APrimeronDifferential Equations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "APrimeronDifferential Equations"

Transcription

1 APrimeronDifferential Equations Francesco Giavazzi September 2007 Preliminaries: Classification of differential equations Adifferential equation is any equation that contains a differential, or derivative. Differential equations can be ordinary or partial, depending whether they contain ordinary or partial derivatives. They are classified accordingtotheirorder (whether they contain a first derivative, a second derivative or a higher order derivative), whether they are linear or non linear, and whether they are autonomous or non autonomous. 1.1 order The order of a differential equation is determined by the highest order of derivative contained in the equation. An example of a second order differential equation is 3ÿ +2ẏ + y =2 1.2 autonomous, non autonomous Adifferential equation is said to be autonomous if it does not depend on time explicitly; otherwise it is non autonomous. For example, ẏ +5y = t is a non autonomous first-order equation. But ẏ +5y =3 is an autonomous first-order equation. ThesenotesareinspiredbyMaurice Obstfeld s Primer on Differential Equations (unpublished, Spring 1980) which is unfortunately no longer available. IGIER, Università Bocconi 1

2 1.3 linear, non linear Adifferential equation is non linear if it involves any non linear terms in y, ẏ, ÿ, andsoon.itislinearifall the y terms are raised to no power than 1. For example, ẏ + t 2 y =cost is a linear, but non autonomous first-order differential equation, whereas ẏ + y 2 =2 is a non linear, autonomous, first-order differential equation. Before proceeding, it may be useful to recall that a solution to a differential equation is a function that makes the differential equation true. There are usually many solutions to a differential equation. For example, consider the linear, autonomous, first-order differential equation that describes the accumulation of capital in a closed economy without capital depreciation: K = I(t) One solution is Another is The general solution is K(t) =It K(t) =It +1 K(t) =It + C where C is an arbitrary constant. To verify that this is indeed a solution, differentiate it and see that the derivative of K does equal I. Since C can take any value, there is an infinity of solutions to this differential equation. However, if we are given more information, such as the initial value of K, we can determine the value of C. For example, if we are given that K(0) = 3, which means the value of the economy s endowment of capital K at t =0 was 3, then the value of C must be 3. 2

3 PRIMER ON DIFFERENTIAL EQUATION 1. Autonomous systems of differential equations The most general differential equations systems have the form dx/dt = dy/dt = ẋ = Φ (x, y, t) (1) ẏ = Ψ (x, y, t) We shall start by considering the case in which time, t, does not appear explicitly on the right-hand-side. Such differential equations are called autonomous or purely homogeneous Autonomous systems are time-independent, and therefore a stationary state (or steady state, or long run equilibrium) for the variables x and y is defined by the conditions Φ (x, y) = 0 Ψ (x, y) = 0 (2) By shifting the origin, we may take this stationary or long run equilibrium to be the point (0, 0). (2) will in general be a non-linear system. A first pass at studying the properties of such a system consists in linearizing it around the stationary equilibrium and then studying the dynamic properties of the linearized system. What we shall find is an approximation, and will obviously be valid only for small displacements of (x, y) from(0, 0). Linearizing (with a second order Taylor expansion) Φ and Ψ in a neighborhood of the origin we will obtain dx/dt = dy/dt = ẋ = ax + by (3) ẏ = cx + dy where a = Φ x, etc. and all partial derivatives are evaluated at (0, 0). Our goal is to solve the system (3) by expressing x and y as functions of time. Before doing this, it is useful to consider the case of a single differential equation in a single variable. We shall then see how the 2x2 system can be reduced to the simpler case. 3

4 1.1 The single-variable case We are now faced with the simple linear system dx/dt = ẋ = ax (4) Consider a solution of the form x(t) = K exp(at), where K is an arbitrary constant. Differentiating with respect to time we see that dx/dt = ẋ = ak exp(at) =ax(t), so that we have indeed found a solution for (4). Since K = x(0), choosing the arbitrary constant K is equivalent to choosing an initial condition for x. The subsequent evolution of x is then governed by (4). It is important to remember that there are infinitelymanypathscompatible with with a differential equation, and that we can choose a particular path only by choosing an initial condition or starting point for the variables of the system. The analysis of stability is trivial in a single-variable system. If a>0, it is evident that x(t) as t, and so the system fails to attain a stationary state: it is dynamically unstable. When a<0, x(t) 0as t, and so the system is stable with stationary state x = The general case Our strategy is to exploit our knowledge of the solution to (4) in order to solve (3). Writing (3) in matrix form, we have ẋ. y x = A y We notice immediately that if we can find a change in coordinates such that A becomes diagonal, we may reduce the system to one in which our previous result can be used, i.e. to two first-order differential equations such as in (4). We know that we can write A = P ΛP 1,whereΛ is the diagonal matrix whose non-zero elements are the eigenvalues λ 1 and λ 2 of A and P is a matrix whose columns are the eigenvectors of A. Multiplying both sides of (5) by P 1 and defining u v = P 1 x y we obtain.ụ λ1 0 u = v 0 λ 2 v which is the diagonalization we were looking for. (5) (6) 4

5 It is now immediate that the solution to (6) has the form u(t) = K 1 exp(λ 1 t) v(t) = K 2 exp(λ 2 t) where K 1 and K 2 are arbitrary constants. We now need only transform this solution back in terms of x and y, the original state variables. Since P u v 0 = x y 0,wemustlookmorecloselyatP,thematrixofthe eigenvectors of A. To find P,weusethefactthatAP = P Λ. Writing e11 e P = 12 e 21 e 22 we see that ae 11 + be 21 = λ 1 e 11 ce 11 + de 21 = λ 1 e 21 and so the eigenvector 0 e 11 e 21 (which, you should remember, is defined only up to multiplication by a constant, because the rows of the matrix h b of the eigenvectors are not linearly independent) is given by m (λ 1 a) 1 where m 6= 0 is some constant. Observation Note that we could have chosen our eigenvector to be a multiple of [(λ 1 d) /c 1] 0. But as we shall see in a moment, this would make no difference, because any eigenvalue λ must satisfy (λ d) /c = b/ (λ a), which is simply the systems characteristic equation, that is the solution to λ a b det =0 c λ d (end of observation) Returning to the equations that allow us to compute the e ij,wefind with the same steps followed above that 0 e 12 e 22 can be written as h i0 n,wheren is arbitrary. Having found P,wecannowfind b (λ 2 a) 1 u v = P 1 x y 5 i0,

6 so that x(t) y(t) = P u(t) v(t) mb/ (λ1 a) nb/ (λ 2 a) m n K1 exp (λ 1 t) K 2 exp (λ 2 t) which allows us to write the general solution of (3) in the form x(t) = [k 1 b/ (λ 1 a)] exp (λ 1 t)+[k 2 b/ (λ 2 a)] exp (λ 2 t) (7) y(t) = k 1 exp (λ 1 t)+k 2 exp (λ 2 t) where now k 1 = mk 1 and k 2 = nk 2 are arbitrary constants to be determined by the initial conditions. 1.3 Stability of the autonomous systems of differential equations Before proceeding with a quantitative analysis of the solutions, it is common in economic applications to conduct a qualitative analysis, often with a phase diagram. In order to do this, we require two types of information. First, we need to know the steady-state values for y and x (i.e. the values for which ẏ, ẋ = 0). Second, we need to know the arrows of motion of the system around the steady state values, to determine whether or not the system would converge to one of these steady state values. Solution (7) makes clear that the stability of the system (3) i.e. its tendency (or lack of) to converge to a stationary position is crucially linked to the signs of its characteristic roots λ 1 and λ 2.Itiseasytofind these roots. If λ is an eigenvalue, we know that there is an eigenvector e such that A e λ e =0andsoifI is the 2x2 identity matrix, A λi must be singular, i.e. its determinant det (A λi) must be zero. The characteristic equation of (3) can thus be written as λ 2 (a + d) λ +(ad bc) =λ 2 tr(a) + det(a) =0. The two roots of this equation are obviously just the eigenvalues of A. From the quadratic formula we obtain λ 1,λ 2 = tr(a) ± tr(a) 2 4det(A) 1/2 2 (8) 6

7 We must now distinguish between real and complex roots: Real Roots: a) λ 1,λ 2 negative; λ 1,λ 2 positive Let us initially assume that the eigenvalues are real. If the two roots of (8) are negative, it is obvious from (7) that, regardless of the initial conditions imposed, x(t) andy(t) will converge to a stationary equilibrium (0, 0) as t, because exp(λt) 0whenλ is negative. In this case the system is stable, i.e. it will converge to a stationary state from any starting point. From (8) it is immediate that a necessary and sufficient condition for both roots to be negative is that tr(a) < 0 and det(a) > 0. (λ 1 + λ 2 = tr(a); λ 1 λ 2 = det(a)) Following the same reasoning, it appears clear that when λ 1, 2 is positive, the system will fail to converge, diverging from the stationary state from any starting point. b) λ 1 positive, λ 2 negative, or vice-versa If, on the contrary, it happens to be det(a) < 0, we see from (8) that one root will be negative and the other positive. This is the case of saddlepath stability that arises in many economic models characterized by: (i) the assumption that agents form their expectations with full knowledge of the future (the assumption of perfect foresight) (ii) the presence, in the system, of non-predetermined variables, that is variable such as the price of a financial asset, but also consumption that canjumpinreactionto news. What does saddlepath stability entail? For concreteness, assume λ 2 < 0. Then we see that if k 1 6= 0, the system s behavior will sooner or later be dominated by its positive root λ 1, and the state variables will exhibit an explosive behavior. However, if we impose the initial condition k 1 = 0, the system s behavior will depend only on its negative root, and a stationary equilibrium will in the long run be attained. The condition k 1 = 0 implies a relationship between x and y µ (λ2 a) y(t) = x(t) (9) b 7

8 The locus described by (9) which is derived from (7) is the stable branch (or saddlepath, or stable manifold) of the system. It is the unique path in the (x, y) plane which converges to (0, 0). A typical saddlepath configuration is illustrated in Figure (1). The condition k 1 = 0 is typically imposed in macroeconomic models. Notice that if one of the two variables in the system is non-predetermined, (9) is necessary to uniquely determine the equilibrium at any instant t. This is because, at any t, one variable (the pre-determined variable, e.g. thestock of capital) will be given by history, but the other variable (e.g. the price of capital, which is non pre-determined, i.e. not given by history) needs an additional condition to be determined. Absent (9), the equilibrium of the system at any t would not be determined. Animportantcaseinwhichwedo not impose k 1 = 0 is when we study the response of the economy to anticipated future changes in some exogenous variables for instance when we ask how does consumption react to the 8

9 announcement of a future increase in government spending. In this case a set of initial conditions naturally emerges from economic reasoning Complex Roots When tr(a) 2 4 det(a) < 0, the characteristic roots are complex numbers. Since the coefficients of the characteristic equation (6) are real, complex roots will always occur as complex conjugate pairs. Hence, if p + iq is one root, the other root must be p iq. For instance, suppose that: [λ 1 ] = [p + iq] [λ 2 ] = [p iq] then, from the fact that x(0) = k 1 b/(λ 1 a)+k 2 b/(λ 2 a) mustbereal, we deduce that k 1 b/(λ 1 a) k 2 b/(λ 2 a) must be complex conjugates, which can be written in polar form as re iθ and re iθ.recalling that x(t) =[k 1 b/ (λ 1 a)] exp (λ 1 t)+[k 2 b/ (λ 2 a)] exp (λ 2 t) and substituting, we have: x(t) =r exp(iθ)exp(p + iq)t + r exp( iθ)exp(p iq)t = = r exp(pt)exp(i(qt + θ)) + r exp(pt)exp( i(qt + θ)) = =2r exp(pt)cos(qt + θ) = =2r exp(pt)(cos(θ)cos(qt) sin(θ)sin(qt)). Rewriting it, for clarity s sake: x(t) = 2r exp(pt)(cos(θ)cos(qt) sin(θ)sin(qt)). (10) On the other hand, substituting λ 1 = p + iq in re iθ = k 1 b/(λ 1 a), and isolating k 1,wehavek 1 = re iθ (p a + iq)/b, andsymmetrically k 2 = re iθ (p a iq)/b. Recalling that: y(t) =k 1 exp (λ 1 t)+k 2 exp (λ 2 t) 9

10 and proceeding as above, we can show that: y(t) =2r exp(pt)([p a)/b cos(θ) c/b sin(θ)] cos(qt) [(p a)/b sin(θ)+q/b cos(θ)] sin(qt)). (11) It is evident that the system x(t), y(t) will exhibit damped oscillations if the real part p of its roots is negative, and will be unstable otherwise. Choice of r and θ yields the two initial conditions needed to describe the path of the system. It should be noted that the stability criterion developed above ( ẋ =0,ẏ = 0 ) remains valid. 1.4 Summary The steady-state solutions to an autonomous system of differential equations are said to be stable if the system converges to the steady state solutions and unstable otherwise. We have found that the stability characteristics of differential equations depend on the sign of the characteristic roots. Roots with negative real parts are associated with differential equations that converge to the steady state (stable); roots with positive real parts are associated with differential equations that diverge from the steady state (unstable). The stability of a system of differential equations also depends on the signs of the roots of the characteristic equation. The following theorem recaps the conditions of convergence: THEOREM The steady-state solution of a system of linear, autonomous differential equations is asymptotically stable if and only if the characteristic roots are negative (the real part is negative in the case of complex-valued roots). In economic models, it is common to obtain a system of differential equations in which one of the characteristic roots is positive and the other one is negative. In this case, the steady-state equilibrium is called a saddlepoint equilibrium, and it is unstable. However, y(t) andx(t) convergeto their steady-state solutions if the initial conditions satisfy k 1 =0,which implies y(t) = ³ (λ2 a) b x(t). The locus of points (y, x)defined by this equation is known as the saddle path. 10

11 2. Non autonomous linear systems We shall now consider systems of general form ẋ = [ax + by + v(t)] (12) ẏ = [cx + dy + w(t)] As t is included explicitly, then this is a non-autonomous system. To start, it is again useful to look at the case of a single equation in one variable: ẋ =[ax + v(t)] (13) where the term (ν) is function of time, and t is included explicitly Thesinglevariablecase We refer to ax as the homogenous part of the above equation and to v(t) astheinhomogenous part. Aswehaveseen,ageneralsolutionto the homogenous part is given by x(t) =K exp(at). To solve this form, we guess a solution of form: where f(t) is a function to be determined. To find f(t),we differentiate (14), obtaining x(t) =K exp(at)f(t) (14) ẋ(t) = K exp(at)f 0 (t)+ak exp(at)f(t) = = ax(t)+v(t) (provided that K exp(at)f(t) = x(t) ). Hence v(t) = K exp(at)f 0(t), or f 0(t) =(1/K)exp( at)v(t). As the reader well knows, the second Fundamental Theorem of Calculus holds for any f, continuous on an open interval I, andanya point in I, stating that if F is defined by 11

12 then F (x) = Z x a f(t)dt F 0 (x) =f(x) at each point in I. In our case, being f 0 (t) =(1/K)exp( at)v(t), we may rewrite : Z ½ (1/K) exp( as)v(s)ds + C 1 a > 0 t f(t) = Z t (1/K) exp(as)v(s) ds + C 2 a<0 ¾ where a > 0 is often referred to as the forward solution, and a<0 viceversa. Using this result, we easily obtain the solution for the equation (12): ½ k exp(at) x(t) = k exp(at)+ Z t Z t where k is given by an initial condition. exp(a(t s))v(s)ds a > 0 ¾ exp(a(t s))v(s)ds a < 0 We have made our choice of solution depending on the sign of a: a positive a denotes a forward solution, as we have already noticed. This dependency implies that we are implicitly assuming that x(t) should be finite for all functions v(t) that do not grow too quickly with time. For example, if we were to choose the firsttypeofsolution(the forwardlooking solution), when a<0, the integral term will fail to converge. We illustrate this last remark with an example. 12

13 Example 1: the Cagan hyperinflation model In his classic paper, Cagan (1956) studied seven hyperinflation. Hyperinflation is defined as a period during which the price level of goods in terms of money rises at a rate averaging at least 50% per month. We consider the Cagan hyperinflation model of money demand. Let M denote a country s money supply, and P its price level. Demand for real money balances M P depends entirely on expected future price-level inflation: once expected inflation rises, then M P decreases, by rising the opportunity cost of holding money. If we write the demand for real balances in the log linear form, we have m d p = aπ (a >0) where m log M, p log P and π ṗ. The relation above is a first order differential equation, which explains price level dynamics in terms of money supply (m d = m), taking money supply as an exogenous variable. (E1.1 rational expectations) If we close the model by assuming rational expectations, E(π) = ṗ, we find that the price level is governed by the non-autonomuos d.e.: ṗ =(1/a)p (1/a)m(t) Utilizing the previous findings, a solution for the price level must have the form: p(t) =k exp((1/a)t)+(1/a) Z t exp((1/a)(t s))m(s)ds As in our earlier discussion, it is reasonable to impose the initial condition k = 0, which prevents the behavior of p(t) from being dominated by the positive root 1/a. It is also the only initial condition consistent with the sensible requirement that p(t) = m when m(s) = m for all s > t. The economic reason to set k = 0 is that allows us to rule out speculative bubbles. We thus obtain Z p(t) =(1/a) exp((1/a)(t s))m(s)ds t 13

14 The price level consists simply in an esponentially-weighted average of all future money stocks, a solution consistent with the hypotesized forwardlooking behavior of agents in rational expectations models. Looking closer, the remaining integral term shows that the price level depends on a discounted value of future money supply m with weight summing to one. This implies that money is fully neutral: changing the level of the money supply or the nominal unit of account by the same proportion on all dates leads to an immediate equal proportional change in the price level. (This feature is characteristic of all models that lack nominal rigidities or money illusion). (E1.2 adaptive expectations) We might alternatively close the Cagan model by allowing expectations to evolve according to the adaptive formula π = b(ṗ π) = bπ + bṗ (b >0) Now the system s root ( b) is negative, and so the backward solution is the convergent one. Under adaptive expectations, as we shall see in a moment, agents take the past alone into account in setting today s price level. The solution for the expected inflation rate is then: Z t π(t) =m(t)+ab exp( b(t s))p(s)ds Our convergence assumption allows today s price level to depend only on today s money stock and the past history of inflation. This is no surprise. The reader should be aware, however, that there exist rational expectations models in which only the backward-looking solution converges, so that it is rational to ignore the future in setting prices. The implication is that the convergence assumption should not be taken lightly. Example 2: Capital growth in an economy with technological change (from Hoy, Livernois, McKenna, Rees, Stengos, 2001) Consider a simple model of an economy that produces output using only capital. The amount produced is given by the production function which, we assume, shifts over time because of technological change. Letting y denote output, and k denote capital, we assume that the technical relationship is 14

15 y =(a + ak)t 1/2 This says that output is a linear function of the amount of capital in the economy k, but that, over time, the entire function increases. We further assume that a constant share s of output is saved, where 0 <s<1. Capital accumulation in the economy is equal to savings. Therefore Rearranging, it gives k = s(a + αk)t 1/2 k sαt 1/2 k = sαt 1/2 We wish to solve this to obtain an expression showing k as a function of t. Thecoefficient is sαt 1/2.Therefore A(t) = which can be integrated to obtain Z 0 sαt 1/2 dt A(t) = 2 3 sαt3/2 An equivalent expression for the differential equation then is d h i e 2sαt3/2 /3 k = sαt 1/2 e 2sαt3/2 /3 dt Integrating both sides gives e 2sαt3/2 /3 k = sa Z 0 t 1/2 e 2sαt3/2 /3 dt + C The integration on the right-hand side can be taken further to get " # e 2sαt3/2 e 2sαt3/2 /3 /3 k = sa sα Solving for k(t) gives k(t) = a α + Ce 2sαt3/2 /3 Assuming an initial condition of k(0) = k 0,wemustset 15

16 C = a α + k 0 After substituting, we get k(t) = a ³ a α + α + k 0 e 2sαt3/2 /3 as the explicit solution for capital in this model. 2.2 The general case To deal with the general case ẋ = [ax + by + v(t)] ẏ = [cx + dy + w(t)] we may once again change coordinates so that we have a diagonal system and then invoke the solution just derived. At this point, the reader now has at hand the tools needed to find a general solution Concluding remarks: higher dimension systems We have restricted our attention to systems of dimension 2 or lower. Our techniques obviously extend to higher-dimensional systems, but the algebra becomes tedious. Our methods also handle higher order equations like ẍ = aẋ + bx To solve, we merely define y = ẋ, and then solve the two-dimensional first-order system ẋ = y ẏ = ay + bx Finally, all our results have exact analogues in the discrete-time, difference equation framework favored by many. The interested reader should consult the texts by Sargent. 3. Introducing disturbances in a perfect foresight model 16

17 This paragraph discusses the response to an anticipated future monetary disturbance in Dornbusch s model of exchange-rate dynamics, which is the perfect-foresight extension of the Mundell Fleming model. In the first section we discuss an important continuity condition implicitly imposed whenever we describe the paths available to economies in which agents have perfect foresights. In the following section, we apply this condition to obtain an analytical solution for the path chosen by the economy in response to an announced future increase in the money supply. In the final section, we present an alternative derivation using the original method of Sargent and Wallace. This alternative approach has the advantage of making explicit the effects of the change in expectations that occurs when the announcement is made THE CONTINUITY CONDITION.* Empirical evidence has shown that, during the 70s and the 80s, the industrialized economies in the world saw years of economic instability. If volatile money supplies had amplified effects on exchange rates, Dornbusch reasoned, they might be substantially responsible for the sharp exchange rate fluctuations observed. Buthowdothepricelevelandtheexchangerateinaneconomy respond to a change in the money supply? The Dornbusch overshooting model provides a framework for conducting an interesting analysis of this and related questions. In addition, it provides a classic example of a system of two linear, first-order differential equations for which the steady state is a saddle point equilibrium. We can introduce a simplified version of the Dornbusch exchange-rate dynamics model considering a small open economy, that faces an exogenous world rate. The money demand is described by m D p = λr + ψy where m is the demand of money, p the price level, r the domestic interest rate, y the domestic level of output, and λ and ψ are constant positive coefficients of the money demand function. All lower case are logarithms in the Dornbusch model. As a result, the real supply of money is given by m S = m p, wherem is the exogenous nominal supply of money. Equilibrium in the asset market requires that supply equals demand : 17

18 m p = λr + ψy If this economy were not open to trade with other countries, this equation would determine the equilibrium interest rate, r. However, because the economy is assumed to be open to trade, international capital movements will force the interest rate to equal the world interest rate,r,inthe absence of exchange rate fluctuations. However, if we allow variations in the exchange rate, an interest rate differential equal to the expected rate of depreciation of the home currency can persist. Symbolically this means that r = r + E(ė) where E(ė) is the expected rate of depreciation of the exchange rate. The exchange rate, e, is defined as the domestic price of foreign currency. Note that it is correct to interpret ė as a rate of change or depreciation because e is the logarithm of the actual exchange rate. For example, if the U.S. dollar is expected to depreciate by 1% against other currencies, then the U.S. interest rate will be 1% higher than the world rate in equilibrium. Investors are not willing to exploit the interest differential any further because their earnings are denominated in dollars, which are expected to depreciate by 1%, thereby canceling the higher interest rate. Dornbusch assumes that economic agents have perfect foresight when forecasting exchange rate movements. This means that expected and actual rates of depreciation of the exchange rate are assumed to be equal. This implies that E(ė) =ė and thus the interest parity implies r = r + ė Substituting the interest parity condition in the money market equation, and taking y = r = 0 for simplicity, we get, after some rearranging: ė = m λ + p λ This is one of the two linear differential equations in the model. The second one, which we derive next, describes the dynamics of the domestic 18

19 price level. Whereas we have assumed that the asset market is always in equilibrium (exchange rate and interest rate adjust continuously), we assume that prices adjust sluggishly in response to excess demand. Specifically, we assume that ṗ = δ(y D y S ) δ>0 where y D and y S are the (logarithms of) aggregate quantity demanded and supplied respectively, and δ is the speed-of-adjustment coefficient. Under the assumption that the (logarithm of) supply is fixed at 0, and the demand is given by y D =(e p), we get ṗ = δ(e p) which is the second linear differential equation in the model, and describes the price-level adjustment. The model can be expressed in the dynamic system ṗ δ δ p p = ė 1/λ 0 e ē (15) δ δ Labelling A = 1/λ 0, the determinant of this system is negative: det(a) = δ λ < 0 therefore, its real roots are of opposite sign one another. This means that the economy is governed by a saddle path of equilibrium. The system steady state,as is easily verified, is described by p =ē = m. To draw the isoclines for p and e, and to describe their motion in response to changes of the fundamentals of the economy, we proceed as follows. isoclines ṗ =0 = e = p ė =0 = p = m = p arrows of motion 19

20 p: δṗ/δp = δ <0 (the derivative is negative above the line ṗ =0) δṗ/δe =+δ>0 (the derivative is postive below the line ṗ =0) e: δė/δp =+1/λ > 0 (the derivative is positive above ė =0) δė/δe = 1/λ < 0 (the derivative is negative below ė =0) We can now draw our economy: Letting μ 1 and μ 2 denote the eigenvalues of the matrix, μ 1 > 0 >μ 2, we find the associated eigenvectors are multiples of [λμ 1 1] and [λμ 2 1 ], and we may thus write the general (continuous) solution to(15)as: p(t) p = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t)+k 2 λμ 2 exp(μ 2 t) (16) e(t) ē = k 1 exp(μ 1 t)+k 2 exp(μ 2 t) 20

21 ,where k 1 and k 2 are given by choice of initial conditions, while p is predetermined. By restricting ourselves to the above continuous solutions, we have ruled out paths of the type shown in Fig.3, which satisfy the differential equations in the dymamic system (15), if we interpret the derivatives appearing there as right-hand side derivatives. In other words, we rule out anticipated discrete jumps, or, what come to the same thing, anticipated shifts in the system s initial condition. There is a good economic reason for imposing this CONTINUITY CON- DITION. Suppose agents expect a discrete jump in the exchange rate at some point in the future. Then they also must expect that the interest-parity condition will be violated, for the jump in e will cause an instantaneously infinite capital gain or loss. Thus, the instant before the jump is expected to occur, agents will have an incentive to bring about a sharp change in e. But this would violate the assumption of perfect foresight.(for an reference example of this, see the Krugman model of balance-sheet financial 21

22 crises). It follows that we can rule out paths of the discontinuous type on economic grounds. When a disturbance occurs, asset-holders will bid the exchange-rate to a level such that no further jumps occur; and in this way they will ensure that foreign exchange holdings earn exactly the equilibrium rate of return, r, at every point of the economy s anticipated subsequent path ANTICIPATORY DYNAMICS Permanent not foreseen change in m Suppose now that an exogenous increase in the nominal supply of money m were to occur at time t 1.Before the instant t 1, the economy is stuck in its initial long run equilibrium, point 1, and the relevant isoclines are labelled with subscript 1. The exogenous increase in the nominal supply of money m makes the isoclines e to shift up to the upper path, labelled with subscript 2, while the path of p would remain unaffected. As a result, p and ē rise by the same amount, which is clear because the slope of the p isocline is unity. We know that the economy must end in the long run equilibrium point 2, but it cannot jump to the new steady state instantly, however, because domestic price, p, changes sluggishly. On the other hand, e can adjust instantly. Given the strong assumption of perfect foresight on the part of economic agents in the model, the exchange rate will jump to the point e 2, to reach the new saddle path. (consider how only this jump is consistent with the economy reaching the new long-run equilibrium at the new steady state). From that point, as shown in Figure 4, the economy follows the new saddle path toward the new steady state 2. Even from this simple dynamic exercise, we see how in this model the short-run increase in the exchange rate therefore overshoots the long run increase, by changing more than proportionately to the money stock, and this 22

23 is the reason why we speak about an overshooting exchange rate Permanent and foreseen change in m Let now the economy be in its long-run equilibrium at t 0, when the central bank announces that at time t0 (> t 0 ) in the future, the money supply will be increased from m to m 0 = m+ m. What happens? We have two clues. First, since p is a predetermined variable, we know that p cannot change from its original path p(0) = p = m when the announcement is made. Second, we know from the continuity condition that when m is actually increased, the exchange rate cannot be expected to take a discrete jump (such a jump would be arbitraged away the moment it was foreseen). Figure 5 shows the path of the economy consistent with these two requirements. Initially, e depreciates to e0, withp remaining at p = m = p(0).the economy must then move along one of its unstable paths, for the money supply has yet to increase and so (14) still describes the motion of p and e over 23

24 time. Speculators choose e 0 so that at time t 0,whenm increases, (p(t 0 ),e(t 0 )) lies on the stable arm or saddlepath of the dynamic system associated with money stock m + m. They thus prevent a foreseen jump in the exchange rate that might have otherwise been necessary to place the economy on the new saddlepath at t 0. After t 0, the economy travels toward the stationary state ( p 1, ē 1 ). We now turn to the derivation of an analytical representation of the implied path. Our task is to determine two sets of initial conditions (k 1,k 2 ), and (k 1,1,k 1,2 ). The first set is associated with the economy s path between t =0andt = t 0 ; the second gives its path between t = t0 and t =. For clarity s reasons, we label (k 1,1,k 1,2 )as(k0 1,k0 2 ) From the assumption of price stickiness, (15) tells us that p(0) p =0=k 1 λμ 1 + k 2 λμ 2 24

25 (16), and this is our first constraint on λ 1 and k 2. The saddlepath of the system associated with the higher money stock m + m is described by the equation p(t) p0 = λμ 2 (e(t) ē0), or, (4), p(t) p = λμ 2 (e(t) ē)+(1 λμ 2 ) m (17) The unstable path chosen by the economy for the period between t =0 and t = t 0 must, by the continuity condition, be such that (p(t 0 ),e(t 0 )) lies on the locus given by (17). The price level and exchange rate at time t are p(t 0 ) p = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) e(t 0 ) ē = k 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )k 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) where we have used (15) and (16), and substituting into (17) yields: or k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 )=k 1 λμ 2 exp(μ 1 t 0 )+(1 λμ 2 ) m k 1 = m(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )/λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) (18) k 2 = (μ 1 /μ 2 ) m(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )/λ(μ 1 μ 2 ). The initial conditions imposed on k 1 and k 2 determine the economy s path between the time of the announcement and the time of the monetary expansion. The initial conditions are associated with the economy s path after m rises, since the economy must now be on the saddlepath. We must have k 1 =0, so that at t = t 0 : e(t 0 ) ē 0 = k 0 2 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) (19) But from (18a, b), we have seen that e(t 0 ) ē 0 = e(t 0 ) ē m (20) = m(1 λμ 2) λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [1 (μ 1/μ 2 )exp((μ 1 μ 2 )t 0 )] m 25

26 and this, together with (19), implies k 0 2 = m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [(1 λμ 1)exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 ) To summarize, the path of the economy is given by: p(t) = p + μ 1 m(1 λμ 2 ) (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1 t 0 )[exp(μ 1 t) exp(μ 2 t)] (0 t t 0 ) p 0 + μ 2 m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t)[(1 λμ 1 )exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )] (t t 0 ) e(t) = ē 0 + ē + m(1 λμ 2 ) λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1 t 0 )[exp(μ 1 t) (μ 1 /μ 2 )exp(μ 2 t)] (0 t t 0 ) m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t)[(1 λμ 1 )exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )] (t t 0 ) These expressions are readily derived using (15) and the initial conditions we have calculated. Some implications of these results are now briefly explored. Setting t = 0, we can examine the jump taken by the exchange rate when the announcement occurs. The spot depreciation is just e(0) ē = m(1 1/λμ 2 )exp( m 1 t 0 ) which implies that as t 0, e(0) ē. The farther in the future is the policy action, the smaller is the impact on today s exchange rate. When t 0 =0,wehavetheeffect of an unanticipated change in m, and see immediately that since μ 2 < 0,theexchangerateovershootē0. What is the value of the exchange rate when the increase in money takes place? at t = t 0,wehave 26

27 e(t 0 ) ē 0 = m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [(1 λμ 1) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp((μ 1 μ 2 )t)] and since λμ 1 < 1,theexchangeratemustbeaboveitslong-runlevel, m actually rises. An interesting point to note is that lim t e(t0 ) ē 0 = m (1 λμ 1 ) /λ(μ 1 /μ 2 ) > 0 Even when the disturbance is anticipated infinitely far in advance, economy will have not adjusted completely when it occurs. This is a peculiarity of the Dornbusch model, due to the fact that the price adjustment rule does not look forward into time (as would, say, a Phillips curve augmented by inflationary expectations), but instead reflects only current excess demand. 4. An alternative approach An alternative approach to solving the problem of the previous section serves as a check on the solution we have derived. The alternative approach has the advantage that it makes explicit the role of expectations regarding the future level of the money supply. In addition, it shows how we can still interpret continuity condition as a once-for-all choice of initial condition. To implement this second method, we write the path of the money stock anticipated after the announcement is made as m(t) = m (0 <t<t 0 ) (21) m(t) = m + m (t t 0 ) (22) Our system of equations is now non-autnomous, given by ṗ = δ(e p) ė = (1/λ)p [1/λm(t)] 27

28 The inverse of the matrix of eigenvectors of the system s homogeneous part is easily calculated to be p 1 = 1 1 λμ2 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) 1 λμ 1 and so we may write the system in the diagonal form as μ 2 u = μ 1 u + λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) m(t) μ v = μ 2 v 1 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) m(t) where [u v] 0 = p 1 [pe] 0.The solution of this system is of general form u(t) = k 1 exp(μ 1 t) v(t) = k 2 exp(μ 2 t) μ 2 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) μ 1 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) Z t Z t exp(μ 1 (t s))m(s)ds exp(μ 2 (t s))m(s)ds Multiplying by P and so changing back to the original coordinates p and e yields Z p(t) = λμ 1 k 1 exp(μ 1 t)+λμ 2 k 2 exp(μ 2 t) μ 1μ 2 exp(μ (μ 1 μ 2 ) 1 (t s)) t μ Z t 1μ 2 exp(μ (μ 1 μ 2 ) 2 (t s)m(s)ds Z μ e(t) = k 1 exp(μ 1 t)+λexp(μ 2 t) 2 exp(μ λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) 1 (t s)m(s)ds μ 1 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) Z t exp(μ 2 (t s)m(s)ds t We may use this general solution to calculate the path of the economy in the wake of the announcement of monetary expansion at time t. But first we need to determine the initial conditions k 1 and k 2.Asusual,weset 28

29 k 1 = 0: this places the economy on a generalized saddle path having the property that(p(t),e(t)) will approach a steady state when m(t)converges to a constant value t.thisleavesk 2 to be determined, and we do so by recalling that, by price-level stickiness,p(0) = p = m. Now, for 0 >t>t 0 : = Z t Z t Z t exp((μ 1 (t s))m(s)ds + exp((μ 1 (t s))mds + Z = m/μ 1 m/μ 2 +exp(μ 1 (t t )) m/μ 1 t exp(μ 2 (t s))m(s)ds exp((μ 1 (t s)) mds + Z t exp(μ 2 (t s))mds (7). For t t 0 Z t Z t + Z t exp((μ 1 (t s))m(s)ds + exp(μ 2 (t s))mds + Z t t exp(μ 2 (t s))m(s)ds(t s))(m + m)ds exp(μ 2 (t s))mds = (m + m)μ 1 m/μ 2 [1 exp(μ 2 (t t )) m/μ 2 (8). Thus, at time t =0,wehave: m = λμ 2 k 2 μ 1μ 2 (μ 1 μ 2 ) [m/μ 1 m/μ 2 +exp( μ 1 t )) m/μ 1 ] = λμ 2 k 2 + m μ 2 m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1t ) With this second initial condition on hand, we may solve for the path; we start with the price level.. When 0 >t>t, we find, using (7), that: 29

30 p(t) = λμ 2 m exp(μ 2 t μ 1 t ) μ 1μ 2 λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) (μ 1 μ 2 ) [m/μ 1 m/μ 2 +exp(t t )) m = p + μ 2 m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1t )[exp(μ 2 t) exp(μ 1 t)] (for p <m). Now we know that μ 1 μ 2 = δλ and μ 1 + μ 2 = δ. Soμ 2 = μ 2 + δ δ = μ 1 + λμ 1 μ 2 = μ 1 (1 λμ 2 ),andwemaywritetheaboveas: p(t) = p + μ 1 m(1 λμ 2 ) (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1 t )[exp(μ 1 t) exp(μ 2 t)] This is the expression given on page 6. When t t 0,(8)implies p(t) = λμ 2 m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t μ 1 t 0 ) μ 1μ 2 (m + m)/μ1 (m + m)μ (μ 1 μ 2 ) 2 +exp(μ 2 (t t 0 )) m/μ 2 and, since p0 = m + m, p(t) = p 0 + m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t) μ 2 exp( μ 1 t) μ 1 exp( μ 2 t 0 ) But μ 2 = μ 1 (1 λμ 2 )= μ 2 (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )and μ 1 = μ 2 + δ = μ 2 λμ 1 μ 2 = μ 2 (1 λμ 1 ), and so p(t) = p 0 + μ 2 m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t) (1 λμ 1 )exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 ) Again, this is identical to the path previously calculated. The path of the exchange rate is derived in similar fashion, and can be shown, using the above relations, to be identical to the path derived using the method of the previous section. This is left as an exercise. 30

31 Where have we imposed the continuity condition? We have implicitly done so by imposing, once and for all, an initial condition: for once this is done the solution of a non-autonomous is continuous. REFERENCES. Birkoff, G. andg.-c. Rota. Ordinary Differential Equations. Lexington: Xerox College Publishing,1969 Blanchard, O.J., Backward and Forward Solutions for Economies with Rational Expectations. American Economic Review 69 (May 1979): Hirsh, M.W., and S. Smale. Differential Equations, Dynamical Systems and Linear Algebra. NewYork:AcademicPress;1974 Hoy, M., Livernois, J., McKenna, C., Rees, R., Stengos, T., Mathematics for Economies, TheMITPress,2001 Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., Foundation of International Macroeconomics, The MIT Press, Sargent, T.J. Macroeconomic Theory. NewYork: AcademicPress, 1979 Calvo, G. The Stability of Models of Money and Perfect Foresight: A Comment. Econometrica 45 (Oct. 1977): Rogoff, Essays on Expectations and Exchange-Rate Volatility. Doctoral dissertation, MIT, ( ) ANALYTICAL DERIVATION MUNDELL-FLEMING-DORNBUSCH MODEL The model is described by m p = λr + ψy r = r + ė ṗ = δ(e p) provided that for simplicity reason we have set y = r = 0 we can rewrite m p = λr r = ė ṗ = δ(e p) In order to get the system of differential equations we isolate 31

32 ṗ ė = δ δ (p p) 1 λ 0 (e ē) Let s now denote μ 1 > 0 >μ 2 the eigenvalues of the matrix: the associated eigenvectors have form [λμ 1 1] 0 [λμ 2 1] 0 The general solution, as previous shown in sect. 1.2, is x(t) = [k 1 b/ (λ 1 a)] exp (λ 1 t)+[k 2 b/ (λ 2 a)] exp (λ 2 t) y(t) = k 1 exp (λ 1 t)+k 2 exp (λ 2 t) that in our case translates in p(t) p = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t)+k 2 λμ 2 exp(μ 2 t) e(t) ē = k 1 exp(μ 1 t)+k 2 exp(μ 2 t) Recalling that, for the assumption of price stickiness, at the time t = t 0 of the announcement we have p(0) p = 0 = k 1 λμ 1 + k 2 λμ 2 k 1 λμ 1 = (k 2 λμ 2 ) which represents the first constraint on λ and k 2. We are now ready to derive the saddlepath of the system associated with the higher money stock m + m p(t) p 0 e(t) ē 0 = k 1λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t) k 2 λμ 2 exp(μ 2 t) k 1 exp(μ 1 t) k 2 exp(μ 2 t) (k 1 =0) 32

33 which simplifies in p(t) p 0 = λμ 2 e(t) ē 0 p(t) p m = λμ 2 (e(t) ē) λμ 2 m p(t) p = λμ 2 (e(t) ē)+(1 λμ 2 ) m So that our saddle path is p(t) p = λμ 2 (e(t) ē)+(1 λμ 2 ) m t > t0 Consider now the t between the initial and the final equilibrium, t 0 < t<t 0. In that period, the economy follows an unstable path, which is required to bring, at t = t0, the economy in (p(t 0 ),e(t 0 )), along the higher saddle path, allowing the economy to converge to its new long run equilibrium. At the announcement, this equality must hold: and substituting it in k 1 λμ 1 = (k 2 λμ 2 ) μ k 2 = k 1 1 μ 2 we have p(t 0 ) p = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t) k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 2 t) e(t 0 ) ē = k 1 exp(μ 1 t) k 2 exp(μ 2 t) p(t 0 ) p = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) e(t 0 ) ē = k 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )k 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) that denotes the price level and the exchange rate at time t0. Now, if we substitute these values in the equation for the higher saddlepath, we will get the initial conditions to be imposed on k 1 and k 2,to determine the economy s path between the time of the announcement and the time of monetary expansion: p(t) p 0 = λμ 2 (e(t) ē 0 ) 33

34 p(t) p 0 = k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) = λμ 2 e(t) ē 0 +(1 λμ 2 ) m λμ 2 k1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )k 1 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) +(1 λμ 2 ) m k 1 λμ 1 exp(μ 1 t 0 ) = k 1 λμ 2 exp(μ 1 t 0 )+(1 λμ 2 ) m and, isolating k 1 and k 2, k 1 = m(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )/λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) k 2 = (μ 1 /μ 2 ) m(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )/λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) To derive now the saddle path after the m rise, we can recall that k 0 1 =0 (we are on a saddle path), and thus: e(t 0 ) ē 0 = k1(= 0 0) exp(μ 1 t 0 )+k2 0 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) e(t 0 ) ē 0 = k2 0 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) = e(t 0 ) ē m = m(1 λμ 2) λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [1 (μ 1/μ 2 )exp((μ 1 μ 2 )t 0 )] m and setting e(t 0 ) ē 0 m = k2 0 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) m(1 λμ 2 ) λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [1 (μ 1/μ 2 )exp((μ 1 μ 2 )t 0 )] m = k2 0 exp(μ 2 t 0 ) we have k 0 2 = m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) [(1 λμ 2)exp( μ 2 t 0 ) μ 1 μ 2 (1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )] Summarizing, and substituting the k 1,2 that we have found, the path of the economy is described by p(t) = p + μ 1 m(1 λμ 2 ) (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp( μ 1 t 0 )[exp(μ 1 t) exp(μ 2 t)] (t 0 t t 0 ) p 0 + μ 2 m (μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t)[(1 λμ 1 )exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )] (t t 0 ) 34

35 e(t) = ē + m(1 λμ 2 ) λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) ē 0 + exp( μ 1 t 0 )[exp(μ 1 t) (μ 1 /μ 2 )exp(μ 2 t)] (t 0 t t 0 ) m λ(μ 1 μ 2 ) exp(μ 2t)[(1 λμ 1 )exp( μ 2 t 0 ) (μ 1 /μ 2 )(1 λμ 2 )exp( μ 1 t 0 )] (t t 0 ) 35

International Macro Finance

International Macro Finance International Macro Finance Economies as Dynamic Systems Francesco Franco Nova SBE February 21, 2013 Francesco Franco International Macro Finance 1/39 Flashback Mundell-Fleming MF on the whiteboard Francesco

More information

The Dornbusch overshooting model

The Dornbusch overshooting model 4330 Lecture 8 Ragnar Nymoen 12 March 2012 References I Lecture 7: Portfolio model of the FEX market extended by money. Important concepts: monetary policy regimes degree of sterilization Monetary model

More information

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Topic 5: The Difference Equation Topic 5: The Difference Equation Yulei Luo Economics, HKU October 30, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME October 30, 2017 1 / 42 Discrete-time, Differences, and Difference Equations When time is taken to

More information

EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics. Prof. Jianjun Miao

EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics. Prof. Jianjun Miao EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics Prof. Jianjun Miao 1 Deterministic Dynamic System State vector x t 2 R n State transition function x t = g x 0 ; t; ; x 0 = x 0 ; parameter 2 R p A parametrized dynamic

More information

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003 Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics Problem Set 3 May 15, 2003 Due: Thu, June 5, 2003 Instructor: Marc-Andreas Muendler E-mail: muendler@ucsd.edu 1 Trending Fundamentals in a Target

More information

Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate

Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate Open Economy Macroeconomics, Fall 2006 Ida Wolden Bache October 24, 2006 Macroeconomic models of exchange rate determination Useful reference: Chapter

More information

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Dynamical Systems. August 13, 2013

Dynamical Systems. August 13, 2013 Dynamical Systems Joshua Wilde, revised by Isabel Tecu, Takeshi Suzuki and María José Boccardi August 13, 2013 Dynamical Systems are systems, described by one or more equations, that evolve over time.

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

B. Differential Equations A differential equation is an equation of the form

B. Differential Equations A differential equation is an equation of the form B Differential Equations A differential equation is an equation of the form ( n) F[ t; x(, xʹ (, x ʹ ʹ (, x ( ; α] = 0 dx d x ( n) d x where x ʹ ( =, x ʹ ʹ ( =,, x ( = n A differential equation describes

More information

An Alternative Method to Obtain the Blanchard and Kahn Solutions of Rational Expectations Models

An Alternative Method to Obtain the Blanchard and Kahn Solutions of Rational Expectations Models An Alternative Method to Obtain the Blanchard and Kahn Solutions of Rational Expectations Models Santiago Acosta Ormaechea Alejo Macaya August 8, 2007 Abstract In this paper we show that the method of

More information

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting The second section of Chapter 11 of Dornbusch (1980) draws on Dornbusch (1976) Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Slides to Lecture 3 of Introductory Dynamic Macroeconomics. Linear Dynamic Models (Ch 2 of IDM)

Slides to Lecture 3 of Introductory Dynamic Macroeconomics. Linear Dynamic Models (Ch 2 of IDM) Partial recap of lecture 2 1. We used the ADL model to make precise the concept of dynamic multiplier. Slides to Lecture 3 of Introductory Dynamic Macroeconomics. Linear Dynamic Models (Ch 2 of IDM) Ragnar

More information

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction Masanori Yokoo Abstract In many standard undergraduate textbooks of macroeconomics, open economies are discussed by means of the Mundell Fleming model, an open macroeconomic version of the IS LM model.

More information

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016 Christian Groth A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics February 15, 216 (3-hours closed book exam) 1 As formulated in the course description, a score of 12 is

More information

SADDLEPOINT DYNAMICS WITH AN ENDOGENOUS ROOT CONVERGENCE. By Omar O. Chisari 1

SADDLEPOINT DYNAMICS WITH AN ENDOGENOUS ROOT CONVERGENCE. By Omar O. Chisari 1 1 August 1999 SADDLEPOINT DYNAMICS WITH AN ENDOGENOUS ROOT CONVERGENCE. OF By Omar O. Chisari 1 This paper reconsiders local stability in the saddlepoint sense. Market time and the root of convergence

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Chapter 4: Anticipation effects and economic policy BJ Heijdra Department of Economics, Econometrics & Finance University of Groningen 1 September 2009

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Solving a Non-Linear Model: The Importance of Model Specification for Deriving a Suitable Solution

Solving a Non-Linear Model: The Importance of Model Specification for Deriving a Suitable Solution Solving a Non-Linear Model: The Importance of Model Specification for Deriving a Suitable Solution Ric D. Herbert a and Peter J. Stemp b a School of Design, Communication and Information Technology, The

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-2010 Macroeconomics II Franck Portier Homework 1 Problem I An AD-AS Model Let us consider an economy with three agents (a firm, a household and a government) and four

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

We shall finally briefly discuss the generalization of the solution methods to a system of n first order differential equations.

We shall finally briefly discuss the generalization of the solution methods to a system of n first order differential equations. George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Mathematical Annex 1 Ordinary Differential Equations In this mathematical annex, we define and analyze the solution of first and second order linear

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Lecture 3: A dynamic IS-LM model

Lecture 3: A dynamic IS-LM model Lecture 3: A dynamic IS-LM model José L. Torres Universidad de Málaga Advanced Macroeconomics José L. Torres (Universidad de Málaga) Lecture 3: A dynamic IS-LM model Advanced Macroeconomics 1 / 26 Model

More information

7 Planar systems of linear ODE

7 Planar systems of linear ODE 7 Planar systems of linear ODE Here I restrict my attention to a very special class of autonomous ODE: linear ODE with constant coefficients This is arguably the only class of ODE for which explicit solution

More information

Examples include: (a) the Lorenz system for climate and weather modeling (b) the Hodgkin-Huxley system for neuron modeling

Examples include: (a) the Lorenz system for climate and weather modeling (b) the Hodgkin-Huxley system for neuron modeling 1 Introduction Many natural processes can be viewed as dynamical systems, where the system is represented by a set of state variables and its evolution governed by a set of differential equations. Examples

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD February 6, 2009 Karl Whelan (UCD) Models with Rational Expectations February 6, 2009 1 / 32 Moving

More information

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam Econ 50 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam Spring 202 Real Business Cycle Theory. Consider a simple neoclassical growth model (notation similar to class) where all agents are identical

More information

Math Ordinary Differential Equations

Math Ordinary Differential Equations Math 411 - Ordinary Differential Equations Review Notes - 1 1 - Basic Theory A first order ordinary differential equation has the form x = f(t, x) (11) Here x = dx/dt Given an initial data x(t 0 ) = x

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Title: Past trend versus future expectation: test of exchange rate volatility Author: Sengupta, Jati K., University of California, Santa Barbara Sfeir, Raymond,

More information

Copyright (c) 2006 Warren Weckesser

Copyright (c) 2006 Warren Weckesser 2.2. PLANAR LINEAR SYSTEMS 3 2.2. Planar Linear Systems We consider the linear system of two first order differential equations or equivalently, = ax + by (2.7) dy = cx + dy [ d x x = A x, where x =, and

More information

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model Monetary Policy in a Macro Model ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2017 1 / 67 Readings Mishkin Ch. 20 Mishkin Ch. 21 Mishkin Ch. 22 Mishkin Ch. 23, pg. 553-569

More information

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital Princeton University Press, 2017 Motivation In this chaper we introduce production and physical capital accumulation. Doing so will allow us to address two

More information

The construction and use of a phase diagram to investigate the properties of a dynamic system

The construction and use of a phase diagram to investigate the properties of a dynamic system File: Phase.doc/pdf The construction and use of a phase diagram to investigate the properties of a dynamic system 1. Introduction Many economic or biological-economic models can be represented as dynamic

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Math 312 Lecture Notes Linear Two-dimensional Systems of Differential Equations

Math 312 Lecture Notes Linear Two-dimensional Systems of Differential Equations Math 2 Lecture Notes Linear Two-dimensional Systems of Differential Equations Warren Weckesser Department of Mathematics Colgate University February 2005 In these notes, we consider the linear system of

More information

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM This is a 90-minute exam. Answer all three questions, each of which is worth 30 points. You can get partial credit for partial answers. Do not spend disproportionate

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

Linearization of Differential Equation Models

Linearization of Differential Equation Models Linearization of Differential Equation Models 1 Motivation We cannot solve most nonlinear models, so we often instead try to get an overall feel for the way the model behaves: we sometimes talk about looking

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) Models with Rational Expectations Spring 2016 1 / 36 Moving Beyond

More information

22.3. Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

22.3. Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices. Introduction In this Section we further develop the theory of eigenvalues and eigenvectors in two distinct directions. Firstly we look at matrices where one

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 1 General Assumptions Ignore variations in the capital stock There are differentiated goods with Calvo price stickiness Wages are not sticky Monetary policy is a choice

More information

Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors

Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors Contents Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors. Basic Concepts. Applications of Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors 8.3 Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices 3.4 Numerical Determination of Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors

More information

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture notes #12 : Solving Dynamic Rational Expectations Models

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture notes #12 : Solving Dynamic Rational Expectations Models 2012-2013 Master 2 Macro I Lecture notes #12 : Solving Dynamic Rational Expectations Models Franck Portier (based on Gilles Saint-Paul lecture notes) franck.portier@tse-fr.eu Toulouse School of Economics

More information

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Friday September 8 th : Lecture 10 Gerzensee, September 2017 Roger E. A. Farmer Warwick University and NIESR Topics for Lecture 10 Tying together the pieces

More information

Solutions to Dynamical Systems 2010 exam. Each question is worth 25 marks.

Solutions to Dynamical Systems 2010 exam. Each question is worth 25 marks. Solutions to Dynamical Systems exam Each question is worth marks [Unseen] Consider the following st order differential equation: dy dt Xy yy 4 a Find and classify all the fixed points of Hence draw the

More information

22.2. Applications of Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

22.2. Applications of Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes Applications of Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors 22.2 Introduction Many applications of matrices in both engineering and science utilize eigenvalues and, sometimes, eigenvectors. Control theory, vibration

More information

Based on the specification in Mansoorian and Mohsin(2006), the model in this

Based on the specification in Mansoorian and Mohsin(2006), the model in this Chapter 2 The Model Based on the specification in Mansoorian and Mohsin(2006), the model in this paper is composed of a small open economy with a single good. The foreign currency 立 政 治 price of the good

More information

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo October 20, 2008 1 Ch 17, 19 and 20 in IAM Since our primary concern is to

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-200 Macroeconomics II Franck ortier Homework Solutions max Π = A FOC: d = ( A roblem I An AD-AS Model ) / ) 2 Equilibrium on the labor market: d = s = A and = = A Figure

More information

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Beyond IS-LM We have reviewed the

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies Journal of Regional Development Studies2010 131 Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies Ken-ichi ISHIYAMA 1. Introduction We have observed large increases in trade and

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39: Equilibrium Indeterminacy under F Title Interest Rate Rules Author(s) NAKAGAWA, Ryuichi Citation Working Paper Series, F-39: 1-14 Issue Date 2009-06 URL http://hdl.handle.net/10112/2641 Rights Type Technical

More information

Old Math 330 Exams. David M. McClendon. Department of Mathematics Ferris State University

Old Math 330 Exams. David M. McClendon. Department of Mathematics Ferris State University Old Math 330 Exams David M. McClendon Department of Mathematics Ferris State University Last updated to include exams from Fall 07 Contents Contents General information about these exams 3 Exams from Fall

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 7 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600 DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 6 1. differential Equations 1 1.1. Basic Concepts for Univariate Equations. We use differential equations to model situations which treat time as a continuous

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Math 266: Phase Plane Portrait

Math 266: Phase Plane Portrait Math 266: Phase Plane Portrait Long Jin Purdue, Spring 2018 Review: Phase line for an autonomous equation For a single autonomous equation y = f (y) we used a phase line to illustrate the equilibrium solutions

More information

Systems of Linear ODEs

Systems of Linear ODEs P a g e 1 Systems of Linear ODEs Systems of ordinary differential equations can be solved in much the same way as discrete dynamical systems if the differential equations are linear. We will focus here

More information

A critique of the Granger representation theorem

A critique of the Granger representation theorem University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Commerce - Papers (Archive) Faculty of Business 007 A critique of the Granger representation theorem Edgar J. Wilson University of Wollongong, ewilson@uow.edu.au

More information

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

0. Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides Monetary Policy, 7/3 2018 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen "0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic

More information

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University Lecture 7 The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 2013 Phillips Department of Economics Lakehead University 7.1 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 Phillips Phillips 7.2 Market Equilibrium:

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model)

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model) The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model) Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 September 27, 2017 1 / 32 The Growth Model in Continuous Time We add optimizing households to the Solow model. We first study

More information

Taylor rules with delays in continuous time

Taylor rules with delays in continuous time Taylor rules with delays in continuous time ECON 101 (2008) Taylor rules with delays in continuous time 1 / 38 The model We follow the flexible price model introduced in Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Economies as ynamic Systems Francesco Franco Nova SBE February 11, 2014 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/18 First-order The variable z t follows a first-order di erence

More information

STABILITY. Phase portraits and local stability

STABILITY. Phase portraits and local stability MAS271 Methods for differential equations Dr. R. Jain STABILITY Phase portraits and local stability We are interested in system of ordinary differential equations of the form ẋ = f(x, y), ẏ = g(x, y),

More information

1 / 5. Stability of 2 2 Systems of Differential Equations April 2014

1 / 5. Stability of 2 2 Systems of Differential Equations April 2014 / 5 Stability of Systems of Differential Equations April 04 Alecos Papadopoulos Department of Economics Athens University of Economics and Business papadopalex@aueb.gr http://alecospapadopoulos.wordpress.com

More information

Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices

Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices Repeated Eigenvalues and Symmetric Matrices. Introduction In this Section we further develop the theory of eigenvalues and eigenvectors in two distinct directions. Firstly we look at matrices where one

More information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Eric R. Sims University of Notre Dame and NBER January 17, 2012 Abstract In a standard New Keynesian model, a Taylor-type interest rate rule moves the equilibrium real

More information

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy George W. Evans (Univ. of Oregon and Univ. of St. Andrews) Lecture 4 Liquidity traps, learning and stagnation Evans, Guse & Honkapohja (EER, 2008), Evans

More information

ES10006: Core skills for economists: Mathematics 2

ES10006: Core skills for economists: Mathematics 2 ES10006: Core skills for economists: Mathematics 2 Seminar 6 Problem set no. 4: Questions 1c, 1d, 2, 4, 7, 8b First-order linear differential equations From Chiang and Wainwright (2005, Section 15.1),

More information

Some Notes on Linear Algebra

Some Notes on Linear Algebra Some Notes on Linear Algebra prepared for a first course in differential equations Thomas L Scofield Department of Mathematics and Statistics Calvin College 1998 1 The purpose of these notes is to present

More information

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Background Much progress made on constructing and estimating models that fit quarterly data well (Smets-Wouters,

More information

ENGI 9420 Lecture Notes 4 - Stability Analysis Page Stability Analysis for Non-linear Ordinary Differential Equations

ENGI 9420 Lecture Notes 4 - Stability Analysis Page Stability Analysis for Non-linear Ordinary Differential Equations ENGI 940 Lecture Notes 4 - Stability Analysis Page 4.01 4. Stability Analysis for Non-linear Ordinary Differential Equations A pair of simultaneous first order homogeneous linear ordinary differential

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

Beiträge zur angewandten Wirtschaftsforschung

Beiträge zur angewandten Wirtschaftsforschung Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre und Statistik No. 68- Stable Solutions to Homogeneous Difference- Differential Equations with Constant Coefficients Manfred Krtscha and Ulf von Kalckreuth Beiträge zur

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Fundamentals of Dynamical Systems / Discrete-Time Models. Dr. Dylan McNamara people.uncw.edu/ mcnamarad

Fundamentals of Dynamical Systems / Discrete-Time Models. Dr. Dylan McNamara people.uncw.edu/ mcnamarad Fundamentals of Dynamical Systems / Discrete-Time Models Dr. Dylan McNamara people.uncw.edu/ mcnamarad Dynamical systems theory Considers how systems autonomously change along time Ranges from Newtonian

More information

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 702/312 Spring 2016 An Example Now work out a parametric example, using standard functional forms. Cobb-Douglas

More information

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach origin of Keynesian approach to Growth can be traced back to an article written after the General Theory (1936) Roy Harrod, An Essay in Dynamic Theory, Economic Journal, 1939 Theoretical premises of the

More information

Damped harmonic motion

Damped harmonic motion Damped harmonic motion March 3, 016 Harmonic motion is studied in the presence of a damping force proportional to the velocity. The complex method is introduced, and the different cases of under-damping,

More information

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction The New Keynesian Model: Introduction Vivaldo M. Mendes ISCTE Lisbon University Institute 13 November 2017 (Vivaldo M. Mendes) The New Keynesian Model: Introduction 13 November 2013 1 / 39 Summary 1 What

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

1 Differential Equations

1 Differential Equations Reading [Simon], Chapter 24, p. 633-657. 1 Differential Equations 1.1 Definition and Examples A differential equation is an equation involving an unknown function (say y = y(t)) and one or more of its

More information

Department of Mathematics IIT Guwahati

Department of Mathematics IIT Guwahati Stability of Linear Systems in R 2 Department of Mathematics IIT Guwahati A system of first order differential equations is called autonomous if the system can be written in the form dx 1 dt = g 1(x 1,

More information

Module 6 : Solving Ordinary Differential Equations - Initial Value Problems (ODE-IVPs) Section 3 : Analytical Solutions of Linear ODE-IVPs

Module 6 : Solving Ordinary Differential Equations - Initial Value Problems (ODE-IVPs) Section 3 : Analytical Solutions of Linear ODE-IVPs Module 6 : Solving Ordinary Differential Equations - Initial Value Problems (ODE-IVPs) Section 3 : Analytical Solutions of Linear ODE-IVPs 3 Analytical Solutions of Linear ODE-IVPs Before developing numerical

More information

Linear Models with Rational Expectations

Linear Models with Rational Expectations Linear Models with Rational Expectations Vivaldo Mendes Dep. of Economics Instituto Universitário de Lisboa October 2017 (Vivaldo Mendes ISCTE-IUL ) Master in Economics October 2017 1 / 59 Summary 1 From

More information