Cherry-picking in Labor Markets with Imperfect Information

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Cherry-picking in Labor Markets with Imperfect Information"

Transcription

1 Cherry-picing in Labor Marets with Imperfect Information Shuaizhang Feng Bingyong Zheng April 13, 2009 Abstract We study a competitive labor maret with imperfect information. In our basic model, the labor maret consists of heterogeneous worers and ex ante identical firms who have imperfect information about worers productivities. Firms compete by posting wages each round to win the right to mae job offers, and tae turns to cherry-pic more productive worers. We also consider extensions of the model where firms differ in either productivity or information technology. The model predicts many important empirical regularities, including non-degenerated firm size distribution, persistent wage dispersions, positive sorting of firms and worers, and employer size-wage premium. The main insight of this paper is that identical worers can get different wages in a competitive maret when they are pooled with coworers of different average productivities. Keywords: Imperfect information, cherry-picing, wage dispersion, size-wage premium. JEL classification codes: D83; J31. We would lie to than Han Farber, Hanming Fang, Peter Gottschal, Lars Lefgren, Alan Krueger, Andrew Marder, David McAdams, Bruce Meyer, Jim Smith, Wing Suen, Cheng Wang, and Tao Zhu for comments. We also than participants at the Princeton IRS Lunch seminar. All errors are our own. Princeton University and IZA. shuaizha@princeton.edu. Shanghai University of Finance and Economics. bingyongzheng@gmail.com.

2 1 Introduction Larger firms pay more on average to worers of similar characteristics than smaller firms. A large number empirical studies have found the wage differentials to be statistically significant and practically large even after controlling for worers observable characteristics and unobservable heterogeneity. To put the magnitude of the size-wage premium into perspective, we quote Brown and Medoff (1989), if a typical worer went from an establishment with employment one standard deviation below average to an establishment with employment one standard deviation above average, the employee would enjoy a wage increase of 8-12 percent, about as large as the union-nonunion differential in these data. Why should worers of apparently same ability get different wages at similar jobs? Various theories have been advanced to explain the size-wage premium puzzle, with the search friction model (e.g. Burdett and Mortensen 1998) being the most commonly invoed explanation. Suppose ex ante identical worers do not now the wages offered by firms, but now the distribution of wage offers. At random time intervals, a worer receives information about new jobs. As jobs are identical apart from the wages associated with them, employed worers move from lower to higher paying jobs as the opportunity arises. Since worers are more liely to leave a low paying job but less liely to leave a high paying job, firms can offer higher wages to retain worers and also to attract new worers. In equilibrium, firms that offer higher wages earn lower profit per worer but hires more worers, while firms that offer lower wages earn higher profit per worer but hires fewer worers; thus yielding the same total profit for all firms. Hence, persistent wage differentials can exist as a result of search frictions. While search friction may explain part of what we observe in the labor maret, it can not be the whole story. The search friction model concentrates on search frictions, arising because worers do not now firms wage offers, which is not always plausible. Further, the search friction model predicts a positive relationship between firm size and wages offered, which is only one form of wage dispersions. But it does not explain other form of wage dispersions. In some labor marets, for example, the academic job maret, worers of similar ability can get different pay in different firms, but there is not necessary a positive relationship between firm sizes and wages. Finally, the search friction model predicts that unemployment decreases with the increase of minimum wages in a competitive maret. In this paper we focus on information imperfection instead of search friction. That is, the employer may not now the productivities of potential employees. We demonstrate this type of imperfection can result in wage dispersion as well. In many job marets, the employer is not sure of the productive capabilities of an individual worer at the time of hiring. To learn more about the worer s productivities, the employer can mae an assessment based on observable characteristics, such as the individual s sex, race, age, education, etc. But this assessment is rarely perfect. A productive worer may also try to inform the employer her true type through some costly signaling (e.g., Spence 1973). However, in a world where there are more types than the number of signals available for this means, signaling has only a limited use 2

3 and is not always effective at separating worers of various productive capabilities. 1 As a result, employers only have imperfect information of potential worers productivities when maing hiring decisions. We show that imperfect information about worer productivity may lead to persistent wage dispersions, including the employer size-wage premium in a competitive job maret. Our basic model considers a one period labor maret with infinite number of firms that are ex ante identical, and a continuum of worers who are either of high productivity type or of low productivity type. Because firms only have limited information about worers productivities, they mae job offers conditional on the (unbiased) expectations, or beliefs, of worer s type. Firms tae turns to cherrypic worers that they thin are of high productive capabilities. They compete for the right to hire each round by posting high wages, with the firm with the highest wage getting the right to hire in any round. In equilibrium, firms hire worers of different expected (average) productivities at different wages. Firms that hire in earlier rounds pay higher wages and draw disproportionately more high type worers. As the wage a firm pays equals the average productivity of its labor force, worers of the same productivity will be paid differently when they are pooled with coworers of different average productivities. Consequently, all equilibria of the model are characterized by persistent wage dispersion. When we restrict attention to equilibria in which firms hire all worers that they thin are of high type, there is a positive relationship between firm sizes and wages in equilibrium. That is, firms who post higher wages and thus hire earlier will also hire more worers. 2 This is so as they select from a better applicant pool in terms of average productivity. Our model predicts that productive worers can remain unemployed as firms can not tell them apart from other less productive ones. The equilibrium unemployment is increasing in minimum wage. This prediction is consistent with traditional wisdom and what we observe in real world. One drawbac of our basic model is perhaps the multiplicity of equilibria. As firms are ex ante identical, the order of hiring is not unique, as any firm can tae any position in the sequence of hiring. However, when firms are different in their respective productivities, there is a unique equilibrium with wage dispersion, as we demonstrate in Section 3. In this equilibrium, firms with higher productivities hire earlier, hire more worers that are of higher average productivities, offer higher wages, and mae more profits. Thus, there is a size-wage premium for worers conditional on type. Also, even though high productivity worers and firms are not perfectly matched, there exists positive sorting in the sense that the proportion of high productivity worers in the worforce is increasing in firm productivity. In another extension we consider a labor maret where firms have different in- 1 A necessary condition for signaling to be effective is the negative correlation relationship between productivities and signaling cost. Only under this condition, productive worers may be able to successfully separate themselves from unproductive worers through costly signaling. See Spence (1973) for detailed discussion. 2 In fact, this is true for all equilibria in which hiring firms hire the same portion of worers they thin as high type. 3

4 formation technology the ability to judge worer s true types. We show that when an equilbrium exists, firms with superior information technology always earn higher profits. However, the order of hiring depends on relative scarcity of high productivity worers. When the proportion of high type worer is sufficiently low, marginal benefits of cherry picing is high, and firms with better information technology will hire earlier. This results again a unique equilibrium with size-wage premium. When the proportion of high type worer is sufficiently high, marginal benefits of cherry picing is low, equilibrium may or may not exists in that case. We therefore have demonstrated that worers of same sills can get different pay, not because of search friction, but because they are pooled with coworers of different average productivities. In addition, we predict that wage differentials exists in any labor maret in which firms may have imperfect information about potential employees abilities, even if no clear size-wage relationship can be identified. Given firms always have some way to screen worers, is information imperfection really that important? We believe so, especially in some labor maret for silled worers. The academic job maret for new Ph.D.s is the best example, typically with job candidates nowing more about hiring departments while the recruiting institutions have difficulties judging a candidate s abilities. In our model, worer now the wages posted by firms but firms do not now the types of worers, an thus, a firm pays the average productivity of its labor force. This is the source of wage dispersion here. In the search friction model, firms have no difficulty judging worers productivity. However, worers do not now the wages offered by firms, and this friction leads to wage dispersion. In this sense, both the search friction model and our model are looing at some type of imperfect nowledge (or imperfect information) by maret participants in explaining persistent wage dispersions. As to the nature of imperfection, however, our model and the search friction model part company. This paper falls into a large literature on labor maret information that dates bac at least to Stigler (1962). Previously, Spence (1973) shows how high productivity job applicants could send costly signals to prospective employers in order to be separated from low productivity worers. However, signaling only plays a limited role in the labor maret because the available number of signals is far less than number of worer types, due to both individual heterogeneity and uncertainty in the production process. 3 More recently, Grossman (2004) demonstrates that the combination of imperfect information with national differences in the dispersion of worer talents can be an independent source of comparative advantage, and lead to trade in two otherwise identical countries. Grossman (2004) motivates imperfect information with team wor in production and labels this incomplete labor contract, as no contract can be written conditional on each individual worer s marginal product. This paper is also closely related to the statistical discrimination literature (for example, Coate and Loury 1993, Moro and Norman 2004), which focus on informational friction to explain group based inequality in labor maret. In their models, worers 3 Also, a necessary condition for signaling to be effective is the negative correlation relationship between productivities and signaling cost. 4

5 sills are unobservable, but employers may observe a noisy signals of sill. Thus, employer s inability to judge worer s type also plays a vital role in their models. However, there is main difference between our model and the statistical discrimination modes. There, the wage inequality is rationalized as a coordination failure, and thus, the inequality can be solved by policies aimed at reversing discrimination. Whereas in our model, the wage inequality among worers of similar sill is a result of pooling with coworers of different average productivities. Hence, remedy comes only when firms have better information technology in judging worers sills. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents our basic model. Section 3 extends the model by introducing productivity heterogeneity. In Section 4, we consider an extension in which firms have different information technology. Section 5 discusses the relationship of this paper to some others in the literature. Section 6 concludes. 2 The basic model 2.1 Setup We consider a competitive labor maret with no barriers to entry and exit. Firms are ex ante identical, and have a constant return to scale production technology. They produce the same output that are sold in a competitive maret at price P which we normalize to 1. There is a continuum of worers of measure one, that are of either high or low type. High type and low type worers account for proportion α and 1 α of the population, respectively. A high type worer produces one unit of output if employed, while a low type worer produces nothing. The proportion of the two types and productivities of each type are common nowledge to all maret participants. However, an individual worer s type is unnown to all parties, including herself 4. Worers maximize their wages subject to a reservation wage r. There is no application cost and worers are free to apply to all hiring firms. When a worer applies to a firm, the firm maes a private assessment of the job applicant s type. With probability β H, a high type worer is taen as high type by the firm, thus labeled as h. With probability 1 β H, she is mistaenly recognized as low type, or labeled as l. Similarly, a low type worer is labeled l with probability β L and h with probability 1 β L. We assume all firms have the same ability to differentiate high type worers from low type ones, i.e., they have the same β H and β L. The private assessments of different firms are independent, 5 thus a worer recognized as low type by one firm may be taen as high type by another. 4 An alternative assumption is that worers now their own types, but are prohibited from sending signal to firms. Our model thus departs from the signaling literature but resembles statistical discrimination models such as Coate and Loury (1993). 5 Our main results do not change as long as these assessments are not perfectly correlated. Assuming independence simplifies our analyses, though. 5

6 For simplicity, we let β H = β L = β. 6 When β = 1/2, firms have no ability to differentiate high type worers from low type worers. When β = 1, firms can perfectly distinguish high type from low type worers. When 1 > β > 1/2, firms have some but less than perfect ability to judge worer types, and this is the case we focus on in this paper. Because all individuals have the same reservation wage, firms offering w < r will not be able to hire anyone. Therefore, if the reservation wage is too high, no firm would hire in the maret. To eliminate this uninteresting case, throughout the paper we assume r < α, which implies that a firm could mae a profit by hiring all worers or a random subset at their reservation wage r. The job maret wors in a sequential manner, consisting of many rounds of auctions among hiring firms. Each round, firms that have not hired yet post wages they are willing to offer to at least some worers in the remaining pool of job applicants, and the one with the highest wage wins the right to hire. In case several firms tie at the highest wage, one firm is randomly chosen to hire in that round. The firm who wins then offers to hire selected worers from the remaining pool of applicants at the posted wage. We assume firms always mae offers to a positive measure of worers when it wins the right to hire. Upon receiving an offer from the firm, worers decide whether to accept the offer or not. After that, the game moves to the next round in which the same process is repeated for firms who have not won any round and for worers who remain unemployed. The game ends when no firm finds it profitable to post a wage that will be accepted. That is, firms are unwilling to hire any unemployed worer at a wage greater than their reservation wage. Production then starts, and firms who have hired a positive measure of worers realize their profits. Sequential wage posting leads to all standard perfect competition results in a frictionless setting. It therefore offers a basic framewor upon which maret frictions such as imperfect information can be built and studied. Also, many actual labor marets seem to display this sequential nature and clear upside-down. Tae the U.S. academic job maret as an example, it consists three segments: the preemptive maret, which is conducted prior to the Allied Social Science Association (ASSA) meetings and only participated by top candidates and departments; the primary maret, which holds interviews at the ASSA meetings and campus visits shortly after; and the secondary maret, which starts after the primary maret has begun to clear. Even for the primary maret where the majority of applicants and hiring departments participate, although applications are processed at roughly the same time, in reality, top programs usually get priority in hiring their ideal candidates. For example, less prestigious programs frequently give good job candidates a grace period of at least two wees to respond to their offers, so that the job candidates can contact their preferred departments. Often candidates are willing to give up less prestigious program s offer to wait for better offers when they have positive feedbacs from them (See Cawley 2006.). In this model, an equilibrium is characterized by the number of active firms K, unemployment rate u, and wage distribution F(w), such that the following conditions 6 None of our substantive results will change without this assumption. 6

7 are satisfied: 1. Worers maximize the wage income they receive, provided the wage offered is greater than their reservation wage r, 2. Firms mae wage offers to maximize profit, 3. Firms update beliefs about worers types using Bayes rule. 2.2 Main results To start, note that because firms are ex ante identical, they must mae the same level of total profit in any equilibrium. Otherwise, firms that mae lower level profit will mimic the behavior of those earning higher profit. A firm actually maes two choices in the recruiting process: to post a wage, and decide whom to hire at the posted wage if it wins the right to hire. From the firm s perspective, it faces two groups of worers, those labeled as h and those labeled as l. After winning the right to hire, the firm can hire in three different ways, to hire randomly irrespective of the signals received from worers, to hire only those it receives a signal h, or to hire only those with a signal l. Competition between firms, however, forces a firm to hire only those it thins are of high type. Claim 1. In any equilibrium, a firm that wins the right to hire at any round maes offers only to those it labels as h. Proof. See Appendix A. The intuition for this result is straightforward. As firms compete for the right to hire in a round, they have pushed the winning bid so high, such that hiring those l label worers would decrease profit given the posted wage. As a result, we observe firms tae turns cherry picing more productive worers in equilibrium. Claim 2. In any equilibrium, firms mae zero profit. Proof. See Appendix A. The above two claims suggest that firms expected profit from each worer hired is zero. Therefore, a firm does not have to hire every worer it thins as high type. This implies that there are multiple equilibria in this model. In an equilibrium, it is optimal for firm to hire any δ (0, 1] proportion of those from whom it labels as h at the posted wage. We summarize our results so far in the following proposition. Proposition 1. There exist multiple equilibria. In any equilibrium, firms pay worers their average productivities. Also, both average productivities and wages decline in, the order of hiring. 7

8 Proof. The results follow directly from Claim 1 and Claim 2. Let firm mae offers to δ proportion of those it receives good signals h, with 0 < δ 1. It suffices to show that H > H +1, as w = H and w +1 = H +1. Let the applicant pool firm hires from be R 1, which consists ñ measure of high worers and m measure of low type worers. The average productivity of worers at firm is H = ñ β ñ β + m (1 β). The applicant pool firm +1 will choose from consists of ñ +1 = (1 δ β)ñ measure of high type worers and m +1 = [1 δ (1 β)] m measure of low type worers. Hence, H +1 = (1 δ β)ñ β (1 δ β)ñ β + [1 δ (1 β)] m (1 β). Clearly, H > H +1 given that 1 > β > 1/2. It remains to show that there exists at least two active firms in the maret. This is guaranteed by the assumption that r < α. Note that the average productivity of worers with good signals for firm 2 is H 2 = (1 δ 1 β)αβ (1 δ 1 β)αβ + [1 δ 1 (1 β)](1 α)(1 β) > α, which is greater than the reservation r, so firm 2 will be active. We focus our attention to the case when firms hire the same portion of worers they thin are of high types, i.e., δ = δ for all. It turns out that for any δ (0, 1], the corresponding equilibria have the same properties. For simplicity, we assume that δ = 1, that is, firms hire every worer they thin as hight type. This is formally stated in the following assumption 7. Assumption 1. Firms treat observationally identical worers in the same way. That is, if a firm maes an offer to any worer, then it must also mae the same offer to other worers who have the same expected productivity from the firm s perspective. Proposition 2. Under Assumption 1, the equilibrium is characterized by employer size-wage premium. Firms that offer higher wages (both unconditionally and conditional on type) also hire more worers. Proof. Note this is just the special case with δ = 1 as considered in Proposition 1. In general, the average productivity of worers at firm is H = αβ(1 β) 1 αβ(1 β) 1 + (1 α)β 1 (1 β). The measure of worers firm hires equals N = α(1 β) 1 β + (1 α)β 1 (1 β). Clearly, both H and N decrease as increases. Hence, there is a positive relationship between firm size and wage. 7 In an environment when firms now worer types perfectly, Shimer (2005) similarly assumes that firms wage offers may be conditional on a worer s type but not on her individual identity. 8

9 Under Assumption 1, the equilibrium is unique up to renaming of the firms. Again, note that maing the alternative assumption, δ = δ < 1 for all, also results in equilibrium with size-wage effect, but with H and N formulated differently. After firms 1, 2,, 1, have hired, the measure of worers remains to be hired equals R = α(1 β) + (1 α)β, and the average productivity of the remaining worers will be α +1 = α(1 β) α(1 β) + (1 α)β = α[(1 β)/β] α[(1 β)/β] + (1 α). Note that both R and α +1 are strictly decreasing in. As more and more firms have hired, the proportion of high type worers in the remaining pool decreases, so does the measure of unemployed worers. At certain point, it becomes unprofitable for another firm to hire, as the expected benefit from hiring a worer the firm recognizes as high type drops below the reservation wage r firm needs to pay. This implies that the equilibrium number of firms K is determined by the condition H K r > H K+1. (1) Claim 3. In the equilibrium characterized in Proposition 2, there exists a finite number of active firms. Also, number of active firms K is decreasing in worers reservation wage r, while equilibrium unemployment rate is increasing in r. Proof. The first part of the claim follows immediately from the fact that H strictly decreases in, and that K is determined by the condition H K r > H K+1. To show the second part, we note that the measure of worers remain unemployed after round equals R = α(1 β) +(1 α)β. The measure of unemployed worers equals R K. As K decreases in r, R K increases in r. Hence, we conclude that the measure of unemployed worers, also the unemployment rate, strictly increases in the reservation wage r. In the equilibrium, there are α(1 β) K measure of unemployed high type worers and (1 α)β K measure of unemployed low type worers, both increasing with the reservation wage r. In addition, the proportion of high type worers among unemployed worers, α(1 β) K /[α(1 β) K + (1 α)β K ] decreases in K and thus, increases in the reservation wage r. As one interpretation of r could be the minimum wage, the prediction therefore implies that an increase in minimum wage results higher proportion of high productivity worers in the unemployed pool. 3 Heterogeneity in Firm s Productivity Because firms are identical in our basic model, no predictions can be made with respect to the order of hiring by each firm. In this section we consider an extension of the model where firms are ex ante different in terms of their productivities. For convenience, we index firms by the ran order of their productivities, thus firm i has productivity ψ i which rans ith among all firms. Worer type and firm productivity enter the production function multiplicatively. A high type worer hired by firm i produces ψ i units of output, while a low type worer still produces nothing. 9

10 Claim 4. In any equilibrium, active firms profits strictly increase in their production technology ψ i. For two firms, firm i with ψ i and firm j with ψ j, both of which hire a positive measure of worers in an equilibrium, ψ i > ψ j implies Π i > Π j. Proof. Suppose there is an equilibrium in which firm j hires in the -th round at w and employs n measure of high type worers and m measure of low type worers, and generate a profit of Π j = n ψ j ( n + m )w. Firm i could offer w + ǫ and hire in the -th round, mimic firm j s behavior and hire the same measure of high type and low type worers, as the two firms have the same β. Thus it must be that Π i Π i = n ψ i ( n + m )w > Π j. Claim 5. In any equilibrium, the wage offers by active firms strictly decrease. That is, if w is the wage offer for the -th round, then w > w +1 for any. Proof. We prove this result by contradiction. Suppose there were one equilibrium in which the equilibrium wage offers for two consecutive rounds are such that w w +1. Let the applicant pool for the -th round consists of ñ measure of high type, m measure of low type worers. Let firm j be the one that hires in the ( + 1)-round, facing ñ +1 measure of high type and m +1 measure of low type worers. Clearly ñ +1 + m +1 < ñ + m and ñ +1 / m +1 < ñ / m because the firm that hires in round proportionally select better worers from the pool. Thus firm j has an incentive to deviate by offering w + ǫ and get the right to hire in round, where it faces strictly better applicants pool (in terms of both total measure of worers and proportion of high productivity worers) and lower wages. Since firms have to pay at least the reservation wage r > 0, Claim 5 implies that there exists finite number of active firms, which we denote as K. In addition, Claim 4 implies that those active firms will be firms 1, 2,...,K. The next assumption is technical which rules out the possibility that some firms dominate the maret because their productivities are far more superior than others. Assumption 2. The production technology difference is not too large, specifically, { } ψi α(1 β)β + (1 α)β 2 max Ω(α,β) i<j α(1 β)β + (1 α)(1 β) 2. ψ j Claim 6. Under Assumption 2, in equilibrium, no active firms hire any worer they label as l when it is their turn to hire. Proof. Consider firm that hires in the -th round, facing an applicant pool with α proportion of high type and 1 α proportion of low type worers. It is necessary that α w βψ K+1 α β+(1 α, where firm K + 1 is an inactive firm, as otherwise it could offer a )(1 β) wage w + ε and realizes a positive profit. In this case, however, it will not be profitable for any firm to hire worers they label as l signal. This because the expected productivities of those l worers are strictly less than the wage. α (1 β)ψ α (1 β) + (1 α )β < α βψ K+1 α β + (1 α )(1 β) w. 10

11 ( ) The first inequality holds because ψ ψ ψ K+1 max i i<j ψ j < Ω(α,β) < Ω(α,β). Note that for any > 1 we have α < α as the average productivities of the applicant pool deteriorate over time. Claim 7. In any equilibrium, high productivity firms always hire before low productivity firms. Proof. Note first that Claim 4 ensures that all active firms except the last one firm K maes strictly positive profits. This combined with Claim 6 means that those firms will hire all h worers when it is their turn in order to maximize profit. We prove this claim by contradiction again. Suppose this is not the case, then there must exist at least one equilibrium in which one firm s productivity is greater than that of the firm that hires immediately before it. Without loss of generality, let firm j hires in the -th round and firm i hires in the + 1-th round, with ψ j < ψ i. The applicant pool facing firm j at the -th round consists of ñ measure of high type, m measure of low type worers. The expected profit for firm j is Π j = ñ βψ j [ñ β + m (1 β)]w. Suppose firm j wait and post w +1 + ǫ in the + 1-th round, its profit would be Π +1 j Meanwhile,firm i s profit is: = ñ (1 β)βψ j [ñ (1 β)β + m β(1 β)](w +1 + ǫ). Π +1 i = ñ (1 β)βψ i [ñ (1 β)β + m β(1 β)]w +1, and it could post w + ǫ and hire in the -th round, and get a profit of Π i = ñ βψ i [ñ β + m (1 β)](w + ǫ). Equilibrium requires that both firms be maximizing their profits, thus it has to be true that Π i Π +1 i and Π j Π +1 j. Substituting the above profit equations and combining the two inequalities leads to ψ j ψ i, which clearly violates our assumption that ψ j < ψ i. We now characterize the determination of K and the behavior of firm K. Because all firms hiring before K cherry pic the worers that they recognize as high type, the applicant pool left for the K-th round consists of (1 β) K 1 α high type worers and β K 1 (1 α) low type worers. This indicates that the number of active firms is determined by the condition α(1 β) K 1 βψ K α(1 β) K 1 β + (1 α)β K 1 (1 β) r > α(1 β) K βψ K+1 α(1 β) K β + (1 α)β K (1 β). (2) In any equilibrium, the wage offered at each round is such that the firm hires in the next round is indifferent between hiring in the current round and the next. For 11

12 example, in competing the right to hire in the K-th round, firm K + 1, who has the highest productivity among those not hiring, is willing to offer w K K+1 = α(1 β) K 1 βψ K+1 α(1 β) K 1 β + (1 α)β K 1 (1 β). Consequently, any active firm who wins the right to hire in this round has to offer at least this much. However, if wk+1 K happens to be less than worers reservation wage, then the firm has to offer at least r. Clearly, the firm does not have any incentives to offer more than the maximum of r and wk+1 K either. Hence, { } α(1 β) K 1 βψ K+1 w K = max r,. (3) α(1 β) K 1 β + (1 α)β K 1 (1 β) Firm K maes a strictly positive profit unless r = α(1 β) K 1 βψ K α(1 β) K 1 β + (1 α)β K 1 (1 β). (4) In that case, K could hire any positive proportion of worers it labels as h, otherwise it will hire them all. Similarly, profit maximization ensures that w in general is determined by the condition Π +1 = Π+1 +1 such that the firm hires in the + 1 round has no incentive to deviate to one round earlier. The following proposition proves formally that this is an equilibrium. Proposition 3. Under Assumption 2, there exists a unique equilibrium with the following properties: (a) There are K active firms determined by the condition (2). (b) Firms hire according to the ran order of their productivities. That is, firm with ψ hires in the -th round. (c) All active firms hire all worers they thin are of high type but none they thin are of low type. The last hiring firm K, though, hire any proportion of worers it considers as high type should condition (4) holds. (d) Wages decrease in each round. Further, they are recursively determined starting from w K in (3). In general w is determined such that firm + 1 is just indifferent between hiring in the +1-th round at wage w +1 and hiring in the -th round at wage w. (e) All active firms mae positive profits except firm K, which maes zero profit if Condition (4) happens to hold. Total profits decrease strictly with. (f) The equilibrium exhibits a positive relationship between firm size (the measure of worers) and wages. Proof. The uniqueness of such an equilibrium, if it exists, is guaranteed by the previous discussions and claims. Thus we only need to establish existence. 12

13 Given other firms strategies, we show that there is no incentive for any firm to deviate. First, firm has no incentive to hire earlier than the -th round. For any h 0, we have: Π h Π h 1 =(Π h Π h h ) (Π h 1 Π h 1 h ) = β(1 β) h 1 α(ψ ψ h ) β(1 β) h 2 α(ψ ψ h ) > 0 Next, firm has no incentives to hire later than the -th round. For any h 0, wages w +h and w +h+1 are such that Π +h Π +h+1 Π +h +h+1 ) (Π+h+1 Π +h+1 +h+1 ) = β(1 β) +h 1 α(ψ ψ +h+1 ) β(1 β) +h α(ψ ψ +h+1 ) > 0 =(Π +h Given our previous discussions, firm hires β(1 β) 1 α high type worers and (1 β)β 1 (1 α) low type worers. The only exception is that for firm K, if condition (4) holds, firm K maes zero profit, thus it could hire δβ(1 β) K 1 α high type worers and δ(1 β)β K 1 (1 α) low type worers in which 0 < δ 1. (f) simply follows from (c) and (d). 4 Heterogeneity in Firm s Information Technology In this section we extend our basic model in a different direction by assuming firms have different information technologies. Firms are now indexed by the ran order of their information technology, i.e, for two firms i and j, i < j implies that β i > β j. Also, there is imperfect information as for all i, β i (1/2, 1). Claim 8. In any equilibrium, no firm hires all remaining worers when it wins the right to hire. Proof. We show this by contradiction. Suppose firm j hires all worers at round at wage w, then there must be some firms end up being inactive. Also, it must be that w = α, the average productivities of the applicant pool, such that firm j only breas even. Otherwise an inactive firm could bid w + ǫ, hire all worers at round, and mae strictly positive profit. In this case, an inactive firm could deviate by offering w + ǫ at round. It could then hire all worers it labels as h and mae a strictly positive profit, as the average productivities of those worers will be greater than α. Proposition 4. In any equilibrium, profits of active firms strictly increase in their information technology. That is, for two firms i and j that both hire a positive measure of worers, β i > β j implies Π i > Π j. 13

14 Proof. Without loss of generality, suppose there is an equilibrium in which firm j hires in the -th round from an applicant pool with ñ measure of high type worers and m measure of low type worers, at a wage w. Suppose firm j hires δ > 0 proportion of worers it labels as h, and hires δ proportion of those it labels as l. Based on claim 8, it must be that profits from l worers are zero even when those worers are hired. Thus, firm j s total profit is As β i > β j, it can be shown that Π j = δ ñ β j δ [ñ β j + m (1 β j )]w 0. ñ β i [ñ β i + m (1 β i )]w > ñ β j [ñ β j + m (1 β j )]w 0. This is because ñ ñ w + m w 1 β j β j > ñ w > ñ w m w. Therefore, in equilibrium firm i could at least offer w at the -th round and hire all worers it labels as h. Hence Π i Π i = ñ β j [ñ β j + m (1 β j )]w > Π j, and firm i earns a higher profit than firm j in equilibrium. Claim 9. In any equilibrium, number of active firms K is finite. In addition, all active firms except the one with worst information technology among them (which is firm K) hire all worers they label as h. No active firm hires any worer it labels as l. Proof. Following proposition 4, all active firms except the one with lowest β must earn strictly positive profit. Thus to maximize profit, it is necessary for them to hire all h worers given the wage offers. This ensures that worer average productivity strictly deteriorates each round (except for maybe when firm K hires). As reservation wage r is positive, number of active firms K must be finite. To see why firms don t hire l worers, note that in any round it is necessary that wage w is greater than the average productivity of all worers α, otherwise an inactive firm can enter by offering w + ǫ and earn a positive profit by hiring all worers. As the average productivity of worers the firm recognizes as low type is strictly less than α, it is not profitable for the firm to hire any one of them at w. Claim 10. Wage offers strictly decrease in any equilibrium. That is, for any consecutive rounds and + 1, w > w +1. Proof. We prove this by contradiction. Suppose w w +1. Let the applicant pool for the -th round consists of ñ measure of high type and m measure of low type worers. Let firms i and j hire in the -th and ( +1)-th rounds, respectively. Firm j s profit from hiring in the ( + 1)-th round equals Π +1 j = ñ (1 β i )β j [ñ (1 β i )β j + m β i (1 β j )]w +1. As w w +1, it can shown that firm j would deviate to hire in the -th round at w + ǫ and earn a higher level of profit. Π j = ñ β j [ñ β j + m (1 β j ](w + ǫ) > Π +1 j. 14

15 This is because Π j Π+1 j β j ñ β i [ñ β i + m (1 β i ) 1 β j β j ]w > Π i > 0. Hence, there exists no equilibrium such that w w +1. As in the previous section, equilibrium wage offers are determined in a bacward direction. Given Proposition 4, we now that if any equilibrium exists, then it must be firms 1, 2,...,K that are active in the maret, but we are still not sure about the order of hiring. Let the firm who hires last be firm j 1, 2,...,K, then { α[ K wj K =1, j = max r, (1 β } )]β K+1 α[ K =1, j (1 β )]β K+1 + (1 α)[ K =1, j β, ](1 β K+1 ) As firm j has to pay at least the maximum of reservation r and the highest possible offer that firm K + 1 (which has the best information technology among all inactive firms) can mae to brea even. Similarly, the equilibrium wage offered for the (K 1)-th round will be such that the firm that hires in the K-th round is indifferent between hiring in the K-th round and the (K 1)-th round. In general, we now that for a firm to win the right to hire in the -th round, it has to offer a wage no less than the maximum wage firms who hire after the -th round are willing to offer for the -th round. In order to determine the order of hiring in each round, we have the following results: Claim 11. At any round, let the measure of high type and low type worers be ñ and m, respectively. Suppose in equilibrium firm i and j hire at round and + 1, respectively. If ñ < (>) m, then it must be that β i > (<)β j. Proof. See Appendix B. In general, firms remaining in the maret mae a decision regarding whether to bid the highest wage and win the right to hire at the current round, or wait until the next round. Waiting lowers the wage the firm has to pay, but also results an applicant pool with lower average productivity. As the previous claim suggest, the trade-off to some extent depends on the composition of high type and low type worers. In what follows, we separately discusses the two cases when there are at least as many low type worers as high type ones in the maret initially, α 1/2, and when there are more high type worers, α > 1/ Low type worers less than or equal to high type worers When α < 1/2, there are relatively few high type worers in the pool. Thus securing a better applicant pool becomes the main concern for firms, and those with informational advantage will bid aggressively for the right to hire earlier. As a result, firms with larger βs hire earlier than firms with smaller ones. Thus the order of hiring can be uniquely determined. The following proposition summarizes the results. 15

16 Proposition 5. When α < 1/2, there exists a unique equilibrium in which firms hire in the order of information technology. Firms 1, 2,...,K are active in the maret, where K is determined by the condition Proof. See Appendix B. α K 1 (1 β i)β K α K 1 (1 β i)β K + (1 α) K 1 β i(1 β K ) r > (5) α K (1 β i)β K+1 α K (1 β i)β K+1 + (1 α) K β i(1 β K+1 ) Definition 1. The distribution of information technology is not too dispersed if for any two consecutively raned firms i,i+1 with β i and β i+1 respectively, (1 β i )/(1 β i+1 ) β i. Claim 12. When α < 1/2, if the distribution of information technology is not too dispersed, then there exists a positive relationship between firm size and wage. Proof. See Appendix B. When α = 1/2, hiring in the order of information technology (1, 2,...K) is still an equilibrium. However, in certain cases there also exists another equilibrium in which firm 2 hires first, i.e, firms hire in the order (2, 1,...K). Claim 13. When α = 1/2, there exists no equilibrium in which the hiring order is other than (1, 2,...K) or (2, 1,...K). Proof. See Appendix B. Claim 14. When α = 1/2, in the case of K > 2, the number of active firms K is determined by the condition in (5). Hiring in the order of (1, 2,...K) is always an equilibrium. In addition, under certain conditions, there is another equilibrium in which firms hire in the order (2, 1,...K). Proof. See Appendix B. 4.2 More high type worers When α > 1/2, there are relatively abundant high type worers initially in the applicant pool. Thus, firm 1 may find it profitable to wait until later rounds to hire, as suggested by claim 11. While waiting to later rounds costs the firm in terms of the average quality of applicants, the benefit of paying a lower wage may more than offset the cost. Proposition 6. When 1/2 < α β 2, there exists a unique equilibrium in which firms hire in the order of (2, 1,...K), where the number of active firms K is determined by the condition in (5). 16

17 Proof. See Appendix B. In this case, firm 1 is willing to let firm 2 hire first. Because firm 2 s ability in selecting the good candidates is not as good as firm 1 s, firm 1 finds the wage w 2 a bargain price given the quality of the remaining pool. when α > β 2, we consider cases with different K. To start, when K = 1, obviously only firm 1 is active in the maret. This happens under condition that { α(1 β r > 1 )β 2 r, αβ 1 αβ 1 +(1 α)(1 β 1 ) αβ 1 αβ 1 +(1 α)(1 β 1 ). Firm 1 pay a wage of w α(1 β 1 )β 2 +(1 α)β 1 (1 β 2 ) 1 = max When K = 2, both firm 1 and 2 are active in the maret. Based on claim 11, the only possible hiring order is that firm 2 hires before firm 1, then α(1 β 2 )β 1 α(1 β 2 )β 1 + (1 α)β 2 (1 β 1 ) r > α(1 β 1 )(1 β 2 )β 3 α(1 β 1 )(1 β 2 )β 3 + (1 α)β 1 β 2 (1 β 3 ) firm 1 maes a profit of { w 2 = max r, α(1 β 2 )β 3 α(1 β 2 )β 3 + (1 α)β 2 (1 β 3 ) }, Π 2 1 = α(1 β 2 )β 1 [α(1 β 2 )β 1 + (1 α)β 2 (1 β 1 )]w 2, Note that w 1 is determined by the condition Π 1 1 = Π 2 1, where Π 1 1 = αβ 1 [αβ 1 + (1 α)(1 β 1 )]w 1. Thus w 1 = αβ 1β 2 + [α(1 β 2 )β 1 + (1 α)β 2 (1 β 1 )]w 2, αβ 1 + (1 α)(1 β 1 ) Π 1 2 = αβ 2 [αβ 2 + (1 α)(1 β 2 )]w 1, Π 2 2 = α(1 β 1 )β 2 [α(1 β 1 )β 2 + (1 α)β 1 (1 β 2 )]w 2, We can chec that Π 1 2 > Π 2 2, thus as long as the condition Π holds, three exists an equilibrium in which firm 2 hires before firm 1. Otherwise no equilibrium exists. When K 3, no equilibrium exist. This is summarized by the following claim. Proposition 7. When α > β 2, no equilibrium exists if the number of active firms K 3, in which K is determined by condition (5). Proof. See Appendix B. In this case, no order of hiring is stable; no equilibrium exists. However, the significance of this result should not be overemphasized. Note that α(1 β 2 ) > (1 α)β 2 if and only if β 2 < α, which requires the proportion of high type worers in the maret to be high while at the same time the information technology β of firms other than firm 1 not very accurate. Hence, this case is at most a rarity rather than a norm. }. 17

18 5 Related Literature Our paper is closely related to the vast literature of labor maret search and matching. Although these models sometimes generate similar implications as we do, the types of frictions under consideration are quite different. Random search models typically assume that worers do not fully now potential jobs, thus have to either wait for a time period or incur a direct cost to sample from the pool of job offers. In the onthe-job search model of Burdett and Mortensen (1998), worers search randomly and gradually move from low paying jobs to high paying jobs. Identical firms offer different wages in the equilibrium, as those who offer higher wages attract more worers at the expense of enjoying lower per worer profit. Thus the model also generates size-wage premium in the equilibrium, a well-established but puzzling empirical regularity in labor maret 8. However, their underlying intuition is quite different than ours. Because worers are homogeneous in their model, large firms pay more to eep a larger worforce. In our model, large firms are willing to pay more because they want to select better worers from a heterogeneous population of job candidates. The directed search literature restricts the number of jobs a worer can apply at a time, thus creates a coordination problem among fellow job seeers. In Shimer (2005), heterogeneous worers and firms interact in a static environment. The model generates wage dispersion as well as positive sorting of worers and firms. However, it does not predict size-wage premium as a firm is just characterized by one job vacancy. On the other hand, Shimer (2005) captures the coexistence of unemployment and job vacancies, which is beyond the scope of this paper. Shimer (2005) also consider more general production functions. Similarly, Acemoglu and Shimer (2000) study how labor maret coordination friction also induce ex ante firms to adopt different technologies. Albrecht et al. (2006) allow worers to mae multiple (but still fixed number of) applications. Many macroeconomic models of labor maret rely on an aggregate matching function without specifying the exact source of maret frictions (see Pissarides 2000). The micro-foundations of a well-performed matching function includes random search (urn-ball model), coordination friction, the stoc-flow analysis of Coles and Smith (1998), and model of Lagos (2000) which considers optimal decisions across spatially distinct locations. Our paper also falls into the large literature on labor maret information that dates bac at least to Stigler (1962), who studies information about jobs for worers and initiated the whole search literature. Spence (1973) shows how high productivity job applicants could send costly signals to prospective employers in order to be 8 Moore (1911) first documented this phenomenon for worers at Italian textile mills. For studies in U.S., see Lester (1967), Personic and Barsy (1982), Mellow (1982), Brown and Medoff (1989), Brown et al. (1990), Idson and Feaster (1990), Trose (1999). For studies in U.K. and other European countries, see Main and Reilly (1993), Green et al. (1996), Abowd et al. (1999), Albæ et al. (1998), Winter-Ebmer and Zweimüller (1999). Similar findings are also reported in developing countries, see e.g. Velenchi (1997), Schaffner (1998), and Söderbom et al. (2005). The seminal paper of Brown and Medoff (1989) examine a variety of potential explanations but still find sizable wage differentials unexplained. 18

19 separated from low productivity worers. Similarly, the statistical discrimination literature (for example, Coate and Loury 1993, Moro and Norman 2004) analyzes how personal characteristics such as race and gender can be used to form conditional expectations in labor marets with imperfection information, and lead to self-fulfilling vicious cycles. More recently, Grossman (2004) demonstrates that the combination of imperfect information with national differences in the dispersion of worer talents can be an independent source of comparative advantage, and lead to trade in two otherwise identical countries. Grossman (2004) motivates imperfect information with team wor in production and labels this incomplete labor contract, as no contract can be written conditional on each individual worer s marginal product. Recently, there is also a growing literature exploring the role of private information in the framewor of search. This includes Guerrieri (2008), Faig and Jerez (2005), and Guerrieri et al. (2008). These models combine search (coordination) friction with imperfect information, thus are different from our model. Their predictions are also different from ours. 6 Conclusions Information plays a very important role in many job maret. With perfect information, the law of one price must hold, with worers of identical productive capabilities being paid equal wages. However, real world labor contract are seldom perfect as employer may have imperfect nowledge of worers productivities. In this case, competing force is not enough to ensure worers are paid according to their talents. Worers of different abilities can be paid the same wage, while worers of the same ability can be paid differently. In this paper we exploit this intuition and analyze a model of cherry picing by firms that have imperfect nowledge of worers productivities. The cherry-picing process by firms most resembles the junior faculty recruiting process at the North American job maret for economists. We show that the combination of competition and imperfect information will generate wage dispersion. In addition, there is a positive relationship between firm size and wage. Therefore, our model has offered an alternative way of understanding the puzzling size-wage premium phenomenon in the labor maret. Although we consider firms in a given industry in our model, the analysis can be extended to understand inter-industry wage structures (See e.g. Krueger and Summers 1988). Treating one industry as a firm, if some industries have higher productivity, then they will draw from the worer pool first, but only imperfectly. Thus, controlling for worer heterogeneity, there will be a industry wage premium not explained under competitive setting. Note that this ind of industry wage differentials are hard to be rationalized under alternative model such as Burdett and Mortensen (1998) and Shimer (2005). 19

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER November 2011 Introduction Search and

More information

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Neel Rao University at Buffalo, SUNY August 26, 2016 Abstract This paper integrates asymmetric information between firms into a canonical

More information

Module 16: Signaling

Module 16: Signaling Module 16: Signaling Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis Players with private information can take some action to signal their type. Taking this action would distinguish them from other types.

More information

Directed Search with Multiple Vacancies

Directed Search with Multiple Vacancies Directed Search with Multiple Vacancies Benjamin Lester University of Western Ontario July 9, 2008 Abstract Preliminary and incomplete: please do not circulate. Contact: blester@uwo.ca. I would like to

More information

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7 EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7 Leonardo Felli NAB.2.14 27 February 2014 Signalling Games Consider the following Bayesian game: Set of players: N = {N, S, }, Nature N strategy

More information

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I Lecture 11 Instructor: Tommaso Nannicini Teaching Fellow: Jeremy Bowles Harvard University November 9, 2017 Overview * Today s lecture Dynamic games of incomplete

More information

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER May 27, 2011 Introduction Search and

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 3. Dynamic games of incomplete information Chapter 3. Job Market Signaling Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha

More information

Thema Working Paper n Université de Cergy Pontoise, France

Thema Working Paper n Université de Cergy Pontoise, France Thema Woring Paper n 2014-11 Université de Cergy Pontoise, France "Wage Differentials: Trade Openness and Wage Bargaining" Gustavo Gonzaga Beatriz Muriel Cristina Terra May, 2014 Wage Differentials: Trade

More information

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information) Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan 200 Good luck!!! Question (duopoly games with imperfect information) Consider a duopoly game in which the inverse demand function is linear where it is positive

More information

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University March 2016 D. Liu (NJU) DMP 03/16 1 / 35 Introduction Motivation In the previous lecture, McCall s model was introduced McCall s model

More information

Equilibrium Refinements

Equilibrium Refinements Equilibrium Refinements Mihai Manea MIT Sequential Equilibrium In many games information is imperfect and the only subgame is the original game... subgame perfect equilibrium = Nash equilibrium Play starting

More information

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Gagan Ghosh Bingchao Huangfu Heng Liu October 19, 2017 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: COMMENTS WELCOME) Abstract We study wars of attrition between two bidders who

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Mortenson Pissarides Model

Mortenson Pissarides Model Mortenson Pissarides Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 November 22, 2017 1 / 47 Mortenson / Pissarides Model Search models are popular in many contexts: labor markets, monetary theory, etc. They are distinguished

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities

On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities James Albrecht Georgetown University, CESifo, and IZA Carlos Carrillo-Tudela University of Essex, CEPR, CESifo, and IZA Susan Vroman Georgetown University,

More information

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals Liping Tang Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh PA 15213, USA Abstract. Crawford and Sobel s Cheap Talk model [1] describes an information

More information

THE POSTDOC VARIANT OF THE SECRETARY PROBLEM 1. INTRODUCTION.

THE POSTDOC VARIANT OF THE SECRETARY PROBLEM 1. INTRODUCTION. THE POSTDOC VARIANT OF THE SECRETARY PROBLEM ROBERT J. VANDERBEI ABSTRACT. The classical secretary problem involves sequentially interviewing a pool of n applicants with the aim of hiring exactly the best

More information

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Applications and Interviews: Firms' Recruiting Decisions in a Frictional Labor Market

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Applications and Interviews: Firms' Recruiting Decisions in a Frictional Labor Market University of Toronto Department of Economics Working Paper 522 Applications and Interviews: Firms' Recruiting Decisions in a Frictional Labor Market By Ronald Wolthoff November 10, 2014 Applications and

More information

Working Time Reduction, Unpaid Overtime Work and Unemployment

Working Time Reduction, Unpaid Overtime Work and Unemployment Working Time Reduction Unpaid Overtime Work and Unemployment Makoto Masui Department of Economics Soka University 1-236 Tangi-cho Hachiouji-city Tokyo 192-8577 Japan First Version: April 2007 Second Version:

More information

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Julan Du Chinese University of Hong Kong Yi Lu University of Hong Kong Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Abstract In acquiring the same intermediate inputs, a firm

More information

A Centralized or a Decentralized Labor Market?

A Centralized or a Decentralized Labor Market? ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers A Centralized or a Decentralized Labor Market? Juha Virrankoski Aalto University and HECER Discussion Paper No. 42 November

More information

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Teoria das organizações e contratos Teoria das organizações e contratos Chapter 6: Adverse Selection with two types Mestrado Profissional em Economia 3 o trimestre 2015 EESP (FGV) Teoria das organizações e contratos 3 o trimestre 2015 1

More information

Online Appendix to Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Online Appendix to Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Online Appendix to Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Neel Rao University at Buffalo, SUNY August 26, 2016 Abstract The online appendix extends the analysis to the case where

More information

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication Regis Barnichon Yanos Zylberberg July 21, 2016 This online Appendix contains a more comprehensive description

More information

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Tilburg University On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Publication date: 1997 Link to publication General rights Copyright and

More information

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Roberto Bonilla Department of Economics University of Newcastle Business School University of Newcastle upon Tyne Newcastle upon Tyne U.K.

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium / 22 Bayesian Nash equilibrium and dynamic games L M R 3 2 L R L R 2 2 L R L 2,, M,2, R,3,3 2 NE and 2 SPNE (only subgame!) 2 / 22 Non-credible

More information

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment Timothy Mathews and Soiliou Daw Namoro Abstract. A model of two tournaments, each with a field of

More information

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101 3 Tournaments 3.1 Motivation General idea Firms can use competition between agents for 1 incentive and 2 selection purposes We mainly focus on incentives 3 / 101 Main characteristics Agents fulll similar

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations

Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations By GUIDO MENZIO AND SHOUYONG SHI In models of search on the job (e.g. Kenneth Burdett and Dale Mortensen 1998, Burdett and Melvyn Coles

More information

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX Monika Mrázová University of Geneva and CEPR J. Peter Neary University of Oxford, CEPR and CESifo Appendix K: Selection into Worker Screening

More information

Sequential Games with Incomplete Information

Sequential Games with Incomplete Information Sequential Games with Incomplete Information Debraj Ray, November 6 For the remaining lectures we return to extensive-form games, but this time we focus on imperfect information, reputation, and signalling

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT. Melvyn G. Coles Dale T.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT. Melvyn G. Coles Dale T. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT Melvyn G. Coles Dale T. Mortensen Working Paper 17284 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17284

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 2. Dynamic games of complete information Chapter 2. Two-stage games of complete but imperfect information Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas

More information

ECO421: Signaling. Marcin P ski. March 26, 2018

ECO421: Signaling. Marcin P ski. March 26, 2018 ECO421: Signaling Marcin P ski March 26, 2018 Plan Introduction Education Suits Signaling everywhere Conclusion Introduction Signaling games We talked about communication cheap talk veriable talk Talk

More information

Endogenous information acquisition

Endogenous information acquisition Endogenous information acquisition ECON 101 Benhabib, Liu, Wang (2008) Endogenous information acquisition Benhabib, Liu, Wang 1 / 55 The Baseline Mode l The economy is populated by a large representative

More information

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion:

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: Interpretation and Step-by-Step Examples Ana Espínola-Arredondo School of Economic Sciences Washington State University Pullman, WA 99164 Félix Muñoz-García y School

More information

McCall Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. November 22, Econ720

McCall Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. November 22, Econ720 McCall Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 November 22, 2017 1 / 30 Motivation We would like to study basic labor market data: unemployment and its duration wage heterogeneity among seemingly identical

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal

The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal Timothy Perri* Revised May 13, 2013 Abstract More able individuals may over-invest in education when education

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

The Harris-Todaro model

The Harris-Todaro model Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics July 3, 2006 The Harris-Todaro model In two seminal papers, Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) have developed a canonical model of rural-urban

More information

Directed Search with Multiple Job Applications. Manolis Galenianos, Philipp A. Kircher

Directed Search with Multiple Job Applications. Manolis Galenianos, Philipp A. Kircher ÓÒÒ ÓÒ Ù ÓÒ È Ô Ö Discussion Paper 20/2005 Directed Search with Multiple Job Applications by Manolis Galenianos, Philipp A. Kircher June 2005 ÓÒÒ Ö Ù Ø Ë ÓÓÐ Ó ÓÒÓÑ Ô ÖØÑ ÒØ Ó ÓÒÓÑ ÍÒ Ú Ö ØÝ Ó ÓÒÒ Ò Ù

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry! Econ 0A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sry! This Problem set tests the knowledge that you accumulated mainly in lectures 2 to 26. The problem set is focused

More information

Manolis Galenianos, Philipp Kircher and Gabor Virag Market power and efficiency in a search model

Manolis Galenianos, Philipp Kircher and Gabor Virag Market power and efficiency in a search model Manolis Galenianos, Philipp Kircher and Gabor Virag Market power and efficiency in a search model Article (Submitted version) (Pre-refereed) Original citation: Galenianos, Manolis and Kircher, Philipp

More information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information joint with Stephen Morris (Princeton University) November 2010 Payoff Environment in games with incomplete information, the agents are uncertain

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation

Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation Yangbo Song November 10, 2014 Abstract I study the problem of social learning in a model where agents move sequentially. Each agent receives a private

More information

Simultaneous Search with Heterogeneous Firms and Ex Post Competition

Simultaneous Search with Heterogeneous Firms and Ex Post Competition Simultaneous Search with Heterogeneous Firms and Ex Post Competition Pieter A. Gautier Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute Ronald P. Wolthoff Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam and Tinbergen

More information

A Pure Theory of Wage Dispersion

A Pure Theory of Wage Dispersion A Pure Theory of Wage Dispersion Cheng Wang and Youzhi Yang February 13, 2017 Abstract We look for equilibrium wage dispersion in a labor market model with search and on-the-job search, identical firms

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan

Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan David Atkin, Azam Chaudhry, Shamyla Chaudry Amit K. Khandelwal and Eric Verhoogen Sept. 016 Appendix B: Theory

More information

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017 G5212: Game Theory Mark Dean Spring 2017 Signalling We will now move to consider a simple model of costly signalling The classic example of this is the education signalling model by Spence [1973] Different

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Monika Köppl-Turyna Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Winter 2017/2018 Static Games of Incomplete Information Introduction So far we assumed that payoff functions

More information

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar ABSTRACT We study a model of social learning with partial observations from

More information

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 16 Feb 2012

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 16 Feb 2012 Implementing Optimal Outcomes in Social Computing: A Game-Theoretic Approach arxiv:1202.3480v1 [cs.gt] 16 Feb 2012 Arpita Ghosh Yahoo! Research Santa Clara, CA, USA arpita@yahoo-inc.com February 17, 2012

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale

Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale Rod Garratt, Thomas Tröger, and Charles Zheng September 29, 2006 Abstract In second-price or English auctions involving symmetric, independent,

More information

Uncertainty. Michael Peters December 27, 2013

Uncertainty. Michael Peters December 27, 2013 Uncertainty Michael Peters December 27, 20 Lotteries In many problems in economics, people are forced to make decisions without knowing exactly what the consequences will be. For example, when you buy

More information

Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium Veronica Guerrieri University of Chicago Randall Wright University of Pennsylvania February 2, 2009 Robert Shimer University of Chicago Abstract We extend

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 3. Dynamic games of incomplete information Chapter 2. Signaling Games Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Job Search Models. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. February 12, 2016

Job Search Models. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. February 12, 2016 Job Search Models Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania February 12, 2016 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Job Search February 12, 2016 1 / 57 Motivation Introduction Trade in the labor

More information

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007 Costly Expertise Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz Current Version: December, 007 In many environments expertise is costly. Costs can manifest themselves in numerous ways, ranging from the time that is required

More information

Credence Goods and Vertical Product Differentiation: The Impact of Labeling Policies* Ian Sheldon (Ohio State University)

Credence Goods and Vertical Product Differentiation: The Impact of Labeling Policies* Ian Sheldon (Ohio State University) Credence Goods and Vertical Product Differentiation: The Impact of Labeling Policies* Ian Sheldon (Ohio State University) Seminar: North Dakota State University, Fargo, ND, May, 6 * Draws on Roe and Sheldon

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Adverse Selection, Signaling, and Screening in Markets

Adverse Selection, Signaling, and Screening in Markets BGPE Intensive Course: Contracts and Asymmetric Information Adverse Selection, Signaling, and Screening in Markets Anke Kessler Anke Kessler p. 1/27 Stylized Facts: Market Failure used cars, even if they

More information

JOB SEARCH WITH BIDDER MEMORIES*

JOB SEARCH WITH BIDDER MEMORIES* INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 52, No. 3, August 2011 JOB SEARCH WITH BIDDER MEMORIES* BY CARLOS CARRILLO-TUDELA, GUIDO MENZIO, AND ERIC SMITH 1 University of Essex, U.K.; University of Pennsylvania,

More information

LEM. New Results on Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Role of Luck. Giulio Bottazzi Daniele Giachini

LEM. New Results on Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Role of Luck. Giulio Bottazzi Daniele Giachini LEM WORKING PAPER SERIES New Results on Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Role of Luck Giulio Bottazzi Daniele Giachini Institute of Economics, Scuola Sant'Anna, Pisa, Italy 2018/08 February

More information

Screening and Adverse Selection in Frictional Markets

Screening and Adverse Selection in Frictional Markets Screening and Adverse Selection in Frictional Markets Benjamin Lester Philadelphia Fed Venky Venkateswaran NYU Stern Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones Carnegie Mellon University May 2015 Disclaimer:

More information

Effi ciency in Search and Matching Models: A Generalized Hosios Condition

Effi ciency in Search and Matching Models: A Generalized Hosios Condition Effi ciency in Search and Matching Models: A Generalized Hosios Condition Sephorah Mangin and Benoît Julien 22 September 2017 Abstract When is the level of entry of buyers or sellers effi cient in markets

More information

Compliance with the Institutional Wage in Dualistic Models. Ana Paula Martins. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2011 ISSN:

Compliance with the Institutional Wage in Dualistic Models. Ana Paula Martins. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2011 ISSN: EERI Economics and Econometrics Research Institute Compliance with the Institutional Wage in Dualistic Models Ana Paula Martins EERI Research Paper Series No 5/20 ISSN: 203-4892 EERI Economics and Econometrics

More information

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts Advanced Microeconomic Theory: Economics 521b Spring 2011 Juuso Välimäki Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts The setup is similar to that of a Bayesian game. The ingredients are: 1. Set of players, i {1,

More information

Sorting via Screening vs. Signaling

Sorting via Screening vs. Signaling Sorting via Screening vs. Signaling - Static Frame and Experimental Evidence - Werner Güth and Fabian Winter 1. Introduction 2. Static Frame 3. Experimental Design 4. Main Findings 5. Conclusions 1. Introduction

More information

. Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 8: Dynamic Bayesian Games. HUANG Haifeng University of California, Merced

. Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 8: Dynamic Bayesian Games. HUANG Haifeng University of California, Merced .. Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 8: Dynamic Bayesian Games HUANG Haifeng University of California, Merced Basic terminology Now we study dynamic Bayesian games, or dynamic/extensive games of

More information

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation Roland Bénabou Jean Tirole. Review of Economic Studies 2003 Bénabou and Tirole Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation 1 / 30 Motivation Should a child be rewarded for passing

More information

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1 Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder Jinwoo Kim We study the efficiency of standard auctions with interdependent values in which one of two bidders is perfectly informed of his value while

More information

Markets with Asymetric Information

Markets with Asymetric Information Microeconomics 2 Presentation: Francis Bloch, Slides: Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics March 6, 2017 (Lecture 9) I. Asymmetric information I.1. Introduction The economy is fundamentally

More information

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory Spring 2017 Lars Calmfors Literature: Chapter 7 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: 435-445 1 Topics Weakly efficient bargaining Strongly efficient bargaining

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Why Master s Programs in Top Schools Thrive

Why Master s Programs in Top Schools Thrive Why Master s Programs in Top Schools Thrive Lizi Yu September 2, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the choice of education by considering education as a signal of productivity in the job market. Based on

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago December 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) represent random

More information

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Deniz Dizdar 1 1 Department of Economics, University of Montréal September 15, 2014 1/33 Investments and matching 2/33

More information

Credible Ratings. Ettore Damiano, Li, Hao University of Toronto. Wing Suen The University of Hong Kong. March 7, 2008

Credible Ratings. Ettore Damiano, Li, Hao University of Toronto. Wing Suen The University of Hong Kong. March 7, 2008 Credible Ratings Ettore Damiano, Li, Hao University of Toronto Wing Suen The University of Hong Kong March 7, 2008 Abstract: This paper considers a model of a rating agency with multiple clients, in which

More information

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive An adaptation of Pissarides (990) by using random job destruction rate Huiming Wang December 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/203/ MPRA Paper No. 203, posted

More information

Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster

Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster Marcelo Arbex Dennis O Dea David Wiczer University of Windsor University of Washington Fed Reserve Bank of St. Louis. October 3, 2016 The views expressed herein

More information

Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications

Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 719 Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications James Albrecht Pieter Gautier Susan Vroman February 003 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago September 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) introduce a

More information

Economics 385: Suggested Solutions 2

Economics 385: Suggested Solutions 2 Economics 385: Suggested Solutions 2 7 March, 2007 Signalling Question 1 (Discrete Action Set) (a) In the separating equilibrium, e (10) = e 1. The high type needs to obtain enough education to separate

More information

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Emir Kamenica and Matthew Gentzkow University of Chicago June 2010 1 Persuasion mechanisms In this paper we study a particular game where Sender chooses a signal π whose

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 1 [1] In this problem (see FT Ex. 1.1) you are asked to play with arbitrary 2 2 games just to get used to the idea of equilibrium computation. Specifically, consider the

More information