Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Similar documents
Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Advanced Microeconomics

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

PhD Qualifier Examination

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

First Welfare Theorem

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

1 General Equilibrium

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Msc Micro I exam. Lecturer: Todd Kaplan.

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Theory of Auctions. Carlos Hurtado. Jun 23th, Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Introductory Microeconomics

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Second Welfare Theorem

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Two hours UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER SCHOOL OF COMPUTER SCIENCE. Date: Thursday 17th May 2018 Time: 09:45-11:45. Please answer all Questions.

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

Basics of Game Theory

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Competitive Equilibrium

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

Positive Models of Private Provision of Public Goods: A Static Model. (Bergstrom, Blume and Varian 1986)

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Lecture 1. Evolution of Market Concentration

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

5. Externalities and Public Goods

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Field Exam: Advanced Theory

Market Failure: Externalities

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information*

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Public Goods and Private Goods

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: August 20, 2015

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Economics th April 2011

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

EXAMINATION #4 ANSWER KEY. I. Multiple choice (1)a. (2)e. (3)b. (4)b. (5)d. (6)c. (7)b. (8)b. (9)c. (10)b. (11)b.

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008

0 Aims of this course

Lecture Notes. Microeconomic Theory. Guoqiang TIAN Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, Texas

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 2

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

A : a b c d a : B C A E B : d b c a b : C A B D E C : d c a c : E D B C D : a d b d : A D E B C E : a b d. A : a b c d a : B C A D E

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum

Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information. Games of incomplete information. Cournot Competition under Asymmetric Information (cont )

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Introduction to Game Theory

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Notes on General Equilibrium

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Transcription:

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are to answer one question from each section. Before turning in your exam, please number each page of your answers with the section and question number (for example, III.2 for section III and question 2). Indicate, by circling the appropriate selections below, which questions you have completed. If you answer more than one question in a section, and do not circle a question corresponding to that section, the first of the two that appears in your solution paper will be graded. Section I: Question 1 Question 2 Section II: Question 1 Question 2 Section III: Question 1 Question 2 Section IV: Question 1 Question 2 NOTE: The exam should have 13 pages including this cover page.

Part I Answer at most one question from Part I. 2

Question I.1 Consider a simple utility function for two goods, x 1 and x 2 : u = (x 1 γ 1 ) β 1 (x 2 γ 2 ) β 2, with β 1 > 0, β 2 > 0. The parameters γ 1 and γ 2 are constants, but they could be positive or negative. (a) Someone suggests that it would be okay to assume that β 1 + β 2 = 1. Yet someone else claims that this restriction may be unrealistic. Which person is correct? Briefly explain your answer. (b) Suppose that the person with the above utility function is struck by lightning. He survives, except now his utility function is u = β 1 log(x 1 γ 1 ) + β 2 log(x 2 γ 2 ). Will his consumption decisions change as a result of being struck by lightning? Briefly explain your answer. (c) Returning to the original utility function, assume that the consumer faces the budget constraint p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = w, where p 1 > 0, p 2 > 0 are prices and w > 0 is wealth. Set up the Lagrangean and solve for the two first-order conditions. Then use the budget constraint to solve for the Walrasian demands of both goods. These should be functions of p 1, p 2, w, β 1, β 2, γ 1, and γ 2. Finally, use your answer to part (a) to simplify your answer. (d) Finally, turn to a more general utility function with L goods: u = L (x k γ k ) β k, where β k > 0 for all k, k=1 which is maximized subject to the budget constraint L k=1 p kx k = w. Using the same approach as in part (c), derive the Walrasian demands for the L goods. (Hint: first substitute out the Lagrangean multiplier using the first-order conditions for two goods, i and j, then find an expression for p i x i and sum that expression over all i, using a normalization similar to the one used in part (c)). 3

Question I.2 Consider an expenditure function that has the form log[e(p, u)] = L α k log(p k ) + u k=1 L k=1 p β k k. Don t worry that this is expressed as log[e(p, u)] instead of as e(p, u). After all, if we apply the exp( ) function to both sides, the left-hand side will become e(p, u). (a) Apply Shephard s lemma to this expenditure function to obtain the Hicksian demand for good i. (Hint: Differentiate with respect to log(p i ) to obtain an elasticity that includes the Hicksian demand. Note also that p β k k equals (e log(pk) ) β k. The Hicksian demand should be a function of the α s, the β s, prices, and u.) (b) Derive the indirect utility function that is associated with this cost function. This is easier than part (a). (c) Finally, use your answer to (b) to obtain the Walrasian demands. What is the name of the derivation that is used to obtain the Walrasian demands? 4

Part II Answer at most one question from Part II. 5

Question II.1 Consider a firm that produces a single output q 0 using inputs z 1 0 and z 2 0, where the input-requirement set is nonempty, strictly convex, closed, and satisfies weak free disposal. Assume the firm operates in competitive markets. The firm s profit function is π(r 1, r 2, p) = p α 4(r 1 + r 1 r 2 + r 2 ), where p > 0 is the price of output, r 1 > 0 and r 2 > 0 are the input prices, and α is a constant parameter. (a) What condition on α (if any) is required for π(r 1, r 2, p) to satisfy the price homogeneity property of a valid profit function? Justify your answer. (b) Use π(r 1, r 2, p) to derive the firm s unconditional supply and factor demands. (c) Derive the firm s conditional factor demands and cost function. (d) It is easy to verify that the conditional input demands in (c) are non-increasing in their own price. Show that this result holds in general for a cost function derived from a production possibility set with N inputs and M outputs. 6

Question II.2 Consider a firm that produces output q 0 at a cost of c(q), where c (q) > 0 and c (q) > 0. Also assume that there is a probability 1 > α > 0 that the firm experiences an equipment failure and incurs additional repair costs equal to c R > 0 per unit of output or c R q in total. The competitive price of output is p > 0. (a) Derive the firm s first-order condition for an interior solution assuming its objective is to maximize expected profit. What is the economic intuition of this condition? (b) Derive the firm s first-order condition for an interior solution assuming its objective is to maximize its expected utility of profit, where the strictly increasing and strictly concave function u( ) characterizes its risk preferences. (c) Will the firm produce more if its objective is to maximize expected profit or if its objective is to maximize the expected utility of profit? Justify your answer and provide the economic intuition for your result. 7

Part III Answer at most one question from Part III. 8

Question III.1 There are N > 2 profit-maximizing firms that compete as Cournot oligopolists in a market with inverse demand given by P (Q) = a Q, where P is price, Q = N i=1 q i and q i is the output of firm i for i = 1,... N. Assume that all firms have the same cost function: C(q i ) = cq i. (a) Solve for Cournot equilibrium. Show that the profit for each firm in Cournot equilibrium, π C i, is equal to the square of output: π C i = q 2 i. (b) Suppose that prior to choosing quantities, two firms have the option to merge into a single firm. Compare the profit of the single merged firm in this new Cournot equilibrium, with a total of N 1 firms, to the sum of the two firms individual profits in the original Cournot equilibrium, where there were N firms. Show whether the firms should merge or not. (c) Now suppose N firms compete in an infinitely repeated game in which in each period they simultaneously choose q i. Let δ be the discount factor between periods (0 < δ < 1). Let t = 0, 1, 2,... represent the time period and let Q M denote the monopoly level of output. Suppose that each firm plays the following simple trigger strategy: Set q i = Q M /N in period t = 0 and in all t > 0 for which aggregate output was Q M in all preceding periods, and Set q i equal to the Cournot equilibrium output for all t > 0 for which aggregate output was not Q M in all preceding periods. For what range of the discount factor δ can the trigger strategy support collusion at the monopoly output level as a subgame-perfect equilibrium outcome? 9

Question III.2 A painting is to be auctioned in a sealed-bid auction in which all bidders simultaneously submit a bid and the highest bid wins the painting. Suppose there are only two bidders, i = 1, 2. Let b i be the bid of player i. The value of owning the painting for bidder i is v i. Assume that each v i is drawn from a uniform distribution on [0, 1]. Each bidder knows her own value but not the other bidder s value. (a) In a first-price sealed-bid auction the bidder with the highest bid wins the painting and pays her bid to the auctioneer. Show that bidding b i = v i /2 is a Bayesian Nash equilibrium. (b) In a second-price sealed-bid auction the bidder with the highest bid wins the painting and pays the bid of the second-highest bid to the auctioneer. Show that it is a dominant strategy for each bidder to bid b i = v i. (c) The auctioneer s goal is to maximize the expected revenue from the auction. Show whether the auctioneer should choose the first-price sealed-bid auction or the second-price sealed-bid auction, or whether the auctions generate the same expected revenue. (Hint: A potentially useful mathematical fact is that the expected value of the maximum of two independent random variables uniformly distributed on [0, x] is 2x/3.) 10

Part IV Answer at most one question from Part IV. 11

Question IV.1 Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, j = 1, 2, and two goods x 1 and x 2. Consumer 1 has an endowment of ω 1 = (6, 0) and consumer 2 has an endowment of ω 2 = (0, 6). Subscripts denote consumers and superscripts denote goods. Utility functions are given by x 1 1x 2 1 if x 2 1 2x 1 1 U 1 (x 1 1, x 2 1) = x 1 1 + x 2 1 if x 1 1/2 < x 2 1 < 2x 1 1 and U 2 (x 1 2, x 2 2) = x 1 2x 2 2. x 1 1x 2 1 if x 2 1 x 1 1/2 (Consumer 1 s indifference curves have a flat portion between the rays along which x 2 1 = 2x 1 1 and x 2 1 = x 1 1/2.) (a) Derive the offer curves for the two consumers. Solve for a Walrasian equilibrium allocation and prices (x, p ). You may include a carefully labeled diagram as part of your answer if you wish, but this is not required. (b) Derive the contract curve for this economy. (This is the set that Mas-Colell calls the Pareto set.) Prove that the Walrasian equilibrium allocation you found in part (a) is Pareto optimal. (c) Consider an endowment vector ω R 4 ++ with the property that the aggregate endowment is the same as for ω: for each good i, ω i 1 + ω i 2 = 6. Derive expressions for (i) the associated equilibrium price vector p( ω) and (ii) the associated equilibrium allocation x( ω). 12

Question IV.1 Consider a 2-person economy in the form of Bergstrom, Blume, and Varian with one private good x and one public good G. Each consumer is endowed with a quantity w i of the private good, of which x i is consumed and g i is contributed to the linear provision of the public good. Thus, w i = x i + g i and G = g 1 + g 2. Utility functions are Cobb-Douglas, given by U 1 (x 1, G) = ln x 1 + ln G and U 2 (x 2, G) = ln x 2 + 2 ln G. (a) Suppose the initial endowments are w 1 = 10 and w 2 = 5. Solve for the optimum given by Samuelson s condition. (b) Solve each consumer s problem to obtain the best-response functions g i (g i ) that lead to the voluntary-contribution equilibrium, where g 1 = g 2 and g 2 = g 1. In BBV s notation the best-response functions are of the form g i = max { f i (w i + g i ) g i, 0 }, where f i (w i, g i ) is the demand for G that arises from the solution to max xi,g U i (x i, G) subject to x i + G = w i + g i. (c) Suppose that initially w = (10, 5) as in part (a). Solve for the g i, G, and the x i. Find the range of w 2 such that w 1 + w 2 = 15 and G remains at the level you found for w. (d) Now suppose that both endowments increase proportionately, so that w i = t w i for t > 1. Show that the new equilibrium level of the public good, G, is such that G > G. 13