microeconomics

Beauty Contests and Iterated Expectations in Asset Markets. Franklin Allen Stephen Morris Hyun Song Shin

Weak Dominance and Never Best Responses

C31: Game Theory, Lecture 1

South Slave Divisional Education Council. Math 20-2

SOLVING SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS WITH EXAMPLES FROM ECONOMICS, CHEMISTRY, EDUCATION AND PSYCHOLOGY. Revised: Michael Lolkus 2018

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

(with thanks to Miguel Costa-Gomes, Nagore Iriberri, Colin Camerer, Teck-Hua Ho, and Juin-Kuan Chong)

Games of Elimination

Experimental Evidence on the Use of Information in Beauty-Contest Game

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

Game Theory and Rationality

Quantal Response and Nonequilibrium Beliefs Explain Overbidding in Maximum-Value Auctions

Ambiguity and the Centipede Game

Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing

Reinforcement Learning

Knowing What Others Know: Coordination Motives in Information Acquisition

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Foundations of Mathematics 11 and 12 (2008)

TI-games I: An Exploration of Type Indeterminacy in Strategic Decision-making

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

Simplified Mechanisms

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Microeconomics MSc. preference relations. Todd R. Kaplan. October University of Haifa. Kaplan (Haifa) micro October / 43

1 Functions and Graphs

A Window of Cognition: Eyetracking the Reasoning Process in Spatial Beauty Contest Games

Behavorial learning in a population of interacting agents Jean-Pierre Nadal

The Condorcet Jury Theorem under Cognitive Hierarchies: Theory and Experiments 1

Topics in Nonlinear Economic Dynamics: Bounded Rationality, Heterogeneous Expectations and Complex Adaptive Systems

Parking Slot Assignment Problem

Confronting Theory with Experimental Data and vice versa. European University Institute. May-Jun Lectures 7-8: Equilibrium

Ergodicity and Non-Ergodicity in Economics

Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik

A Dynamic Level-k Model in Games

MARLBORO CENTRAL SCHOOL DISTRICT CURRICULUM MAP. Unit 1: Integers & Rational Numbers

Introduction to Game Theory

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

YOU CAN BACK SUBSTITUTE TO ANY OF THE PREVIOUS EQUATIONS

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Basics of Game Theory

Christian Hellwig 1 Sebastian Kohls 2 Laura Veldkamp 3. May 2012

Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information

6.2. TWO-VARIABLE LINEAR SYSTEMS

Graphing Systems of Linear Equations

LEM. New Results on Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Role of Luck. Giulio Bottazzi Daniele Giachini

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Coordinating Expectations: Global Games with Strategic Substitutes

Review: Limits of Functions - 10/7/16

Level-n Bounded Rationality and Dominated Strategies in Normal-Form Games

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

BILATERAL SEARCH AND VERTICAL HETEROGENEITY* By Jan Eeckhout 1. The London School of Economics, United Kingdom. 1. introduction

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Introduction to Game Theory

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

The assignment game: core, competitive equilibria and multiple partnership

Order on Types based on Monotone Comparative Statics

Expanding Choice in School Choice

Coordination without Common Knowledge

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

July Framing Game Theory. Hitoshi Matsushima. University of Tokyo. February 2018

Discrete Random Variables. Discrete Random Variables

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

Negotiation: Strategic Approach

Vickrey Auction. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS. Heng Liu

Best-Reply Matching in Games

2-5 Rational Functions

Introduction to Game Theory

Evolution & Learning in Games

Microeconomics MSc. preference relations. Todd R. Kaplan. October University of Haifa. Kaplan (Haifa) micro October / 39

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Nonlinear dynamics in a duopoly with price competition and vertical differentiation

A Reflexive toy-model for financial market

UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION B Sc. Mathematics (2011 Admission Onwards) II SEMESTER Complementary Course

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

STOCHASTIC MODELS LECTURE 1 MARKOV CHAINS. Nan Chen MSc Program in Financial Engineering The Chinese University of Hong Kong (ShenZhen) Sept.

SPATIAL VOTING (MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS)

Transcription:

Guessing with negative feedback : an experiment Angela Sutan, Marc Willinger ESC & LAMETA Dijon - Montpellier Lorentz workshop, October 2007

Depth of reasoning in a strategic environment Cognitive process of guessing Game theory : strategic reasoning Psychology : Machiavellic Intelligence (Theory of Mind) : strategic manipulation, Depth of reasoning = number of reasoning steps Not observable Based on the assumption of common knowledge of rationality

The beauty contest game with positive feedback (Moulin, 1986) M players choose simultaneously a real number in the closed interval [0, 100] The winner is the player whose chosen number is closest to : p mean Iterated elimination of dominated strategies leads to : Equilibrium = 0 If p < 1, the equilibrium is eductively stable If p = 1 infinite number of equilibrium solutions, p > 1 two corner solutions

Example : p = 0,7(Ho,Camerer,1998) Choosing a number in the interval : [70, 100] depth of reasoning 0 [49, 70[ depth of reasoning 1 [34, 49[ depth of reasoning 2

Assumptions about eductive reasoning in BCG Agents choose undominated strategies Iterated elimination of dominated strategies Common knowledge of rationality

Laboratory experiments : Nagel (1995) p Median Mean ½ 17 27,05 2/3 33 36,73 4/3 66 60,12 Equilibrium (0) never observed 6% of subjects choose n < 10 Average depth of reasoning 2 3

Most likely type of reasoning : iterated best-reply (to lower depth of reasoning) Level 0 : choose randomly 50 Level 1 : best reply to level 0 p 50 Level 2 : best reply to level 1 p(p 50)

Newspapers experiments : Nagel et al. (2002) P=2/3 Peaks at 33, 22 and 0 Depth of reasoning : 1, 2 infinity

Positive feedback : monotonic convergence High mean high winning number Low mean low winning number Expected mean Depth of reasoning

Negative feedback : non-monotonic (oscillatory) convergence High mean low winning number Low mean high winning number Expectation Depth of reasoning

Beauty contest game with negative feedback M players choose a number in the interval [0,100]. The winning number is : 100 p mean (p < 1)

Negative feedback Iterated elimination of dominant strategies b 0 1 b 3 E b 4 b 2 100

Equilibrium : E = 100 1 ( 1) n 1 + p p n + ( 1) n p n 100 n (with p < 1) E 100 = 1 + p

Why should negative feedback matter? Many real markets provide negative feedback on expectations : crop producers : a high price expectation will lead to low market price financial markets : a low price expectation will lead to a high market price Alternating correction of expectation errors (reducing the bias on both sides of the equilibrium point) facilitates convergence BCG experiments with interior equilibrium exhibit smaller deviations even in first round choices In repeated games, negative feedback reduces the anchoring bias on previously observed values Negative feedback acts as a stabilizer : a change in one direction will be offset by the reactions to move in the opposite direction. Heemeijer, Hommes, Sonnemans, Tuinstra (2007) : Negative feedback market (Cobweb) : Prices are stable and often converge to the equilibrium Positive feedback market (CAPM) : Prices fluctuate and often deviate from fundamentals

Eductive reasoning in the Cob-web model P Supply Price p 0 p 2 p 4 p 3 p 1 Demand x 1 x 3 x 2 x 4 x 0 x Quantity

Eductive reasoning in the Cob-web model P p 0 p 2 p 4 Supply p 3 p 1 Demand x 1 x 3 x 2 x 4 x 0 x

BCG with interior equilibrium M players choose numbers in the intervall [0, 100]. BCG+ : the winning number is : p (mean + c) (p < 1) BCG- : the winning number is : 100 p mean (p < 1) E-stable equilibrium : BCG+ : cp/(1-p) BCG- : 100/(1+p)

Positive feedback interior equilibrium experiment (Gueth et al., 2002) 1/2 (mean + 50) Starting at 100 : 75-62.5-56.25-53.125 50 Starting at 0 : 25-37.5-43.75-46.975 50 Results : Very fast convergence to 50 compared to corner solution High frequency of equilibrium chosen (almost 50%) But! 50 is a focal point

Our experiment 100 p mean (p < 1) Single round experiment Multiple-rounds experiment

Single-round experiment Group size : 8 subjets Rule E Average Abs groups deviation subjects BCG+ 2/3 (mean + 30) 60 50.0 9.9 11 88 BCG- 100 2/3 mean 60 60.4 5.1 12 96 Significantly lower abs deviation for BCG- (Wilcoxon-Mann-Withney, 5%)

76 80 84 88 92 96 100 76 80 84 88 92 96 100 72 72 68 68 64 64 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 single-round BCG- (p = 2/3) 36 40 44 48 52 56 60 single-round BCG+ (p = 2/3) 36 40 44 48 52 56 60 32 32 28 28 24 24 20 20 16 16 12 12 8 8 4 4 0 0 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0

Multiple-rounds experiment Computerized (z-tree). 128 subjects Partner design : 8 subjects per group 10 rounds Average time = 40 min Strategy space : real number between 0 et 100. Winning number : closest to : 100 - p mean 2 treatments : p = 2/3 E = 60, p = ¼ E = 80 Max gain per period : 8 Euros. Max gain observed : 32 Euros

Data p=2/3 number of choices 50 40 30 20 10 0 30 40 50 60 70 80 per1 per6

Data p=1/4 number of choices 50 40 30 20 10 0 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 per1 per6

Winning numbers, p = 2/3, 9 groups 80 70 60 50 40 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Winning numbers, p=1/4, 7 groups 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Average numbers for BCG+ (p =2/3)

Depth of reasoning : Cognitive hierarchy model (Camerer et al. 2004) Main assumption : heterogeneous depth of reasoning An agent of level k believes that other players are of a lower level (l < k) The number of players of level k is decreasing with k (Poisson law) : f τ k ( k ) = e τ / k! Relative frequency of level h players for a level k player g k ( h ) = f ( h ) / k l = 0 f ( l ),

Estimated τ : p = 2/3, E = 60 : τ - = 1,55 ( observed mean = 56,46) p = ¼, E = 80 : τ - = 0,94 (observed mean = 78,04)) Positive feedback : 1 < τ + < 2 Why such a difference between the p = 2/3 and p = 1/4?

Main findings for negative feedback Winning numbers are close to the predicted equilibrium number (even in period 1) Winning numbers converge to the equilibrium number after a few rounds (mostly from above) The average estimated depth or reasoning is between 1 and 2 Puzzle : Since the average depth of reasoning is equal in BCG+ and BCG-, why are winning numbers closer to the equilibrium number in BCG-?

Hypothesis Subjects trade off expected information vs cost of mental effort 1. Subjects have limited cognitive ability (cognitive constraint) cost of mental effort 2. The marginal cost of mental effort is increasing, and becomes infinite beyond the cognitive constraint 3. An additional step of reasoning is carried out only if the (expected) marginal benefit is larger than the marginal cost of reasoning 4. The benefit of a additional step of reasoning is a function of the expected marginal information

Boundaries boundaries of succesive strategy intervalls 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 depth of reasoning BCG+ BCG-

size of remaining intervall (p = 2/3) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 BCG- BCG+

Marginal benefit of expected information At each step, numbers between the previous boundary and the new located boundary are mentally scanned. The localization process implies that the equilibrium point is identified with increasing precision after each step Useful information gained after each step is measured by the intersection between scanned numbers and the nondominated strategies intervall. SNARC effect (Dehaene, 1993) : numbers are perceived from left to right on a logarithmic ordinal scale (for left to right writing cultures)

Available information : number scanned between two successive bounds (SNARC effect) Useful information : available information dominant strategy intervall Positive feedback (corner solution) b 2 b 1 b 0 0 100 E Negative feedback b 1 b 0 0 E 100

Available information : number scanned between two successive bounds (SNARC effect) Useful information : available information dominant strategy intervall Positive feedback (corner solution) b 2 b 1 b 0 0 100 E Negative feedback b 1 b 2 b 0 0 E 100

Marginal information H ( I ) = p log2 p Marginal information at stage k : H b b k 1 k k 1 ( Ik ) = log2 h l b b h l k + H ( I k ) = 0,01 Log 2 0,01

p = 2/3 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 BCG- BCG+ p = 1/4 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 BCG- BCG+

In early steps marginal information is always larger in BCG- than in BCG+ For any increasing cost of reasoning function, the number of steps is at least as large for p = 2/3 than for p = ¼

Conclusions Chosen numbers are close to E under negative feedback Convergence is faster than under positive feedback The cognitive hierarchy model predicts that the average depth or reasoning is the same under negative than positive feedback Early steps are more informative under negative feedback