Optimal Dividend Strategies for Two Collaborating Insurance Companies

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal Dividend Strategies for Two Collaborating Insurance Companies"

Transcription

1 Optimal Dividend Strategies for Two Collaborating Insurance Companies Hansjörg Albrecher, Pablo Azcue and Nora Muler Abstract We consider a two-dimensional optimal dividend problem in the context of two insurance companies with compound Poisson surplus processes, who collaborate by paying each other s deficit when possible. We solve the stochastic control problem of maximizing the weighted sum of expected discounted dividend payments among all admissible dividend strategies until ruin of both companies, by extending results of univariate optimal control theory. In the case that the dividends paid by the two companies are equally weighted, the value function of this problem compares favorably with the one of merging the two companies completely. We identify the optimal value function as the smallest viscosity supersolution of the respective Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation and provide an iterative approach to approximate it numerically. Curve strategies are identified as the natural analogue of barrier strategies in this two-dimensional context. A numerical example is given for which such a curve strategy is indeed optimal among all admissible dividend strategies, and for which this collaboration mechanism also outperforms the suitably weighted optimal dividend strategies of the two stand-alone companies.. Introduction Ever since de Finetti [4] proposed in 957 to measure the value of an insurance portfolio by the expected discounted sum of dividends paid during the lifetime of the portfolio, it has been of particular interest to determine the optimal dividend payment strategy which maximizes this quantity. More than that, this field of research over the years turned out to be a challenging and fascinating area, combining tools from analysis, probability and stochastic control. In 969, Gerber [5] showed that if the free surplus of an insurance portfolio is modelled by a compound Poisson risk model, it is optimal to pay dividends according to a so-called band strategy, which collapses to a barrier strategy for exponentially distributed claim amounts. Whereas Gerber found this result by taking a limit of an associated discrete problem, this optimal dividend problem was studied with techniques of modern stochastic control theory in Azcue and Muler [7], see e.g. Schmidli [22] for a detailed overview. Since then the optimal dividend problem was studied for many different model setups, objective functions and side constraints we refer to Albrecher and Thonhauser [2] and Avanzi [4] for surveys on the subject. A barrier strategy with barrier b pays out dividends whenever the surplus level of the portfolio is above b, so that the surplus level stays at b, and pays no dividends below that barrier b. The most general criteria currently available for barrier strategies to be optimal can be found in Loeffen and Renaud [2]. The optimality of barrier strategies when including the time value of ruin was studied in [24], and when including capital injections by shareholders Department of Actuarial Science, Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Lausanne, CH-5 Lausanne and Swiss Finance Institute. Supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation Project Departamento de Matematicas, Universidad Torcuato Di Tella. Av. Figueroa Alcorta 735 C428BIJ Ciudad de Buenos Aires, Argentina.

2 in Kulenko and Schmidli [8]. All these control problems have been formulated and studied in the one-dimensional framework. However, in recent years there has been an increased interest in risk theory in considering the dynamics of several connected insurance portfolios simultaneously, see e.g. Asmussen and Albrecher [3, Ch.XIII.9] for an overview. Ruin probability expressions for a two-dimensional risk process are studied in Avram et al. [5, 6] for simultaneous claim arrivals and proportional claim sizes and recently in Badila et al. [] and Ivanovs and Boxma [7] in a more general framework. In Azcue and Muler [8], the problem of optimally transferring capital between two portfolios in the presence of transaction costs was considered, see also Badescu et al. []. Czarna and Palmowski [3] study the dividend problem and impulse control for two insurance companies who share claim payments and premiums in some specified proportion for a particular dividend strategy. It turns out that these multi-dimensional problems, albeit practically highly relevant, quickly become very intricate and explicit solutions can typically not be obtained without very strong assumptions. In this paper, we would like to extend the optimal dividend problem from univariate risk theory to a two-dimensional setup of two collaborating companies. The collaboration consists of paying the deficit bailing out of the partner company if its surplus is negative and if this financial help can be afforded with the current own surplus level. We solve the problem of maximizing the weighted sum of expected discounted dividend payments until ruin of both companies. A natural question in this context is whether such a collaboration procedure can be advantageous over merging the two companies completely; we will show that this is the case when the dividends paid by the two companies are equally weighted. For criteria of a merger being an advantage over keeping two stand-alone companies under pre-defined barrier strategies and marginal diffusion processes, see e.g. Gerber and Shiu [6], for the performance of another pre-defined risk and profit sharing arrangement, see e.g. Albrecher and Lautscham []. Our goal here is, however, to address the general problem of identifying the optimal dividend strategy among all admissible dividend strategies for each company under this collaboration framework. This leads to a fully two-dimensional stochastic control problem, and to the question what the natural analogues of the optimal univariate barrier strategies are in two dimensions. The particular structure of the collaboration implemented in this paper will turn out not to be essential, so the techniques may be applicable to other risk-sharing mechanisms as well. Yet, the concrete specification allows to carry through the necessary analysis of the stochastic control problem explicitly by way of example. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we introduce the model and the stochastic control problem in detail and derive some simple properties of the corresponding value function V. In Section 3 we prove that V is a viscosity solution of the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation for independent surplus processes, and in Section 4 we show that V is in fact its smallest viscosity supersolution. Section 5 provides an iterative approach to approximate the value function V, together with the analogous verification steps at each iteration step. Section 6 discusses the stationary dividend strategies that appear in our model, and in Section 7 we establish curve strategies as the appropriate analogues of the univariate barrier strategies. Finally, Section 8 shows how to constructively search for optimal curve strategies and in Section 9 an explicit numerical example for the symmetric and equally weighted case with exponentially distributed claim sizes is worked out for which such a curve strategy is indeed optimal among all admissible bivariate dividend strategies. It is then also illustrated that for this case the proposed type of collaboration is preferable to adding the best-possible stand-alone profits. 2

3 2. Model We consider two insurance companies, Company One and Company Two, which have an agreement to collaborate. Let us call X t the free surplus of Company One and Y t the one of Company Two. We assume that the free surplus of each of the companies follows a Cramér- Lundberg process, i.e. a compound Poisson process with drift given by 2. { X t = x + t Nt i= U i Y t = y + t Nt 2 i= U 2 i, where x and y are the respective initial surplus levels; and are the respective premium rates; U k i is the size of the i-th claim of Company k, which are i.i.d. random variables with continuous distribution F k for k =, 2; Nt and Nt 2 are Poisson processes with intensity λ and λ 2, respectively. We assume here that the processes Nt, Nt 2 and the random variables U i, U 2 i are all independent of each other. There is a rule of collaboration signed by the two companies: if the current surplus of Company One becomes negative, Company Two should cover the exact deficit of Company One as long as it does not ruin itself, and vice versa. Ruin of a company hence occurs when its surplus becomes negative and the other company cannot cover this deficit. A simulated surplus trajectory under this collaboration rule is shown in Figure.. In this trajectory the surplus of Company Two becomes negative after its first claim, so Company One covers the deficit. Afterwards, a claim of Company One arrives and since Company Two cannot cover this deficit, Company One gets ruined. Two helps One 2 Ruin Comp.One x,y 2 2 One helps Two 2 Ruin Comp.Two Fig..: Surplus process under the collaboration rules. Both companies use part of their surplus to pay dividends to their shareholders. The dividend payment strategy L = L t,l 2 t is the total amount of dividends paid by the two companies up to time t. Let us call τi k the arrival time of the i-th claim of company k, with k =, 2. We define the associated controlled process Xt L, Yt L with initial surplus levels x, y as 2.2 { Xt L = X t L t + C 2, t C,2 t Yt L = Y t L 2 t + C,2 t C 2, t, 3

4 where N t C 2, t = i= I { X L τ i <,Y L τ i +X L τ i X L τ i corresponds to the cumulative amount transferred from Company Two to Company One up to time t in order to cover the deficit of Company One and N t 2 C,2 t = i= I { Y L τ 2 i <,Y L τ i 2 +X L τ i 2 Y L corresponds to the cumulative amount transferred from Company One to Company Two up to time t in order to cover the deficit of Company Two. Let us call τ the time at which only one company remains because it cannot cover the deficit of the other, more precisely, { 2.3 τ = inf t : Xt L τ 2 i + Yt L <. Note that since the claim arrival processes of the companies are independent, the probability of simultaneous ruin is zero. The process Xt L, Yt L is defined for t τ. We say that the dividend payment strategy L = L t,l 2 t is admissible if it is non-decreasing, càglàd left continuous with right limits, t τ predictable with respect to the filtration generated by the bivariate process X t, Y t, and satisfies { L t X t + C 2, t C,2 t, L 2 t Y t + C,2 t C 2, t. This last condition means that the companies are not allowed to pay more dividends than their current surplus. Let us call R 2 + the first quadrant. We denote by Π x,y the set of admissible dividend strategies with initial surplus levels x, y R 2 +. Our objective is to maximize the weighted average of the expected discounted dividends paid by the two companies until ruin of both companies. Note that after time τ, the surviving company can continue to pay dividends up to its own ruin. Let us define Vk k =, 2 as the optimal value function of the onedimensional problem of maximizing the expected discounted dividends until ruin of Company k alone. So, for any initial surplus levels x, y R 2 +, we can write down the optimal value function as 2.4 V x, y = sup L Π x,y V L x, y, where τ 2.5 V L x, y = E x,y a e δs dl s + e δτ V Xτ L + a 2 τ e δs dl 2 s + e δτ V2 Yτ L. Here, δ > is a constant discount factor, and a [, ] and a 2 = a are the weights of the dividends paid by Company One and Company Two respectively. The functions Vk k =, 2 are zero in, so depending on which company goes to ruin at τ, either V X τ = or V2 Y τ =. The optimal dividend strategy corresponding to 2.4 may be regarded as the best dividend payment strategy from the point of view of a shareholder who owns a proportion ma of the total shares of Company One and a proportion ma 2 of the total shares of Company Two for some < m min {/a, /a 2. An important particular case is a = a 2 = /2, in which the dividends paid by the two companies are equally weighted for an earlier example of weighting separate terms in the objective function in the univariate dividend context, see Radner and Shepp [2]. 4

5 Remark 2.. In case the two companies are owned by the same shareholders, another possibility of collaboration between the two companies is merging, in which case the companies put together all their surplus, pay the claims of both companies and pay dividends up to time τ at which the joined surplus becomes negative see e.g. Gerber and Shiu [6]. Given the initial surplus levels x, y, we can interpret any admissible dividend payment strategy L t t for the merger as an admissible collaborating one as follows L t = t Xt L X t L+Y t L dl t, L 2 t = t Yt L X t L+Y t L Since L t is constant for t τ = τ, the surviving company does not pay any dividends here. So V L defined in 2.5 for a = a 2 = /2, satisfies τ 2V L x, y > 2E x,y e δs dl s + τ τ e δs dl 2 s = E x+y e δs dl s. 2 2 The last expected value is the value function of the merger dividend strategy L t t. We conclude that the optimal collaborating strategy for equally weighted dividend payments is better than the optimal merger strategy. Both optimal value functions V and V 2 corresponding to the stand-alone companies have an ultimately linear growth with slope one and they are Lipschitz, see for instance Azcue and Muler [7]. Let us state some basic results about regularity and growth at infinity of the optimal value function V defined in 2.4. From now on, let us call λ := λ + λ 2 and p := a + a 2. dl t. Lemma 2.2. The optimal value function is well defined and satisfies for all x, y R 2 +. a x + a 2y + p δ + λ V x, y ax + a2y + p δ Proof. The proof of the second inequality is similar to the one of Proposition.2 of Azcue and Muler [9]: For any initial surplus levels x, y R 2 +, x + t and y + t are upper bounds for the surplus levels of Company One and Company Two at time t, respectively even after the ruin time τ of one of the companies, so the cumulative dividends paid by Company One and Company Two up to time t are less than or equal to x + t and y + t, respectively. So V x, y a e δs dx + s I {s> + a 2 e δs dy + si {s> = a x + a 2y + p δ. In order to obtain the first inequality, consider the admissible strategy L = L t,l 2 t in which each company pays the initial surplus immediately, and then pays the incoming premium up to time τ that coincides with the first claim arrival time τ = τ τ 2 ; we have, V x, y V L x, y τ a x + a 2y + E, e δs pds = a x + a 2y + p. δ+λ Lemma 2.3. The optimal value function V is increasing in both x and y, locally Lipschitz and satisfies for any x, y R 2 +, a h V x + h, y V x, y e δ+λh/ V x, y and for any h >. a 2h V x, y + h V x, y e δ+λh/ V x, y 5

6 Proof. Let us prove the inequalities at the top, the ones at the bottom are similar. Given any ε >, take an admissible strategy L Π x,y such that V L x, y V x, y ε. We define the strategy L Π x+h,y for h > as follows: Pay immediately an amount h of the surplus of Company One as dividends and then follow the strategy L. We have that and so V L x + h, y = V L x, y + a h 2.6 V x + h, y V L x, y + a h > V x, y + a h ε. Consider also an admissible strategy L 2 Π x+h,y such that V x+h, y V L 2x+h, y ε and define the admissible strategy L 3 Π x,y which, starting with surplus x, y pays no dividends until τ = inf {t : Xt L3 x + h, Yt L3 y, at time τ pays either Xt L3 x + h from the surplus of Company One or Yt L3 y from the surplus of Company Two, depending on which of these differences is positive, and then follows strategy L 2 Π x+h,y. In the event of no claims, τ = t := h/; since the probability of no claims until t is e λt, we get 2.7 V x, y V L 3x, y V L 2x + h, ye δ+λt V x + h, y εe δ+λt. From 2.6 and 2.7, we get the inequalities at the top. 3. Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation In order to obtain the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman HJB equation associated to the optimization problem 2.4, we need to state the so called Dynamic Programming Principle DPP. The proof that this holds is similar to the one given in Lemma.2 of Azcue and Muler [9] and uses that V is increasing and continuous in R 2 +. Lemma 3.. For any initial surplus x, y in R 2 + and any stopping time τ, we can write V x, y = sup L Π x,y E x,ya τ τ e δs dl τ τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δτ τ I {τ τ<τ V Xτ τ L, Y L +e δτ τ I {τ τ=τ a V X L τ + a 2V 2 Y L τ. The HJB equation of this optimization problem is τ τ 3. max {LV x, y, a V xx, y, a 2 V yx, y =, where 3.2 LV x, y = V xx, y + V yx, y δ + λ V x, y + IV x, y + Ux, y, x IV x, y = λ V x α, ydf x+y α + λ V, x + y αdf α x y +λ 2 V x, y αdf 2 x+y α + λ 2 V x + y α, df 2 α, y 6

7 and 3.3 Ux, y = λ a 2V 2 y F x + y + λ 2a V x F 2 x + y. Since the optimal value function V is locally Lipschitz but possibly not differentiable at certain points, we cannot say that V is a solution of the HJB equation, and so we prove instead that V is a viscosity solution of the corresponding HJB equation. Let us define this notion see Crandall and Lions [2] and Soner [23] for further details. Definition 3.2. A locally Lipschitz function u : R 2 + R is a viscosity supersolution of 3. at x, y R 2 + if any continuously differentiable function ϕ : R 2 + R with ϕx, y = ux, y such that u ϕ reaches the minimum at x, y satisfies max {Lϕx, y, a ϕ xx, y, a 2 ϕ yx, y. A function u : R 2 + R is a viscosity subsolution of 3. at x, y R 2 + if any continuously differentiable function ψ : R 2 + R with ψx, y = ux, y such that u ψ reaches the maximum at x, y satisfies max {Lψx, y, a ψ xx, y, a 2 ψ yx, y. A function u : R 2 + R which is both a supersolution and subsolution at x, y R 2 + is called a viscosity solution of 3. at x, y R 2 +. Proposition 3.3. V is a viscosity supersolution of the HJB equation 3. at any x, y with x > and y >. Proof. Given initial surplus levels x >, y > and any l, l 2, let us consider the admissible strategy L where Company One and Two pay dividends with constant rates l and l 2 respectively and τ is defined as in 2.3. Let ϕ be a test function for the supersolution of 3. at x, y with x > and y >. As before, denote τ and τ 2 as the arrival time of the first claim of Company One and Two respectively, and τ = τ τ 2. We have for t < τ, { X L t = x + l t, Y L t = y + l 2 t. Note that Nt + Nt 2 is a Poisson process with intensity λ, because the arrival times of the two companies are independent. We have from Lemma 3. that We can write So we obtain ϕx, y = V x, y τ t E x,ya e δ s τ t l ds + a 2 e δ s l 2ds +E x,y e δ τ t I {τ t<τv Xτ L t, Yτ L t +E x,y e δτ I {τ t=τa V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L τ t E x,ya e δ s τ t l ds + a 2 e δ s l 2ds +E x,y e δ τ t ϕxτ L t, Yτ L ti {τ t<τ +E x,y e δτ I {τ t=τa V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L. E x,y e δ τ t ϕxτ L t, Yτ L ti {τ t<τ = E x,yi {t<τ e δt ϕxτ L t, Yτ L t +E x,yi {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ e δτ ϕx L τ, Y L τ +E x,yi {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ 2 e δτ 2 ϕx L τ 2, Y L τ 2. 7

8 Therefore, τ t a lim t + E e δ s τ t l ds+a 2 e δ s l 2 ds x,y t + lim t + e λ+δt ϕx+ l t,y+ l 2 t ϕx,y t I {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ + lim t + E e δτ ϕx L τ,y L τ x,y I {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ + lim t + E 2 e δτ2 ϕx L τ 2,Y L τ 2 x,y t e + lim t + E δτ I {τ t=τ a V XL τ +a 2V2 Y τ L x,y = a l + a 2l 2 δ + λ ϕx, y + l ϕ xx, y + l 2 ϕ yx, y + Iϕx, y +Ux, y. t t Lϕx, y + l a ϕ xx, y + l 2 a 2 ϕ yx, y. Taking l = l 2 =, l with l 2 =, and l 2 with l =, we obtain max {Lϕx, y, a ϕ xx, y, a 2 ϕ yx, y. Proposition 3.4. V is a viscosity subsolution of the HJB equation 3.. Proof. Arguing by contradiction, we assume that V is not a subsolution of 3. at x, y with x > and y >. With a similar proof to the one of Proposition 3. of Azcue and Muler 24, but extending the definitions to two variables, we first show that there exist ε >, h, min{x /2, y /2 and a continuously differentiable function ψ : R 2 + R such that ψ is a test function for the subsolution of Equation 3. at x, y and satisfies 3.4 ψ xx, y a, ψ yx, y a 2 for x, y [, x + h] [, y + h], 3.5 L ψ x, y 2εδ for x, y [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h], and 3.6 V x, y ψx, y 2ε for x, y R 2 + \ x h/2, x + h/2 y h/2, y + h/2. Since ψ is continuously differentiable, we can find a positive constant C such that 3.7 Lψx, y C for all x, y [, x + 2h] [, y + 2h]. Consider { < θ < h 2 max {,, λ 4δ δ + λ, ελ, 2C δ + λ and let us take any admissible strategy L Π x,y. Consider the corresponding controlled risk process X t, Y t starting at x, y, and define the stopping times τ b = inf{t > : τ = inf{t > : X t, Y t [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h], X t, Y t R 2 + [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h] 8

9 and τ = τ b τ + θ τ. Note that τ is finite for h small enough and that it is necessary to introduce θ because before a lump sum dividend payment, X τ, Y τ can be in [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h] and X τ +, Y τ + R 2 + [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h]. Let us show that 3.8 V X τ, Y τ ψx τ, Y τ 2ε if τ = τ b τ + θ < τ. There are two possibilities: If τ = τ b, X τ, Y τ [x h, x + h] [y h, y + h] and so, from 3.6, we obtain V X τ, Y τ ψx τ, Y τ 2ε, 2 If τ = τ +θ, the distance from X τ, Y τ to x, y is at least h/2 h max {, θ, so from 3.6, we get 3.8. Note that X s, Y s [, x + h + θ] [, y + h + θ] [, x + 2h] [, y + 2h] for s τ, so we have that LψX s, Y s C for s τ. Since L t and L 2 t are non-decreasing and left continuous, they can be written as 3.9 L t = t dl,c s + X s + X s s<t L s + L s, L 2 t = t dl 2,c s + Y s + Y s s<t L 2 s + L2 s where L,c s and L 2,c s are continuous and non-decreasing processes. Since the function ψ is continuously differentiable in R 2 +, using the expression 3.9 and the change of variables formula for finite variation processes, we can write ψx τ, Y τ e δτ ψx, y = τ p ψ xx s, Y s + ψ yx s, Y s e δs ds + ψx s, Y s ψx s, Y s e δs + X s X s s τ τ ψ xx s, Y s e δs dl,c s + X s + X s s<τ τ ψ yx s, Y s e δs dl 2,c s + δ τ ψx s, Y s e δs ds. Y s + Y s s<τ Y s Y s s τ δs ψx s, Y s ψx s, Y s e ψx s+, Y s+ ψx s, Y s e δs δs ψx s+, Y s+ ψx s, Y s e Note that X s, Y s R 2 + for s τ except in the case that τ = τ, where X τ + Y τ <. Here we are extending the definition of ψ as ψx, y = a V xi {x + a 2V 2 yi {y for x + y <. We have that X s + X s only at the jumps of L s, and in this case X s + X s = L s + L s. Since L is admissible we have that Xs + = X s L s + L s. We can write 3. τ ψ xx s, Y s e δs dl,c s + X s + X s s<τ = τ ψ xx s, Y s e δs dl,c s + τ a e δs dl,c s a = a τ e δs dl s. L s + L s s<τ δs ψx s+, Y s+ ψx s, Y s e X s + X s s<τ L s + L s dα L s + L s ψ xx s α, Y sdα e δs e δs 9

10 3. Similarly, τ ψ xx s, Y s e δs dl 2,c s + X s + X s s<τ = τ ψ xx s, Y s e δs dl 2,c s a 2 τ e δs dl 2 s. δs ψx s+, Y s+ ψx s, Y s e L 2 s + L2 s s<τ L 2 s + L2 s ψ xx s, Y s αdα e δs On the other hand, X s X s only at the arrival of a claim for Company One, so 3.2 M t = X s X s s t ψx s, Y s ψx s, Y s e δs λ t e δs X s ψx s α, Y s ψx s, Y s df αds λ t e δs X s +Y s X ψ, X s s + Y s α ψx s, Y s df αds λ t e δs X s +Y a2v2 Y s s ψx s, Y s df αds is a martingale with zero expectation for t τ. Analogously, 3.3 M 2 t = Y s Y s s t ψx s, Y s ψx s, Y s e δs λ t 2 e δs Y s ψx s, Y s α ψx s, Y s df 2 αds λ t 2 e δs X s +Y s X ψx s s + Y s α, ψx s, Y s df 2 αds λ t 2 e δs X s +Y av Y s s ψx s, Y s df 2 αds is also a martingale with zero expectation for t τ. So we get 3.4 ψx τ, Y τ e δτ ψx, y τ LψX s, Y s e δs + Mτ + M τ 2 τ a e δs dl τ s a 2 e δs dl 2 s. Using 3.5, 3.7 and the definition of θ we get 3.5 τ LψX s, Y s e δs ds τ b τ τ LψX s, Y s e δs ds + Cθ 2εδ τ b τ τ e δs ds + Cθ 2εδ τ e δs ds + I {τ b τ τ<τ 2εδ τ τ b τ τ e δs ds + Cθ 2ε e δτ + ελ/ δ + λ. From 3.6, Lemma 3., 3.8, 3.4 and 3.5, it follows that

11 3.6 V x, y τ = sup L E x, y a e δs dl τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δτ V X τ, Y τ I {τ <τ + a V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L e δτ I {τ =τ τ sup L E x, y a e δs dl τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δτ ψx τ, Y τ 2ε I {τ <τ + a V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L e δτ I {τ =τ τ sup L E x,y L ψ X s, Y s e δs ds + Mτ + M τ 2 2εe δτ I {τ <τ + ψx, y ψx, y + E x y 2ε e δτ + ελ/ δ + λ 2εe cτ I {τ <τ = ψx, y 2ε + sup L E x y 2εe δτ I {τ =τ + ελ/ δ + λ ψx, y 2ε + 2εEe δτ + ελ/ δ + λ = ψx, y ελ/ δ + λ < ψx, y and this contradicts the assumption that V x, y = ψx, y. From the above two propositions we get the following result. Corollary 3.5. V is a viscosity solution of of the HJB equation Smallest Viscosity Solution Let us prove now that the optimal value function V is the smallest viscosity supersolution of 3.. We say that the function u : R 2 + R satisfies the growth condition A., if ux, y K + a x + a 2y for all x, y R 2 + for some positive K. The following Lemma is technical and will be used to prove Proposition 4.2. Lemma 4.. Fix x > and y > and let u be a non-negative supersolution of 3. satisfying the growth condition A.. We can find a sequence of positive functions u m : R 2 + R such that: a u m is continuously differentiable. b u m satisfies the growth condition A.. c u m,x a, u m,y a 2 and u m,x + u m,y δ + λ u m in R 2 +. d u m u uniformly on compact sets in R 2 + and u m converges to u a.e. in R 2 +. e There exists a sequence c m with lim m cm = such that sup x,y A Lu m x, y c m, where A = [, x ] [, y ]. Proof. The proof follows by standard convolution arguments and is the extension to two variables of Lemma 4. in Azcue an Muler [9]. Proposition 4.2. The optimal value function V is the smallest viscosity supersolution of 3. satisfying growth condition A.. Proof. Let u be a non-negative supersolution of 3. satisfying the growth condition A. and let L Π x,y; define X t, Y t as the corresponding controlled risk process starting at x, y. Consider the function u m of Lemma 4. in R 2 + ; we extend this function as u mx, y = a V xi {x + a 2V 2 yi {y for x + y <. As in the proof of Proposition 3.4, we get

12 4. u mx t τ, Y t τ e δt τ u mx, y t τ Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds a t τ e δs dl s a 2 t τ e δs dl 2 s + M t τ + M 2 t τ, where M t and M 2 t are zero-expectation martingales. So we obtain that u mx t τ, Y t τ e δt τ I {τ>t u mx, y t τ Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds + Mt τ + Mt τ 2 t τ a e δs dl s + e δt τ V X t τ I {τ t t τ a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δt τ V2 Y t τ I {τ t. Using that both L t and L 2 t are non-decreasing processes, from the monotone convergence theorem we get t τ lim t Ex,ya e δs dl s + e δt τ V X t τ I {τ t 4.2 t τ +a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δt τ V2 Y t τ I {τ t = V L x, y. From Lemma 4.c, we have that u m,x + u m,y δ + λ u m and that u m is increasing. So Iu mx, y λu mx, y and then δ + λu mx, y Lu mx, y λu mx, y + Ux, y. But using Lemma 4.b and the inequality X s x + s, Y s y + s we get 4.3 u mx s, Y s K + a X s + a 2Y s K + a x + a 2y + ps. So, using the bounded convergence theorem, we obtain t τ τ 4.4 lim E x,y Lu t mx s, Y s e δs ds = E x,y From 4., 4.2 and 4.4, we get 4.5 Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds. τ lim t Ex,y u mx t τ, Y t τ e δt τ I {τ<t u mx, y E x,y Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds Next, we show that 4.6 lim E x,y u t mx t τ, Y t τ e δt τ I {τ>t =. V L x, y. From 4.3, there exists a K such that E x,y u mx t τ, Y t τ e δt τ I {τ>t K + a x + a 2y + pt e δt. Since the last expression goes to as t goes to infinity, we have 4.6. Let us prove now that τ 4.7 lim sup E x,y Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds. m Given any ε >, we can find T such that 4.8 T Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds < ε 2 2

13 for any m, as by virtue of 4.3, growth condition A., Lemma 4.b and Lemma 4.c, and the growth property of V and V2, there exist positive constants k, k,k 2 and p such that Lu mx s, Y s λu mx s, Y s + UX s, Y s k + k x + k 2y + ps. Note that for s T, X s x := x + T, Y s y := y + T. From Lemma 4.e we can find m large enough such that for any m m T T Lu mx s, Y s e δs ds c m e δs ds cm δ ε 2 and so we get 4.7. Then, from 4.5 and using 4.6 and 4.7, we obtain 4.9 ux, y = lim umx, y V m L x, y. Since V is a viscosity solution of 3., the result follows. From the previous proposition we can deduce the usual viscosity verification result. Corollary 4.3. Consider a family of admissible strategies {L x,y Π x,y : x, y R 2 +. If the function V L x,y x, y is a viscosity supersolution of 3. for all x, y R 2 +, then V L x,y x, y is the optimal value function Iterative Approach In this section, we approximate the optimal value function V defined in 2.4 by an increasing sequence of value functions of strategies which pay dividends and collaborate if it is necessary up to the n-th claim regardless from which company and then follow the take-the-moneyand-run strategy. Given initial surplus levels x, y, the take-the-money-and-run admissible strategy L pays immediately the entire surplus x and y as dividends that is X + = Y + =, and then pays the incoming premium as dividends until the first claim, where the company facing that claim gets ruined. Note that under this strategy the companies can not help each other. Consider τ n as the time of arrival of the n-th claim regardless from which company, that is the n-th point of the Poisson process N t = N t + N 2 t. We define the set Π n x,y of all the admissible strategies in Π x,y which follow L right after τ n. Let us define 5. V n x, y = sup V L x, y L Π n x,y for n, we also define V = V L. We can write 5.2 Note that, for n, we have V x, y = a x + a 2y + λ p + av δ+λ λ 2 p + a2v λ. + λ 2 δ+λ 5.3 V n x, y = sup V n L x, y, L Π x,y where 5.4 V n x, y = L Ex,ya τ e δs dl τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δτ V n Xτ L, Y L +e δτ a V Xτ L + a 2V2 Y L I {τ =τ. τ τ I {τ <τ In this expression, we only consider the admissible strategy L Π x,y for t τ. The following DPP holds. 3

14 Lemma 5.. For any initial surplus x, y in R 2 + and any stopping time τ, we can write V n x, y = τ τ sup L Πx,y E x,ya e δs dl τ τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s +e δτ V n Xτ L, Yτ L I {τ<τ τ + e δτ V n Xτ L, Y L +e δτ a V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L I {τ τ=τ =τ. τ I {τ τ=τ <τ Proposition 5.2. We have that V V 2... V. Proof. We prove the result by induction: a V V, because the strategy L Π x,y. b Assume that V n 2 V n. By 5.3, we have V n τ x, y sup L Πx,y E x,ya e δs dl τ s + a 2 e δs dl 2 s + e δτ V n 2 Xτ L, Yτ L I {τ <τ +e δτ a V Xτ L + a 2V2 Yτ L I {τ =τ = V n x, y. The HJB equation for V n is given by 5.5 max { L n V n x, y, a V n x x, y, a 2 V n y x, y =, where 5.6 L n V n x, y = Vx n x, y + Vy n x, y δ + λ V n x, y + IV n x, y + Ux, y. The following basic results about regularity and growth at infinity of V n, n are similar to those of Lemmas 2.2 and 2.3. Lemma 5.3. The optimal value function V n satisfies growth condition A., it is increasing and locally Lipschitz in R 2 + with a h V n x + h, y V n x, y e δ+λh/ V n x, y a 2h V n x, y + h V n x, y e δ+λh/ V n x, y for any h > and for any x, y in R 2 +. In the next two propositions, we see that V n is a viscosity solution of the corresponding HJB equation. Proposition 5.4. V n is a viscosity supersolution of the HJB equation 5.5 for x > and y >. Proof. Similar to the one given in Proposition 3.3. Proposition 5.5. V n is a viscosity subsolution of the corresponding HJB equation 5.5. Proof. The proof of this proposition is similar to the one of Proposition 3.4, but using as martingales with zero expectation 5.7 M 3 t = X s X s s t V n X s, Y s ψx s, Y s e δs λ t e δs X s λ t e δs X s +Y s X s λ t e δs X s +Y s V n X s α, Y s ψx s, Y s df αds V n, X s + Y s α ψx s, Y s df αds a2v 2 Y s ψx s, Y s df αds 4

15 and 5.8 M 4 t = Y s Y s s t V n X s, Y s ψx s, Y s e δs λ 2 t e δs Y s λ 2 t e δs X s +Y s X s λ 2 t e δs X s +Y s V n X s, Y s α ψx s, Y s df 2 αds V n X s + Y s α, ψx s, Y s df 2 αds av Y s ψx s, Y s df 2 αds. instead of the martingales M t and M 2 t defined in 3.2 and 3.3 respectively. In the next proposition we state that V n is the smallest viscosity solution of the corresponding HJB equation. Proposition 5.6. The optimal value function V n is the smallest viscosity supersolution of 5.5 satisfying growth condition A.. Proof. The proof of this proposition is similar to the one of Proposition 4.2, but using as martingales with zero expectation 5.7 and 5.8. Remark 5.7. From the above proposition we deduce the usual viscosity verification result for the n step: Consider a family of admissible strategies {L x,y Π x,y : x, y R 2 +. If the function V n L x,y x, y is a viscosity supersolution of 5.5 then V n L x,y = V n. Finally, we have the convergence result to the optimal value function 2.4. Proposition 5.8. V n V as n goes to infinity. Proof. By Lemma 2.3 and Lemma 2.2, V is increasing and satisfies property A., so there exists a T > such that 5.9 e δt V x + t, y + t < ε 3 for t T. Let us define κ = V x + T, y + T > and take n > such that 5. P τ n T ε 3κ. There exists an admissible strategy L Π x,y such that 5. V x, y V L x, y ε 3. We define the strategy L n Π n x,y as L n t = L t for t τ n τ and L n t = L t τ n for t τ n if τ n < τ. From 5.9, 5. and Lemma 2.3, we have V L x, y V n L x, y τ E x,y a τ τ n e δs dl s + e δτ V Xτ L τ + a 2 τ τ n e δs dl 2 s + e δτ V2 Yτ L E x,ye δτ τn V X L τ τn, Yτ τ L n E x,yi {τ τn T e δτ τn V x + p τ τ n, y + τ τ n +E x,yi {τn <T e δτ τn V x + p τ τ n, y + τ τ n E x,yi {τ τn T e δτ τn V x + p τ τ n, y + τ τ n + κp τ n < T 2ε 3. Then we obtain from 5. for any n n. V x, y V L x, y + ε 3 V L n x + ε V n x, y + ε 5

16 6. Stationary dividend strategies As in the one-dimensional case see for instance Azcue and Muler [9] our aim is to find a stationary dividend strategy whose value function is the optimal value function V. A dividend strategy is stationary when the decision on the dividend payment depends on the current surplus only, and not on the full history of the controlled process. More precisely, a stationary dividend strategy is given by four positive and Borel-measurable functions l i : R 2 + R + and Li : R 2 + R +, i =, 2. A stationary dividend strategy generates a family of admissible strategies { L x,y = L, L 2 Π x,y for any x, y R+ 2 which are the solutions of the following stochastic differential equations L i t = t li Xs L, Ys L ds + s t L i Xs L, Ys L with initial surplus levels X L = x, Y L = y. L ix, y corresponds to lump sum dividend payments and l ix, y corresponds to the continuous dividend payment rate of the i th company when the current surplus level is x, y. We are not proving in this paper the existence of an optimal strategy. However, if there exist optimal admissible strategies for every x, y R 2 +, then there exists an optimal stationary strategy. Given the optimal admissible strategy L, L 2 Π x,y, we define L i x, y = L i + i,c and lix, y = d L for i =, 2. It can be proved, using the Dynamic Programming Principle and a stair-step approximation on the time variable, that these functions are Borel-measurable and that the stationary dividend strategy generated by them are optimal for any x, y R 2 +. If the optimal value function V is differentiable and this fact has to be checked for every concrete case, see Section 8, the form in which the optimal value function solves the HJB equation at any x, y R 2 + suggests how the dividends should be paid when the current surplus is x, y. There are only seven possibilities: i If the current surplus is in the open set C = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y =, V xx, y > a, V yx, y > a 2, no dividends are paid. The set C is called the non-action set. ii If the current surplus is in the open set B = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y <, V xx, y = a, V yx, y > a 2, Company One pays a lump sum as dividends. This lump sum should be min{b > : x b, y / B. iii If the current surplus is in the open set B 2 = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y <, V xx, y > a, V yx, y = a 2, Company Two pays a lump sum as dividends. This lump sum should be min{b > : x, y b / B 2. iv If the current surplus is in the set B = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y <, V xx, y = a, V yx, y = a 2, but not in the closure of B B 2, both companies pay a lump sum as dividends. v If the current surplus is in the closed set A = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y =, V xx, y = a, V yx, y = a 2, both companies pay their incoming premiums as dividends. 6

17 vi If the current surplus is in the set A = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y =, V xx, y = a, V yx, y > a 2, Company One pays dividends at some special rate so that the surplus remains in A A. vii If the current surplus is in the set A 2 = { x, y R 2 + : LV x, y =, V xx, y > a, V yx, y = a 2, Company Two pays dividends at some special rate so that the surplus remains in A 2 A. Note that if V is a continuously differentiable solution of 3., then A = A A A 2 is closed, B = B B 2 B is open, and any segment which connects a point of B with a point of the open set C should contain a point of A. Remark 6.. Let us consider the simplest case of identical and independent Cramér-Lundberg processes in 2.; that is = = p; λ = λ 2; and U i, U 2 i have the same distribution F. We also choose the dividends paid by both companies to be equally weighted, i.e. a = a 2 = /2. Under these assumptions, the optimal value function will be symmetric, that is V x, y = V y, x, and so the sets introduced above satisfy the following properties: the line y = x is an axis of symmetry of the sets C, B and A ; the sets B and A are the reflection with respect to the line y = x of the sets B 2 and A 2 respectively. 7. Curve strategies We introduce a family of stationary dividend strategies, called curve strategies, in which dividends are paid in the seven ways mentioned in the previous section, having a simple structure: here the boundary between the action and non-action region is given by a curve. These strategies can be seen as the natural analogues of the one-dimensional barrier strategies in this two-dimensional case. It is reasonable to think that if the optimal strategy is a curve strategy it should satisfy the following properties: If x, y B A that is only Company One pays dividends, then x, y should be in B for all x > x ; analogously if x, y B2 A 2 that is only Company Two pays dividends, then x, y should be in B2 for all y > y. Finally, the set C should be bounded because, as in the one-dimensional case, the surplus of each company under the optimal strategy should be bounded for t >. Let us define the curve strategies satisfying the properties mentioned above. For these strategies, R 2 + is partitioned into seven sets C, A, A, A 2, B, B and B 2 where A = A A A 2 is a curve which intersects both coordinate axes. A = {x, y with x, y R 2 +. If the current surplus is x, y, both companies pay their incoming premium as dividends. Let us call u the x-intercept and v the y-intercept of the line with slope / passing through x, y; let us denote O x,y and O x,y 2 the regions in the first quadrant bounded above and below by this line, respectively. B = [x, [y, A. If the current surplus is x, y B, Company One and Company Two pay x x and y y as dividends, respectively. The set A is a curve in O x,y parametrized by { A = u + ξ u, ξ u with u < u M ξ, where ξ : [u, M ξ ] R is a continuously differentiable function with ξ u = y, ξ M ξ = and negative derivative. If the current surplus x, y A, Company Two does not pay dividends and Company One pays dividends at some special rate for which the bivariate surplus remains in the curve A. By basic calculus, it can be shown that this rate is given by l x, y = ξ x p/p2 y. 7

18 The set B is the set to the right of A in O x,y, that is { B = x, y R 2 + : y y and x > ξ y + y. If the current surplus x, y B, Company Two does not pay dividends and Company One pays the lump sum min{b > : x b, y A = x /y ξ y. The sets A 2 and B 2 in O x,y 2 are defined analogously to A and B with the roles of Company One and Two interchanged; that is { A 2 = ξ 2v, v + ξ 2v with v < v M ξ2, and B 2 = { x, y R 2 + : x x and y > ξ 2 x + x, where ξ 2 : [v, M ξ2 ] R is a continuously differentiable function with ξ 2v = x, ξ 2M ξ2 = and negative derivative. If the current surplus x, y A 2, Company One does not pay dividends and Company Two pays dividends at some special rate for which the bivariate surplus remains in the curve A 2. Here this rate is l 2x, y = ξ 2 y p2/px. If the current surplus x, y B 2, Company One does not pay dividends and Company Two pays the lump sum min{b > : x, y b A 2 = y / x ξ 2 x. The no-action region C is the open set delimited by the curve A and the axes. If the current surplus x, y C, no dividends are paid. The set partition of the curve strategy corresponding to x, y =, 2 and the functions ξ u = 2u 4u 6 35 for u [, 4] and ξ 2v = u 3u 6 for v [, 3] is illustrated in Figure 7.. y v u Fig. 6.: Example of Curve Strategy x 8

19 For any w R, let us define the set 7. Φ w = { ξ : [w, M ξ ] R +, ξm ξ =, M ξ, ξ < and ξ continuous. Note that the curve strategies depend only on the point x, y R 2 + and the functions ξ Φ u and ξ 2 Φ v, used in the parametrization of the curve A. We associate to any ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2 and any x, y R 2 + the admissible strategy L ξ = L,ξ t, L 2,ξ t Π x,y Let us define the value function V ξ of this curve strategy as 7.2 V ξ x, y = V L ξx, y. We will look for ξ such that the associated value function V ξ is the optimal value function defined in 2.4. Remark 7.. In the case that A is the segment x + y = K for some K > in R 2 +, the sum of the dividend rates paid by Company One and Two is + for any current surplus in this line. The point A = x, K x indicates how this dividend payment is splitted among the two companies in A: At A, Company One pays and Company Two pays, to the right of this point A Company One pays the total rate + and to the left of this point A 2 it is Company Two which pays Search for the Optimal Curve Strategy The goal of this section is to see whether the optimal value function V is the value function of a curve strategy as defined in the previous section. We do not have a theoretical result on the existence and structure of the optimal stationary strategy, however we can use the iterative approach introduced in Section 5 and Proposition 5.8 as a verification result. This verification result is stated in Proposition 8.8; it will be used in the next Section to obtain the optimal curve strategy and establish its optimality among all admissible dividend strategies in a particular example. We first define an auxiliary function. For any ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2, where x, y R 2 +, ξ Φ u, ξ 2 Φ v and any continuous function W : R 2 + [, +, let 8. W ξ x, y := E τ x,y e δs a dls,ξ + a 2dLs 2,ξ + e δτ W Xτ Lξ, Yτ Lξ +e δτ a V Xτ Lξ + a 2V2 Yτ Lξ I {τ =τ. I {τ <τ If W is the value function of a family of admissible strategies L = L x.y Π x,y x,y R 2 + and C, A, A, A 2, B, B and B 2 are the sets associated to ξ as defined in the previous section, then W ξ would be the value function of the strategy which pays dividends according to the curve strategy L ξ up to the first claim and according to L afterwards. We call this kind of strategy a one-step curve strategy. Define, 8.2 Hx, y := IW x, y + Ux, y. In the next proposition, we find an explicit formula for the function W ξ in terms of W and ξ for x, y O x,y ; the formula for the value function for x, y O x,y 2 follows in an analogous way and depends only on ξ 2. In order to obtain this formula, we use the fact that W ξ satisfies the integro-differential equation LW ξ = in C A and that Wx ξ = a in A A B B. 9

20 Proposition 8.. Given ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2 and a continuous function W, we have that W ξ x, y = p ξ x y y e δ+λ kx y y yi { y u x ξ y+ y,y y + ξx e δ+λw Hx + w, y + wdwi { y u + a x ξ y y + kξ y I { x ξ y+ + a x x + a 2y y + kx y I {x x,y y, y,y y x ξ y+ y,y y for x, y O x,y, where u = x y, the function H is defined in 8.2 and ku = e δ+λ ξ u ξ u +e δ+λ ξ u ξ u + eδ+λ p + Hu + δ+λ δ+λ ξ u, ξ u u a ξ w u e δ+λ dw ξ u ξ u Hξ t + t, te δ+λ p t 2 dt. Proof. Let us consider first an initial surplus x, y C O x,y. By definition 8. we have that the controlled surplus process for t < τ h and h > small enough is given by So we have that X t, Y t = x + t, y + t. W ξ x, y = E x,ye δt W ξ X t τ, Y t τ I {t τ =t + e δτ W X τ, Y τ I {t τ =τ <τ +e δτ a V X τ + a 2V2 Y τ I {t τ =τ =τ. We can write E x,y e δ τ t I {τ t=t<τ W ξ Xτ L t, Yτ L t + e δ τ t I {τ t=τ <τw Xτ L t, Yτ L t = E x,y e δ τ t I {τ t=t<τ W ξ Xτ L t, Yτ L t and so +E x,yi {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ e δτ W X L τ, Y L τ +E x,yi {τ =τ t<τand τ =τ 2 e δτ 2 W X L τ 2, Y L τ 2, e λ+δt W ξ x + t, y + t W ξ x, y lim = Hx, y. t + t Then gt = W ξ x + t, y + t is continuous and differentiable as long as x + t, y + t C with 8.3 g = λ + δw ξ x, y Hx, y. Let us prove now that the function W ξ is continuous in A and has a continuous derivative in the direction of this curve. In case x, y A, we have that for t < τ h and h > small enough, the controlled surplus process is X t, Y t = x + t + t p 2 ξ Xs p/p2 Ys ds, y + p2t A. 2

21 By 8., we have that τ W ξ t x, y = E x,y a ξ Xs p/p2 Ys e δs ds + e δt W ξ X t τ, Y t τ I {t τ =t + E x,y e δτ W X τ, Y τ I {t τ =τ <τ + e δτ a V X τ + a 2V2 Y τ I {t τ =τ =τ. Then, with an argument similar to the case of C, we obtain for any x, y A, e λ+δt W ξ x + t + t ds, y + p2t ξ lim Xs / Y s W ξ x, y t t a = Hx, y +. x p/p2 y ξ So g t := W ξ x + t + t ds, y + p2t ξ Xs p/p2 Ys is continuous and differentiable at t = and satisfies 8.4 g = λ + δw ξ x, y Hx, y + ξ a. x p/p2 y Since x + t + t p2/ξ X s / Y sds, y + t A for t small enough, we have that x + t + t p ds, y + p2t = ut + ξ Xs p/p2 Ys for u t := x / y + t p2/ξ X s / Y sds; therefore W ξ u t + p ξ u t, ξ u t = g t. ξ u t, ξ u t Since u t = /ξ X t / Y t is continuous and negative, u exists and is continuously differentiable, so ku := W ξ u + p ξ u, ξ u = g u u is continuously differentiable. Defining W u, s := W ξ u + p ξ u s, ξ u s, we obtain for u + / ξ u s, ξ u s C that LW u, s := W su, s δ + λ W u, s + Hu + p ξ u s, ξ u s = The equation LW u, s = is a linear ODE in the variable s, so therefore W u, se δ+λs ku = s eδ+λt Hu + p ξ u t, ξ u tdt; 8.5 W ξ u + p ξ u s, ξ u s = e δ+λs ku + s eδ+λt Hu + p ξ u t, ξ u tdt, 2

22 for u u M ξ and s min {ξ u/, u/ + ξ u/. So W ξ is continuously differentiable in the intersection of the set C A with O x,y. We also have, from 8.3 and 8.4, that for any x, y A, Then from ξ W lim x+p t,y+ t W ξ x,y t t = lim t + W ξ x+ t+ t ξ x y,y+t W ξ x,y t a ξ x y. W ξ. x, y + p x 2W ξ. x, y y = + ξ x y we conclude that W ξ x x, y = a. By 8.5, and since u + / ξ u, ξ u A, and then 8.6 Wx ξ u + ξ u, ξ u = k u + = a, ku = kue δ+λ ξ u ξ u + u u W ξ. x x, y + W ξ. y x, y a ξ x y, Hu + ξ ξ u, ξ u δ + λku u a Hw + ξ w, ξ w ξ w e δ+λ ξ u ξ w dw. At the point u + / ξ u, ξ u A the dividend strategy consists of collecting all the incoming premium as dividends up to the time τ, so Then we have, from 8.6, ku = ku = e δ+λ ξ u ξ u + u u p δ + λ + δ + λ Hu + ξ u, ξ u. p + Hu + δ+λ δ+λ ξ u, ξ u a Hw + ξ w, ξ w ξ w e δ+λ ξ u ξ w dw. We conclude for 8.5 that for any x, y in the intersection of the set C with O x,y, which yields the result. p ξ x y y W ξ x, y = e δ+λ kx y y y + ξx e δ+λw Hx + w, y + wdw, Remark 8.2. The formula of W ξ in O x,y 2 can be obtained using the formula given in Proposition 8. by interchanging the role of Company One and Company Two using that W ξ y = a 2 in A 2 A B 2 B. More precisely, if x, y O x,y 2, 22

23 W ξ x, y = p ξ 2 2y x x e δ+λ ky x x xi { x x,y ξ 2 x+ x + ξ2y e δ+λw Hx + w, y + wdwi { x x,y ξ + a 2y ξ 2 x x + kξ 2 x I { x x,y ξ 2 x+ p 2 x + a x x + a 2y y + ky x I {x x,y y, 2 x+ x where kv = e δ+λ ξ 2 v ξ 2 v +e δ+λ ξ 2 v ξ 2 v + eδ+λ p + Hξ2v, v + δ+λ δ+λ ξ 2v v a ξ 2 w 2 v e δ+λ dw ξ2 v ξ 2 Ht, ξ v 2 t + te δ+λ p t dt. From the formulas obtained in Proposition 8. and Remark 8.2 we obtain the following regularity result. Proposition 8.3. If the function H defined in 8.2 is continuously differentiable, then W ξ is continuously differentiable in R 2 +. Proof. Since ξ and ξ 2 are continuously differentiable, it is clear that W ξ is continuously differentiable except possibly at the points of either the boundary of B or the segment { S = x, x x + y R 2 + with x x. After some easy calculations and using that W ξ satisfies p δ + λw ξ x, y + Hx, y =, it can be seen that W ξ is continuously differentiable in S with Wx ξ x, x x + y = x x e δ+λw H xx + w, x x + y + wdw + e and x x δ+λ a Wy ξ x, x u = x x e δ+λw H yx + w, x x + y + wdw + e δ+λ x x a 2. Finally, the differentiability at the boundary of B follows from the differentiability of W ξ at x, y of S. Let us define the set of functions M = {w : R 2 + [, + continuous with wx, y a x a 2y bounded. Proposition 8.4. The value function V ξ of the curve strategy corresponding to ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2 as defined in 7.2, satisfies the formulas given in Proposition 8. and Remark 8.2 replacing both W and W ξ by V ξ. Moreover, V ξ is the unique function in M which satisfies this property. 23

24 Proof. M is a complete metric space with the distance dw, w 2 = sup R 2 + w w 2. The operator T : M M defined as T wx, y := E τ x,y e δs a dls,ξ + a 2dLs 2,ξ + e δτ wxτ Lξ, Yτ Lξ +e δτ a V Xτ Lξ + a 2V2 Yτ Lξ I {τ =τ I {τ <τ is a contraction with contraction factor λ/δ + λ <. Then, there exists a unique fixed point and by definition 7.2, T V ξ = V ξ. Taking in Proposition 8. and in Remark 8.2 the function W as V ξ we obtain from 8. that V ξ = W ξ and so we get the result. This last proposition gives a constructive way to obtain V ξ. Starting with w x, y = a x + a 2y M, we define iteratively w n+ = T w n. Hence, V ξ = lim n w n. Note that at each step w n+ can be obtained from the formulas given in Proposition 8. and Remark 8.2 replacing W by w n. Consider now the function V n,ξ defined in 8. taking W as the optimal value function V n corresponding to step n in 5.. We try to find ξ n, which maximizes V n,ξ among all the possible ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2. If the function V n,ξ n is a viscosity supersolution of 5.5, then by Remark 5.7, we would have that V n,ξ n = V n. In the case that one-step curve strategies corresponding to ξ n exist for all n, by Proposition 5.8, V n,ξ n V. Let us call, as in 8.2, 8.7 H n x, y := IV n x, y + Ux, y. In order to find the optimal one-step curve strategy corresponding to ξ n = x n, y n, ξ,n, ξ2,n, we look first for the optimal vertex x n, y n. By the formula given in Proposition 8., and V n,ξ x, y = p Hn x, y + δ + λ δ + λ for x and y large enough. So V n,ξ x, y = V n,ξ x, y + a x x + a 2y y. x n, y H n x, y n = arg max a x a 2y. x,y R 2 δ + λ + If this maximum is attained at a critical point assuming that H n is differentiable, we have that x n, y n is a solution of 8.8 { xh n x, y = a δ + λ yh n x, y = a 2 δ + λ. Let us call u n = x n / y n and v n = y n / x n. Next, we use Calculus of Variations in order to find two curves ξ,n and ξ2,n which maximize V n,ξ x, y, among all ξ = x n, y n, ξ, ξ 2 for ξ Φ u n, ξ 2 Φ v n and x, y large enough. The two curves can be obtained separately and independently. 24

25 Proposition 8.5. Assume that H n is differentiable and that there exists ξ n = x n, y n, ξ,n, ξ 2,n where ξ,n Φ u n and ξ 2,n Φ v n such that V n = V n,ξ n. Then ξ,n satisfies for u n u M ξ,n, and ξ 2,n satisfies for v n v M ξ 2,n. xh n u + ξ,nu, ξ,nu = a δ + λ yh n ξ 2,nv, v + ξ 2,nv = a 2δ + λ Proof. We will prove this result for ξ,n, the proof for ξ2,n is analogous. Given any ξ Φ u n, we have that V n,ξ x, = V n,ξ M ξ, + a x M ξ, for ξ = x n, y n, ξ, ξ2 and x M ξ. Then, if there exists ξ,n Φ u n such that V n = V n,ξ n, V n,ξ n M ξ,n, a M ξ,n = max V n,ξ M ξ, a M ξ. ξ Φ u n Consider non-negative test functions ς with ςu n = and ςm ξ,n =. We have that ξ,n + ες Φ u n for ε small enough. Let us write, ξ εu = ξ,nu + εςu. We have that M ξε = M ξ,n and then V n,ξ n M ξ,n, a M ξ,n = max V n,ξ ε M ξ, a ς,n M ξ,,n where ξ ε = x n, y n, ξε, ξ2. Denote ϑε := V n,ξ ε M ξ,n, a M ξ,n. We have that ξ εm ξ,n = ξ,nm ξ,n = and ξ εu n = ξ,nu n so we can write by Proposition 8., ϑε = e δ+λξ,n u n p p 2 Clearly, Mξ,n + a e δ+λξεw u n δ + λ + δ + λ Hn u n + ξ dw + p2 ξ,nu n, ξ,nu n,n u n a u n H n ξε t + t, te δ+λt dt. = ϑ ε = Mξ,n u n xh n w + ξ,nw, ξ,nw a δ + λ e δ+λ ξ,n w ςwdw. So we obtain for all u n u M ξ,n. xh n u + ξ,nu, ξ,nu a δ + λ e δ+λ ξ,n u = 25

26 This last proposition gives us a constructive way to find the candidate for V n in the case that it comes from a one-step curve strategy. We find numerically, if it exists, the solution z u of the equation 8.9 xh n u + z u, z u = a δ + λ for u n u min {u : z u = and the solution z 2v of the equation 8. yh n z 2v, v + z 2v = a 2δ + λ for v n v min {v : z 2v =. If z u is in Φ u n and z 2v is in Φ vn, we define ξ,nu = z u and ξ2,nv = z 2v and we obtain the value function V n,ξ n by the formula given in Proposition 8.; this is our candidate for V n. Afterwards, we check whether V n,ξ n is a viscosity supersolution of 5.5; if this is the case, then V n = V n,ξ n. Remark 8.6. Consider claim size distributions F i, i =, 2 such that Vi, and hence also U, are differentiable functions see for instance [9] for sufficient conditions for this property. Assume that there exists ξ n = x n, y n, ξ,n, ξ2,n where ξ,n Φ u n and ξ2,n Φ v nsuch that V n = V n,ξ n for all n, then H n and V n are differentiable for all n. To see this, note that V given in 5.2 is differentiable, that the differentiability of V n implies the differentiability of H n and that, by Proposition 8.3, the differentiability of H n implies the differentiability of V n+. We conclude that the differentiability condition on H n in Proposition 8.5 is automatically fulfilled. In the next Proposition we state some conditions under which the optimal strategy of 2.4 is a curve strategy. This result, together with Propositions 8. and 8.5 gives a way to find the optimal curve if it exists. Let us first define a criterion of convergence for a sequence ξn that will be used in the next proposition. n Definition 8.7. We say that ξ n = x n, y n, ξ,n, ξ 2,n converges to ξ = x, y, ξ, ξ 2 if lim xn, y n = x, y, lim M ξ i,n M ξi for i =, 2, n n lim max ξ n,nu ξ u =, lim max [u n,m ξ,n ] [u,m ξ ] n lim max ξ,n w ξ w = and lim n [,ξ,n u n] [,ξ u] [v n,m ξ2,n ] [v,m ξ2 ] ξ 2,nv ξ 2v =, max ξ 2,n w ξ 2 w =. n [,ξ 2,n v n] [,ξ 2 v] Proposition 8.8. Assume that there exists a ξ n such that V n = V n,ξ n for all n. If ξ n converges to some ξ in the sense of Definition 8.7, then the optimal value function V is the value function of the curve strategy V ξ as defined in 7.2. Proof. From Proposition 5.8, we have that lim n V n,ξ n = V. So replacing W by V n,ξ n and ξ by ξ n in the formulas given in Proposition 8. and Remark 8.2 and letting n go to infinity, we obtain that V satisfies the formulas given in Proposition 8. and Remark 8.2 replacing W by V and ξ by ξ. Therefore, by Proposition 8.4 and Lemma 2.2, the functions V and V ξ coincide. 9. Numerical Example We present a numerical example in the symmetric and equally weighted case with an exponential claim size distribution. By Remark 6., we restrict the search of the optimal curve strategy to ξ = x, x, ξ, ξ, ξ Φ. Using the formulas given in Propositions 8. and equations 8.8, 8.9 and 8., we obtain ξ n = x n, x n, ξ n, ξ n. We check that ξ n Φ and 26

27 that the associated value function V n,ξ n is a viscosity solution of 5.5. By Remark 8.6, V n,ξ n is differentiable because ξ n Φ, so in order to check numerically that V n,ξ n is a viscosity solution of 5.5 it is enough to check that V n,ξ n x a and V n,ξ n y a 2 in the set C and that LV n,ξ n in the set B B, where these sets are the ones defined in Section 7 for ξ n. We also obtain numerically the convergence of ξ n to ξ according to Definition 8.7. Then, using Proposition 8.8, one can conclude that the optimal strategy is a curve strategy with curve ξ. The numerical procedure was done with the Mathematica software and the calculation is quite time-consuming. The concrete chosen parameters are: exponential claim size distribution with parameter 3, Poisson intensity λ = λ 2 = 2/9, premium rate = =, and a discount factor δ =.. In this numerical procedure we used step-size x = y =.2 and iterated 6 times. The resulting optimal curve strategy is given in Figure 9., and V x, y x+y/2 the improvement of the optimal dividend strategy over paying out the initial capital immediately is depicted as the upper curve in Figure 9.2 the sets A and A 2 are not straight lines, even if they appear to be so at first glance. We also compare for this numerical example the optimal value function V x, y with the comparably weighted sum of the stand-alone value functions without collaboration: V Sx, y = V x + V y 2 and with V M x + y/2, where V M is the optimal value function for the merger of the two companies. Figure 9.2 depicts the graphics of all three value functions V x, y, V Sx, y and V M x + y/2, each of them reduced by x + y/2. The optimal merger strategy is barrier with barrier b = By Remark 2., V M x + y/2 < V x, y for all x, y R 2 +. One sees that whereas for the comparison between the stand-alone case and the merger the initial surplus levels matter with the merger case being the lowest of the three value functions in,, the collaboration case outperforms not only the merger case but also the stand-alone one for all combinations of initial surplus levels i.e. if one measures the overall dividend payments that can be achieved with either behavior, for this numerical example collaboration is always preferable. Hence we have here an instance where collaboration is beneficial not only for safety aspects, but also with respect to collective profitability. y Figure 9.: Optimal Curve Strategy x 27

28 Figure 9.2: V x, y x+y 2 vs. V Sx, y x+y 2 vs. V M x+y x+y 2 2 Acknowledgement. The authors would like to thank two referees for useful remarks to improve the presentation of the paper. References [] H. Albrecher and V. Lautscham. Dividends and the time of ruin under barrier strategies with a capital-exchange agreement. Anales Instituto de Actuarios Españoles, in press, 25. [2] H. Albrecher and S. Thonhauser. Optimality results for dividend problems in insurance. Rev. R. Acad. Cienc. Exactas Fís. Nat. Ser. A Math. RACSAM, 32:295 32, 29. [3] S. Asmussen and H. Albrecher. Ruin probabilities. Advanced Series on Statistical Science & Applied Probability, 4. World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd., Hackensack, NJ, second edition, 2. [4] B. Avanzi. Strategies for dividend distribution: a review. N. Am. Actuar. J., 32:27 25, 29. [5] F. Avram, Z. Palmowski, and M. Pistorius. A two-dimensional ruin problem on the positive quadrant. Insurance Math. Econom., 42: , 28. [6] F. Avram, Z. Palmowski, and M. R. Pistorius. Exit problem of a two-dimensional risk process from the quadrant: exact and asymptotic results. Ann. Appl. Probab., 86: , 28. [7] P. Azcue and N. Muler. Optimal reinsurance and dividend distribution policies in the Cramér-Lundberg model. Math. Finance, 52:26 38, 25. [8] P. Azcue and N. Muler. Minimizing the ruin probability allowing investments in two assets: a two-dimensional problem. Math. Methods Oper. Res., 772:77 26, 23. [9] P. Azcue and N. Muler. Stochastic Optimization in Insurance: a Dynamic Programming Approach. Springer Briefs in Quantitative Finance. Springer, 24. [] A. Badescu, L. Gong, and S. Lin. Optimal capital allocations for a bivariate risk process under a risk sharing strategy. Preprint, University of Toronto,

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics Hawkes Seminar May 23, 2018 1 / 46 Some Problems in Insurance and Reinsurance Mohamed Badaoui Department of Electrical Engineering National

More information

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Stefan Thonhauser DSA, HEC, Université de Lausanne 13 th Scientific Day, Bonn, 3.4.214 Outline Introduction Risk models and controls

More information

OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND REINSURANCE UNDER THRESHOLD STRATEGY

OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND REINSURANCE UNDER THRESHOLD STRATEGY Dynamic Systems and Applications 2 2) 93-24 OPTIAL DIVIDEND AND REINSURANCE UNDER THRESHOLD STRATEGY JINGXIAO ZHANG, SHENG LIU, AND D. KANNAN 2 Center for Applied Statistics,School of Statistics, Renmin

More information

Worst-Case-Optimal Dynamic Reinsurance for Large Claims

Worst-Case-Optimal Dynamic Reinsurance for Large Claims Worst-Case-Optimal Dynamic Reinsurance for Large Claims by Olaf Menkens School of Mathematical Sciences Dublin City University (joint work with Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen) LUH-Kolloquium Versicherungs-

More information

Stochastic Areas and Applications in Risk Theory

Stochastic Areas and Applications in Risk Theory Stochastic Areas and Applications in Risk Theory July 16th, 214 Zhenyu Cui Department of Mathematics Brooklyn College, City University of New York Zhenyu Cui 49th Actuarial Research Conference 1 Outline

More information

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Yipeng Yang * Under the supervision of Dr. Michael Taksar Department of Mathematics University of Missouri-Columbia Oct

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.oc] 26 May 2015

arxiv: v2 [math.oc] 26 May 2015 Optimal dividend payments under a time of ruin constraint: Exponential claims arxiv:11.3793v [math.oc 6 May 15 Camilo Hernández Mauricio Junca July 3, 18 Astract We consider the classical optimal dividends

More information

Band Control of Mutual Proportional Reinsurance

Band Control of Mutual Proportional Reinsurance Band Control of Mutual Proportional Reinsurance arxiv:1112.4458v1 [math.oc] 19 Dec 2011 John Liu College of Business, City University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Michael Taksar Department of Mathematics, University

More information

A Ruin Model with Compound Poisson Income and Dependence Between Claim Sizes and Claim Intervals

A Ruin Model with Compound Poisson Income and Dependence Between Claim Sizes and Claim Intervals Acta Mathematicae Applicatae Sinica, English Series Vol. 3, No. 2 (25) 445 452 DOI:.7/s255-5-478- http://www.applmath.com.cn & www.springerlink.com Acta Mathema cae Applicatae Sinica, English Series The

More information

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan) September 17, 2012 KAP 414 2:15 PM- 3:15 PM Prof. (University of Michigan) Abstract: We consider a zero-sum stochastic differential controller-and-stopper game in which the state process is a controlled

More information

Ruin probabilities in multivariate risk models with periodic common shock

Ruin probabilities in multivariate risk models with periodic common shock Ruin probabilities in multivariate risk models with periodic common shock January 31, 2014 3 rd Workshop on Insurance Mathematics Universite Laval, Quebec, January 31, 2014 Ruin probabilities in multivariate

More information

The finite-time Gerber-Shiu penalty function for two classes of risk processes

The finite-time Gerber-Shiu penalty function for two classes of risk processes The finite-time Gerber-Shiu penalty function for two classes of risk processes July 10, 2014 49 th Actuarial Research Conference University of California, Santa Barbara, July 13 July 16, 2014 The finite

More information

An optimal dividends problem with a terminal value for spectrally negative Lévy processes with a completely monotone jump density

An optimal dividends problem with a terminal value for spectrally negative Lévy processes with a completely monotone jump density An optimal dividends problem with a terminal value for spectrally negative Lévy processes with a completely monotone jump density R.L. Loeffen Radon Institute for Computational and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims

Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims Serguei Foss Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh Karlovasi, Samos 3 June, 2010 (Joint work with Tomasz Rolski and Stan Zachary

More information

Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Deterministic Dynamic Programming Deterministic Dynamic Programming 1 Value Function Consider the following optimal control problem in Mayer s form: V (t 0, x 0 ) = inf u U J(t 1, x(t 1 )) (1) subject to ẋ(t) = f(t, x(t), u(t)), x(t 0

More information

Optimal Execution Tracking a Benchmark

Optimal Execution Tracking a Benchmark Optimal Execution Tracking a Benchmark René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Princeton, June 20, 2013 Optimal Execution

More information

Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies

Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies Vathana LY VATH Laboratoire de Mathématiques et Modélisation d Evry ENSIIE and Université d Evry Joint work with E. Chevalier and M. Gaigi ICASQF,

More information

Optimal dividend policies with transaction costs for a class of jump-diffusion processes

Optimal dividend policies with transaction costs for a class of jump-diffusion processes Finance & Stochastics manuscript No. will be inserted by the editor) Optimal dividend policies with transaction costs for a class of jump-diffusion processes Martin Hunting Jostein Paulsen Received: date

More information

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games Joint work with Yu-Jui Huang University of Michigan, Ann Arbor June 7, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 4 5 Consider a zero-sum controller-and-stopper

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

On the Optimal Dividend Problem for Insurance Risk Models with Surplus-Dependent Premiums

On the Optimal Dividend Problem for Insurance Risk Models with Surplus-Dependent Premiums J Optim Theory Appl (216) 168:723 742 DOI 1.17/s1957-15-755-3 On the Optimal Dividend Problem for Insurance Risk Models with Surplus-Dependent Premiums Ewa Marciniak 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 2 Received: 18

More information

OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND FINANCING PROBLEMS FOR A DIFFUSION MODEL WITH EXCESS-OF-LOSS REINSURANCE STRATEGY AND TERMINAL VALUE

OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND FINANCING PROBLEMS FOR A DIFFUSION MODEL WITH EXCESS-OF-LOSS REINSURANCE STRATEGY AND TERMINAL VALUE Vol. 38 ( 218 ) No. 6 J. of Math. (PRC) OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND FINANCING PROBLEMS FOR A DIFFUSION MODEL WITH EXCESS-OF-LOSS REINSURANCE STRATEGY AND TERMINAL VALUE LI Tong, MA Shi-xia, Han Mi (School of

More information

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference Optimal exit strategies for investment projects Simone Scotti Université Paris Diderot Laboratoire de Probabilité et Modèles Aléatories Joint work with : Etienne Chevalier, Université d Evry Vathana Ly

More information

Reflected Brownian Motion

Reflected Brownian Motion Chapter 6 Reflected Brownian Motion Often we encounter Diffusions in regions with boundary. If the process can reach the boundary from the interior in finite time with positive probability we need to decide

More information

The optimality of a dividend barrier strategy for Lévy insurance risk processes, with a focus on the univariate Erlang mixture

The optimality of a dividend barrier strategy for Lévy insurance risk processes, with a focus on the univariate Erlang mixture The optimality of a dividend barrier strategy for Lévy insurance risk processes, with a focus on the univariate Erlang mixture by Javid Ali A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfilment

More information

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Erhan Bayraktar University of Michigan joint work with Virginia R. Young, University of Michigan K αρλoβασi,

More information

The equivalence of two tax processes

The equivalence of two tax processes The equivalence of two ta processes Dalal Al Ghanim Ronnie Loeffen Ale Watson 6th November 218 arxiv:1811.1664v1 [math.pr] 5 Nov 218 We introduce two models of taation, the latent and natural ta processes,

More information

Practical approaches to the estimation of the ruin probability in a risk model with additional funds

Practical approaches to the estimation of the ruin probability in a risk model with additional funds Modern Stochastics: Theory and Applications (204) 67 80 DOI: 05559/5-VMSTA8 Practical approaches to the estimation of the ruin probability in a risk model with additional funds Yuliya Mishura a Olena Ragulina

More information

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Lyapunov stability theory for ODEs s Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Part 1: Introduction Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Strathclyde Glasgow, G1 1XH December 2010

More information

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Proceedings of the World Congress on Engineering 29 Vol II WCE 29, July 1-3, 29, London, U.K. Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Tao Jiang Abstract

More information

A Note On The Erlang(λ, n) Risk Process

A Note On The Erlang(λ, n) Risk Process A Note On The Erlangλ, n) Risk Process Michael Bamberger and Mario V. Wüthrich Version from February 4, 2009 Abstract We consider the Erlangλ, n) risk process with i.i.d. exponentially distributed claims

More information

Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals

Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals Noèlia Viles Cuadros BCAM- Basque Center of Applied Mathematics with Prof. Enrico

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 21 Oct 2010

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 21 Oct 2010 The Annals of Applied Probability 21, Vol. 2, No. 4, 1253 132 DOI: 1.1214/9-AAP643 c Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 21 arxiv:11.4988v1 [q-fin.pm] 21 Oct 21 OPTIMAL INVESTMENT POLICY AND DIVIDEND

More information

Partial differential equation for temperature u(x, t) in a heat conducting insulated rod along the x-axis is given by the Heat equation:

Partial differential equation for temperature u(x, t) in a heat conducting insulated rod along the x-axis is given by the Heat equation: Chapter 7 Heat Equation Partial differential equation for temperature u(x, t) in a heat conducting insulated rod along the x-axis is given by the Heat equation: u t = ku x x, x, t > (7.1) Here k is a constant

More information

On Ergodic Impulse Control with Constraint

On Ergodic Impulse Control with Constraint On Ergodic Impulse Control with Constraint Maurice Robin Based on joint papers with J.L. Menaldi University Paris-Sanclay 9119 Saint-Aubin, France (e-mail: maurice.robin@polytechnique.edu) IMA, Minneapolis,

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 15 Jul 2015

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 15 Jul 2015 STRIKINGLY SIMPLE IDENTITIES RELATING EXIT PROBLEMS FOR LÉVY PROCESSES UNDER CONTINUOUS AND POISSON OBSERVATIONS arxiv:157.3848v2 [math.pr] 15 Jul 215 HANSJÖRG ALBRECHER AND JEVGENIJS IVANOVS Abstract.

More information

A RISK MODEL WITH MULTI-LAYER DIVIDEND STRATEGY

A RISK MODEL WITH MULTI-LAYER DIVIDEND STRATEGY A RISK MODEL WITH MULTI-LAYER DIVIDEND STRATEGY HANSJÖRG ALBRECHER AND JÜRGEN HARTINGER Abstract In recent years, various dividend payment strategies for the classical collective ris model have been studied

More information

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen Abstract We formulate a portfolio optimization problem as a game where the investor chooses a portfolio and his opponent,

More information

Extremes and ruin of Gaussian processes

Extremes and ruin of Gaussian processes International Conference on Mathematical and Statistical Modeling in Honor of Enrique Castillo. June 28-30, 2006 Extremes and ruin of Gaussian processes Jürg Hüsler Department of Math. Statistics, University

More information

Optimal Stopping and Maximal Inequalities for Poisson Processes

Optimal Stopping and Maximal Inequalities for Poisson Processes Optimal Stopping and Maximal Inequalities for Poisson Processes D.O. Kramkov 1 E. Mordecki 2 September 10, 2002 1 Steklov Mathematical Institute, Moscow, Russia 2 Universidad de la República, Montevideo,

More information

A Dynamic Contagion Process with Applications to Finance & Insurance

A Dynamic Contagion Process with Applications to Finance & Insurance A Dynamic Contagion Process with Applications to Finance & Insurance Angelos Dassios Department of Statistics London School of Economics Angelos Dassios, Hongbiao Zhao (LSE) A Dynamic Contagion Process

More information

Recursive methods for a multi-dimensional risk process with common shocks. Creative Commons: Attribution 3.0 Hong Kong License

Recursive methods for a multi-dimensional risk process with common shocks. Creative Commons: Attribution 3.0 Hong Kong License Title Recursive methods for a multi-dimensional risk process with common shocks Author(s) Gong, L; Badescu, AL; Cheung, ECK Citation Insurance: Mathematics And Economics, 212, v. 5 n. 1, p. 19-12 Issued

More information

Some lecture notes for Math 6050E: PDEs, Fall 2016

Some lecture notes for Math 6050E: PDEs, Fall 2016 Some lecture notes for Math 65E: PDEs, Fall 216 Tianling Jin December 1, 216 1 Variational methods We discuss an example of the use of variational methods in obtaining existence of solutions. Theorem 1.1.

More information

A LOGARITHMIC EFFICIENT ESTIMATOR OF THE PROBABILITY OF RUIN WITH RECUPERATION FOR SPECTRALLY NEGATIVE LEVY RISK PROCESSES.

A LOGARITHMIC EFFICIENT ESTIMATOR OF THE PROBABILITY OF RUIN WITH RECUPERATION FOR SPECTRALLY NEGATIVE LEVY RISK PROCESSES. A LOGARITHMIC EFFICIENT ESTIMATOR OF THE PROBABILITY OF RUIN WITH RECUPERATION FOR SPECTRALLY NEGATIVE LEVY RISK PROCESSES Riccardo Gatto Submitted: April 204 Revised: July 204 Abstract This article provides

More information

Analysis of the ruin probability using Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian theorems

Analysis of the ruin probability using Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian theorems Analysis of the ruin probability using Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian theorems Corina Constantinescu and Enrique Thomann Abstract The classical result of Cramer-Lundberg states that if the rate

More information

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Andrea Buraschi Imperial College Business School October 2010 The Euler Equation Take an economy where price is given with respect to the numéraire, which is our

More information

Scale functions for spectrally negative Lévy processes and their appearance in economic models

Scale functions for spectrally negative Lévy processes and their appearance in economic models Scale functions for spectrally negative Lévy processes and their appearance in economic models Andreas E. Kyprianou 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath 1 This is a review talk and

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

Necessary and sucient condition for the boundedness of the Gerber-Shiu function in dependent Sparre Andersen model

Necessary and sucient condition for the boundedness of the Gerber-Shiu function in dependent Sparre Andersen model Miskolc Mathematical Notes HU e-issn 1787-2413 Vol. 15 (214), No 1, pp. 159-17 OI: 1.18514/MMN.214.757 Necessary and sucient condition for the boundedness of the Gerber-Shiu function in dependent Sparre

More information

On Stopping Times and Impulse Control with Constraint

On Stopping Times and Impulse Control with Constraint On Stopping Times and Impulse Control with Constraint Jose Luis Menaldi Based on joint papers with M. Robin (216, 217) Department of Mathematics Wayne State University Detroit, Michigan 4822, USA (e-mail:

More information

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 A new approach for investment performance measurement 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 Thaleia Zariphopoulou University of Oxford, Oxford-Man Institute and The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance

More information

The first order quasi-linear PDEs

The first order quasi-linear PDEs Chapter 2 The first order quasi-linear PDEs The first order quasi-linear PDEs have the following general form: F (x, u, Du) = 0, (2.1) where x = (x 1, x 2,, x 3 ) R n, u = u(x), Du is the gradient of u.

More information

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a liquidity risk model with random trading times Huyên PHAM Special Semester on Stochastics with Emphasis on Finance, Kick-off workshop, Linz, September 8-12,

More information

Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications

Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications Journal of Mathematical Extension Vol. 11, No. 4, (2017), 27-44 ISSN: 1735-8299 URL: http://www.ijmex.com Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications 2 Mat B. Kafash 1 Faculty

More information

Poisson Processes. Stochastic Processes. Feb UC3M

Poisson Processes. Stochastic Processes. Feb UC3M Poisson Processes Stochastic Processes UC3M Feb. 2012 Exponential random variables A random variable T has exponential distribution with rate λ > 0 if its probability density function can been written

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 22 12/09/2013. Skorokhod Mapping Theorem. Reflected Brownian Motion

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 22 12/09/2013. Skorokhod Mapping Theorem. Reflected Brownian Motion MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 22 12/9/213 Skorokhod Mapping Theorem. Reflected Brownian Motion Content. 1. G/G/1 queueing system 2. One dimensional reflection mapping

More information

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT A MODEL FOR HE LONG-ERM OPIMAL CAPACIY LEVEL OF AN INVESMEN PROJEC ARNE LØKKA AND MIHAIL ZERVOS Abstract. We consider an investment project that produces a single commodity. he project s operation yields

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 19 Aug 2017

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 19 Aug 2017 Parisian ruin for the dual risk process in discrete-time Zbigniew Palmowski a,, Lewis Ramsden b, and Apostolos D. Papaioannou b, arxiv:1708.06785v1 [math.pr] 19 Aug 2017 a Department of Applied Mathematics

More information

Ruin probabilities of the Parisian type for small claims

Ruin probabilities of the Parisian type for small claims Ruin probabilities of the Parisian type for small claims Angelos Dassios, Shanle Wu October 6, 28 Abstract In this paper, we extend the concept of ruin in risk theory to the Parisian type of ruin. For

More information

Excursions of Risk Processes with Inverse Gaussian Processes and their Applications in Insurance

Excursions of Risk Processes with Inverse Gaussian Processes and their Applications in Insurance Excursions of Risk Processes with Inverse Gaussian Processes and their Applications in Insurance A thesis presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Shiju Liu Department of Statistics The London

More information

Healthcare and Consumption with Aging

Healthcare and Consumption with Aging Healthcare and Consumption with Aging Yu-Jui Huang University of Colorado Joint work with Paolo Guasoni Boston University and Dublin City University University of Colorado September 9, 2016 This is research

More information

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Paul Gassiat TU Berlin Stochastic processes and their statistics in Finance, Okinawa, October 28, 2013 Joint work with Joscha Diehl and Peter Friz Introduction

More information

Differential games withcontinuous, switching and impulse controls

Differential games withcontinuous, switching and impulse controls Differential games withcontinuous, switching and impulse controls A.J. Shaiju a,1, Sheetal Dharmatti b,,2 a TIFR Centre, IISc Campus, Bangalore 5612, India b Department of Mathematics, Indian Institute

More information

Ruin Theory. A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science at George Mason University

Ruin Theory. A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science at George Mason University Ruin Theory A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science at George Mason University by Ashley Fehr Bachelor of Science West Virginia University, Spring

More information

Optional Stopping Theorem Let X be a martingale and T be a stopping time such

Optional Stopping Theorem Let X be a martingale and T be a stopping time such Plan Counting, Renewal, and Point Processes 0. Finish FDR Example 1. The Basic Renewal Process 2. The Poisson Process Revisited 3. Variants and Extensions 4. Point Processes Reading: G&S: 7.1 7.3, 7.10

More information

Martingale Problems. Abhay G. Bhatt Theoretical Statistics and Mathematics Unit Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi

Martingale Problems. Abhay G. Bhatt Theoretical Statistics and Mathematics Unit Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi s Abhay G. Bhatt Theoretical Statistics and Mathematics Unit Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi Lectures on Probability and Stochastic Processes III Indian Statistical Institute, Kolkata 20 24 November

More information

ERRATA: Probabilistic Techniques in Analysis

ERRATA: Probabilistic Techniques in Analysis ERRATA: Probabilistic Techniques in Analysis ERRATA 1 Updated April 25, 26 Page 3, line 13. A 1,..., A n are independent if P(A i1 A ij ) = P(A 1 ) P(A ij ) for every subset {i 1,..., i j } of {1,...,

More information

Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model

Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model Karel Janeček Zheng Li Mihai Sîrbu August 2, 218 Abstract This paper studies the problem of optimal investment and

More information

CIMPA SCHOOL, 2007 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc

CIMPA SCHOOL, 2007 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc CIMPA SCHOOL, 27 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc 1 Jump Processes I. Poisson Processes II. Lévy Processes III. Jump-Diffusion Processes IV. Point Processes 2 I. Poisson Processes

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH

More information

Sobolev Spaces. Chapter 10

Sobolev Spaces. Chapter 10 Chapter 1 Sobolev Spaces We now define spaces H 1,p (R n ), known as Sobolev spaces. For u to belong to H 1,p (R n ), we require that u L p (R n ) and that u have weak derivatives of first order in L p

More information

On Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities in a Risk Model Under Quota Share Reinsurance

On Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities in a Risk Model Under Quota Share Reinsurance Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 11, 217, no. 53, 269-2629 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com https://doi.org/1.12988/ams.217.7824 On Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities in a Risk Model Under Quota Share Reinsurance

More information

Ruin Probabilities of a Discrete-time Multi-risk Model

Ruin Probabilities of a Discrete-time Multi-risk Model Ruin Probabilities of a Discrete-time Multi-risk Model Andrius Grigutis, Agneška Korvel, Jonas Šiaulys Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics, Vilnius University, Naugarduko 4, Vilnius LT-035, Lithuania

More information

Continuous dependence estimates for the ergodic problem with an application to homogenization

Continuous dependence estimates for the ergodic problem with an application to homogenization Continuous dependence estimates for the ergodic problem with an application to homogenization Claudio Marchi Bayreuth, September 12 th, 2013 C. Marchi (Università di Padova) Continuous dependence Bayreuth,

More information

Some notes on viscosity solutions

Some notes on viscosity solutions Some notes on viscosity solutions Jeff Calder October 11, 2018 1 2 Contents 1 Introduction 5 1.1 An example............................ 6 1.2 Motivation via dynamic programming............. 8 1.3 Motivation

More information

Simulation methods in ruin models with non-linear dividend barriers

Simulation methods in ruin models with non-linear dividend barriers Simulation methods in ruin models with non-linear dividend barriers Hansjörg Albrecher, Reinhold Kainhofer, Robert F. Tichy Department of Mathematics, Graz University of Technology, Steyrergasse 3, A-8

More information

VISCOSITY SOLUTION AND IMPULSE CONTROL OF THE DIFFUSION MODEL WITH REINSURANCE AND FIXED TRANSACTION COSTS

VISCOSITY SOLUTION AND IMPULSE CONTROL OF THE DIFFUSION MODEL WITH REINSURANCE AND FIXED TRANSACTION COSTS VISCOSITY SOLUTION AND IMPULSE CONTROL OF THE DIFFUSION MODEL WITH REINSURANCE AND FIXED TRANSACTION COSTS Huiqi Guan Department of Mathematical Sciences, Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, China. Email:

More information

Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet

Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet LATP June 5, 2011 A ratchet source : wikipedia Plan 1 Introduction : The model of Haigh 2 3 Hypothesis (Biological) : The population

More information

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Samuel N. Cohen Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford (Based on joint work with Ying Hu, Robert Elliott, Lukas Szpruch) Centre Henri Lebesgue,

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

Exam February h

Exam February h Master 2 Mathématiques et Applications PUF Ho Chi Minh Ville 2009/10 Viscosity solutions, HJ Equations and Control O.Ley (INSA de Rennes) Exam February 2010 3h Written-by-hands documents are allowed. Printed

More information

Point Process Control

Point Process Control Point Process Control The following note is based on Chapters I, II and VII in Brémaud s book Point Processes and Queues (1981). 1 Basic Definitions Consider some probability space (Ω, F, P). A real-valued

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 15. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Distribution of the first ladder height of a stationary risk process perturbed by α-stable Lévy motion

Distribution of the first ladder height of a stationary risk process perturbed by α-stable Lévy motion Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 28 (21) 13 2 Distribution of the first ladder height of a stationary risk process perturbed by α-stable Lévy motion Hanspeter Schmidli Laboratory of Actuarial Mathematics,

More information

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past.

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past. 1 Markov chain: definition Lecture 5 Definition 1.1 Markov chain] A sequence of random variables (X n ) n 0 taking values in a measurable state space (S, S) is called a (discrete time) Markov chain, if

More information

Weak convergence and large deviation theory

Weak convergence and large deviation theory First Prev Next Go To Go Back Full Screen Close Quit 1 Weak convergence and large deviation theory Large deviation principle Convergence in distribution The Bryc-Varadhan theorem Tightness and Prohorov

More information

Value Iteration and Action ɛ-approximation of Optimal Policies in Discounted Markov Decision Processes

Value Iteration and Action ɛ-approximation of Optimal Policies in Discounted Markov Decision Processes Value Iteration and Action ɛ-approximation of Optimal Policies in Discounted Markov Decision Processes RAÚL MONTES-DE-OCA Departamento de Matemáticas Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana-Iztapalapa San Rafael

More information

Poisson random measure: motivation

Poisson random measure: motivation : motivation The Lévy measure provides the expected number of jumps by time unit, i.e. in a time interval of the form: [t, t + 1], and of a certain size Example: ν([1, )) is the expected number of jumps

More information

1 Directional Derivatives and Differentiability

1 Directional Derivatives and Differentiability Wednesday, January 18, 2012 1 Directional Derivatives and Differentiability Let E R N, let f : E R and let x 0 E. Given a direction v R N, let L be the line through x 0 in the direction v, that is, L :=

More information

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option A Barrier Version of the Russian Option L. A. Shepp, A. N. Shiryaev, A. Sulem Rutgers University; shepp@stat.rutgers.edu Steklov Mathematical Institute; shiryaev@mi.ras.ru INRIA- Rocquencourt; agnes.sulem@inria.fr

More information

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Remigijus Leipus (with Yang Yang, Yuebao Wang, Jonas Šiaulys) CIRM, Luminy, April 26-30, 2010 1. Preliminaries

More information

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting dx t = a t dt + b t db t dy t = α t dt + β t db t, and taking f(x, y = xy, one has f x = y, f y = x, and f xx = f yy

More information

An optimal reinsurance problem in the Cramér Lundberg model

An optimal reinsurance problem in the Cramér Lundberg model Math Meth Oper Res DOI 1.17/s186-16-559-8 ORIGINAL ARTICLE An optimal reinsurance problem in the Cramér Lundberg model Arian Cani 1 Stefan Thonhauser 2 Received: 23 February 216 / Accepeted: 1 August 216

More information

On the probability of reaching a barrier in an Erlang(2) risk process

On the probability of reaching a barrier in an Erlang(2) risk process Statistics & Operations Research Transactions SORT 29 (2) July-December 25, 235-248 ISSN: 1696-2281 www.idescat.net/sort Statistics & Operations Research c Institut d Estadística de Transactions Catalunya

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 23 Apr 2016

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 23 Apr 2016 Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) On the Optimal Dividend Problem for Insurance Risk Models with Surplus-Dependent Premiums arxiv:164.6892v1 [q-fin.pm] 23 Apr 216 Ewa Marciniak Zbigniew

More information

Gerber Shiu Risk Theory

Gerber Shiu Risk Theory Andreas E. Kyprianou Gerber Shiu Risk Theory Draft May 15, 213 Springer Preface These notes were developed whilst giving a graduate lecture course (Nachdiplomvorlesung) at the Forschungsinstitut für Mathematik,

More information

On the Bellman equation for control problems with exit times and unbounded cost functionals 1

On the Bellman equation for control problems with exit times and unbounded cost functionals 1 On the Bellman equation for control problems with exit times and unbounded cost functionals 1 Michael Malisoff Department of Mathematics, Hill Center-Busch Campus Rutgers University, 11 Frelinghuysen Road

More information

A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under. Liquidity Risk and Price Impact

A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under. Liquidity Risk and Price Impact A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under Liquidity Risk and Price Impact Huyên PHAM Workshop on PDE and Mathematical Finance KTH, Stockholm, August 15, 2005 Laboratoire de Probabilités et Modèles Aléatoires

More information

THE SKOROKHOD OBLIQUE REFLECTION PROBLEM IN A CONVEX POLYHEDRON

THE SKOROKHOD OBLIQUE REFLECTION PROBLEM IN A CONVEX POLYHEDRON GEORGIAN MATHEMATICAL JOURNAL: Vol. 3, No. 2, 1996, 153-176 THE SKOROKHOD OBLIQUE REFLECTION PROBLEM IN A CONVEX POLYHEDRON M. SHASHIASHVILI Abstract. The Skorokhod oblique reflection problem is studied

More information