Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models"

Transcription

1 Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models By Tue Gørgens Chirok Han Sen Xue ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 635 May 2016 JEL: C230 ISBN:

2 Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models Tue Gørgens Chirok Han Sen Xue Abstract: This paper establishes asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator of the autoregressive parameter in simple linear dynamic panel data models with fixed effects under standard minimal assumptions. The number of time periods is assumed to be small. Focusing on settings where autoregressive parameter is uniquely identified, nonstandard convergence rates and limiting distributions arise in the well-known random walk case, as well as in other previously unrecognized cases. The paper finds that the convergence rates are slow in the nonstandard cases, and the limiting distributions are a mixture of two nonnormal distributions. The findings are illustrated using Monte Carlo simulations. Keywords: Dynamic panel data models, fixed effects, generalized method of moments, nonstandard limiting distributions. JEL classification codes: C230. Acknowledgment: This research was supported in part by a grant from the Korean Government (NRF-2014S1A2A ). The Australian National University. tue.gorgens@anu.edu.au. Korea University. chirokhan@korea.ac.kr. The Australian National University. sen.xue@anu.edu.au.

3 1 1 Introduction In this paper we establish the asymptotic distributions of the GMM estimator of the autoregressive parameter in simple linear AR(1) dynamic panel data models with fixed effects. We consider the case where the number of individuals is large and the number of time periods is small. We impose only the standard minimal assumptions that the idiosyncratic errors are serially uncorrelated and uncorrelated with the initial data values and with the fixed effects. The assumptions imply a number of linear and quadratic moment restrictions on the first and second moments of the data, which can be used to identify and estimate the autoregressive parameter. We focus on the GMM estimator that is based on all moment restrictions available under the standard minimal assumptions. We refer to this as the quadratic GMM estimator. We establish the rates of convergence and the asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator under general conditions. In many cases, standard regularity conditions are satisfied and standard root-n convergence and asymptotic normality prevail. However, we show that nonstandard asymptotic results arise when the linear moment restrictions alone do not identify the autoregressive parameter and the quadratic moment restrictions have a double root. Most notably, this can happen in the well-known random walk case where the autoregressive parameter is 1 and there are no fixed effects (i.e. the time series for each individual is a random walk), provided the variances of the idiosyncratic errors are constant over time. We find that the asymptotic distribution is very unusual in the nonstandard cases, in that it consists of two parts depending on the sign of a particular statistic. If the statistic is negative, the rate of convergence is n 1/2 and the limiting distribution is highly skewed. If the statistic is positive, the rate of convergence is n 1/4, which is very slow, and simulation results indicate that the limiting distribution is bimodal. The quadratic GMM estimator is important because it is efficient under the standard minimal assumptions, provided an optimal weight matrix is used. The quadratic GMM estimator can be contrasted with the inefficient difference GMM estimator, which is based on linear moment restrictions only (e.g. Holtz-Eakin, Newey, and Rosen, 1988; Arellano and Bond, 1991). The system GMM estimator is generally not valid under the standard

4 2 minimal assumptions, but requires an additional stationarity assumption (e.g. Arellano and Bover, 1995; Ahn and Schmidt, 1995; Blundell and Bond, 1998). The stationarity assumption may not be appropriate in all empirical applications (e.g. Hayakawa, 2009; Calzolari and Magazzini, 2013). The random walk case has attracted considerable interest in the literature, because data often exhibit substantial persistence and asymptotic distributions typically provide poor approximations to the finite-sample distributions in these situations (e.g. Blundell and Bond, 1998). For example, Bond and Windmeijer (2005) studied the Wald test when the datagenerating process is near the random walk. Kruiniger (2009) and Bun and Kleibergen (2013) derived local asymptotic approximations to the finite-sample distributions of certain well-known linear GMM estimators when the data are close to the random walk case. These studies maintain the stationarity assumption. The present paper contributes to this literature by establishing the asymptotic distribution of the (nonlinear) quadratic GMM estimator, by showing that there are more nonstandard cases than the random walk, and by avoiding the stationarity assumption. Our results also show that standard asymptotic results are usually applicable in the random walk case if the idiosyncratic errors are heteroskedastic. Hence, the quadratic GMM estimator can be a solution to the identification and weak IV problems associated with other estimators when the autoregressive parameter is 1 or close to 1. Throughout this paper, we focus on cases where the autoregressive parameter is uniquely identified. In other recent work, we showed that the identification of the autoregressive parameter cannot be taken for granted, even when it is assumed to be less than 1 (Gørgens, Han, and Xue, 2016). In particular, we showed that there are three possibilities when the linear moment restrictions do not provide identification. Either the quadratic moment restrictions uniquely identify the autoregressive parameter, or they partially identify it, or it is fully unidentified. The latter occurs if and only if there is no individual time variation in the data for t = 0,..., T 2, and is not of much practical interest. Partial identification comes in the form of precisely two candidate values, one of which is the true value. This paper focuses on the case where the autoregressive parameter is uniquely identified, and we defer

5 3 distributional issues related to partial identification to future research. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model and defines the quadratic GMM estimator. Section 3 establishes consistency and limiting distributions. Section 4 presents simulations illustrating the nonstandard results, and Section 5 concludes. Appendix A contains proofs of theorems. 2 The model and the quadratic GMM estimator Suppose we have two-dimensional panel data. Following common practice, we shall refer to the first dimension as individuals and the second as time periods. For i = 1,..., n individuals and t = 0,..., T times, let y it be scalar random variables which are observed and available for analysis. 1 Note that y i0 is observed. Assumption 1 The random variables {(y i0,..., y it ) : i = 1,..., n} are independent across individuals, have finite means, and satisfy y it = y it 1 α 0 + c i + v it, t = 1,..., T, (1) with E(v it ) = 0 for t = 1,..., T. In Assumption 1, α 0 is an unknown (true) parameter to be estimated, and the sum c i +v it is an unobserved term decomposed into an individual-specific random variable, c i, which is constant over time, and an individual- and time-specific term, v it. The model does not have an explicit constant term; this is subsumed into c i. The parameter of interest is α 0. Assumption 1 postulates that the joint distribution of the observed variables derives from the joint distribution of y i0, c i, and v i1,..., v it. Restrictions on the latter are needed to identify α 0, and the standard set are stated as Assumption 2 (Ahn and Schmidt, 1995). 1 For simplicity, the expression i = 1,..., n is suppressed in the remainder of this paper.

6 4 Assumption 2 The random variables in Assumption 1 have finite variances and satisfy E(v it y i0 ) = 0, t = 1,..., T; (2) E(v it c i ) = 0, t = 1,..., T; (3) E(v is v it ) = 0, s = 1,..., t 1, t = 2,..., T. (4) The restrictions imposed by Assumptions 1 and 2 can be utilized to estimate α 0. The first moment restrictions (Han and Kim, 2014; Gørgens, Han, and Xue, 2016) are E( y it y it 1 α) = 0, t = 2,..., T. (5) The linear AB moment restrictions (Holtz-Eakin, Newey, and Rosen, 1988; Arellano and Bond, 1991) are E(y is ( y it y it 1 α)) = 0, s = 0,..., t 2, t = 2,..., T. (6) The quadratic AS moment restrictions (Ahn and Schmidt, 1995) are E((y it y it 1 α)( y it y it 1 α)) = 0, t = 2,..., T 1. (7) There are many other valid moment restrictions, but Ahn and Schmidt (1995) showed that under Assumption 2 they cannot contribute to identification or efficiency over the set given above. We refer to the GMM estimator based on the complete set of moment restrictions as the quadratic GMM estimator. The empirical moment restrictions are defined by replacing expectations in (5), (6), and (7) with sample averages. To simplify the discussion, it is convenient to express the empirical moment restrictions in matrix form. Define z it =

7 5 (1, y i0,..., y it ) and the vectors z i0 y i2. z it 2 y it h 0i =, h y it y 1i = i2. z i0 y i1. z it 2 y it 1 y it y i1 + y it 1 y i2., h 2i = 0. 0 y it 1 y i1.. (8) y it y it 1 y it y it 2 + y it 1 y it 1 y it 1 y it 2 Define the moment function, m, by m(z it, α) = h 2i α 2 h 1i α + h 0i. Define g n by n g n (α) = n 1 m(z it, α). (9) i=1 Then the empirical moment restrictions can be written as g n (α) = 0. For a given weight matrix, W n, the GMM loss function, Q n, is defined by Q n (α) = g n (α) W n g n (α). (10) This is a quartic polynomial in α, which can have at most three distinct local extrema; namely, two local minima and one local maximum. The first-order condition for a minimum is DQ n (α) = 0, where 1 2 DQ n(α) = D α g n (α) W n g n (α). (11) There are either 1 or 3 real-valued solutions to the first-order condition. If there are 3 distinct real roots, one of them corresponds to a local maximum while the others correspond to local minima. In this case, the GMM loss function can be evaluated at the roots to identify the global minimum. We define the quadratic GMM estimator, α n, as the global minimizer of Q n. The quadratic GMM estimator is not unique since it depends on the weight matrix.

8 6 3 Asymptotic theory In this section, we focus on cases where α 0 is uniquely identified, and consider the asymptotic properties of the quadratic GMM estimator. When standard regularity conditions are satisfied, the global minimizer of Q n, i.e. α n, converges to the true value, α 0, and its limiting distribution is normal. However, the standard regularity conditions are not satisfied in all cases. In the following, references to results discussed by Newey and McFadden (1994) are prefixed by NM. Define the nonstochastic function g by g(α) = E(m(z it, α)) = E(h 2i )α 2 E(h 1i )α + E(h 0i ). (12) Then α 0 is uniquely identified by the moment restrictions if and only if α 0 is the unique solution to g(α 0 ) = 0. While all elements of g may contribute to identification, there are cases where the elements corresponding to the linear moment restrictions are constant functions and identification stems entirely from the quadratic moment restrictions (Gørgens, Han, and Xue, 2016). In choosing a weight matrix it is therefore essential to ensure identification is preserved. Accordingly, let W be a nonstochastic positive semidefinite matrix such that W g(α) = 0 holds if and only if g(α) = 0. When α 0 is uniquely identified, we have the usual consistency result (NM-Theorem 2.6), stated here as Theorem 1 for convenience. Theorem 1 Suppose Assumptions 1 and 2 hold, W n p W, W is positive semidefinite and satisfies W g(α) = 0 if and only if g(α) = 0, and α 0 is a unique solution to g(α 0 ) = 0. If α 0 Θ where Θ is known and compact, then α n p α 0. Given consistency, the next question concerns the rate of convergence and the limiting distribution of the estimator, α n. If key regularity conditions are satisfied, then asymptotic normality and consistency of the estimator of the asymptotic variance may follow from standard theorems. However, it turns out that there are cases where standard asymptotics break down. In the remainder of this section, we treat first the standard, then the nonstandard

9 7 cases. If the right-hand sides are well defined, define the following nonstochastic matrices G = E(D α m(z it, α 0 )), (13) Ω = E(m(z it, α 0 )m(z it, α 0 ) ), (14) and V = (G W G) 1 G W ΩW G(G W G) 1. (15) Define also the sample analogues G n = n 1 Ω n = n 1 and n D α m(z it, α n ), (16) i=1 n m(z it, α n )m(z it, α n ), (17) i=1 V n = (G n W ng n ) 1 G n W nω n W n G n (G n W ng n ) 1. (18) Theorem 2 provides asymptotic normality and a consistent estimator of the asymptotic variance under standard regularity conditions. Theorem 2 Suppose the assumptions of Theorem 1 are satisfied. If α 0 is in the interior of Θ, and if G W G is nonsingular, then n 1/2 (α n α 0 ) N(0, V ). Suppose further that for a neighborhood of α 0 we have E(sup α m(z it, α) 2 ) <. Then V n p V. The proof of Theorem 2 is omitted, since the conclusions follow almost immediately from NM-Theorem 3.4 and NM-Theorem 4.5. The last part of Theorem 2 implies that the asymptotic variance of α n can be estimated by Avar(α n ) = n 1 V n. The complicated regularity condition essentially assumes finite and bounded fourth moments; this is used to ensure

10 8 consistency of Ω n. The critical regularity condition for ensuring standard asymptotic results is the nonsingularity of G W G. Since W is a positive semidefinite matrix which preserves identification, the singularity of G W G depends on whether or not G = 0. Recall that g(α) = E(h 2i )α 2 E(h 1i )α + E(h 0i ) and that G = 2E(h 2i )α 0 E(h 1i ). Each element of g(α) is a polynomial in α of degree at most 2, say p 2 α 2 + p 1 α + p 0. The corresponding element of G is 2p 2 α 0 + p 1. Since identification of α 0 means that g(α) = 0 if and only if α = α 0, the degree of the polynomial and the value of G is closely related to the identification. If the degree of a particular element of g is 0 (i.e. p 2 = 0, p 1 = 0, p 0 = 0), the corresponding element of G is 0. In this case, the corresponding moment restriction does not identify α 0. If the degree is 1 (i.e. p 2 = 0, p 1 0), the corresponding element of G is not 0. In this case, the corresponding (linear) moment restriction uniquely identifies α 0. If the degree is 2 (i.e. p 2 0), the corresponding element of G is 2p 2 α 0 + p 1. In this case, the corresponding (quadratic) moment restrictions uniquely or partially identifies α 0. In particular, it is not difficult to show that 2p 2 α 0 + p 1 = 0 if and only if the element of g(α) uniquely identifies α 0 and has a double root at α 0. To sum up, G = 0 if either α 0 is fully unidentified, or if the linear (first or AB) moment restrictions fail to identify α 0 but the quadratic AS moment restrictions provide unique identification in the form of a common double root. Two question arise. First, is the case where α 0 is uniquely identified but G = 0 compatible with data-generating processes given by Assumptions 1 and 2? That is, is it possible to observe such data? Second, what is the rate of convergence and the limiting distribution of the quadratic GMM estimator in such cases? In Theorem 3, we give an affirmative answer to the first question. Theorem 3 Suppose Assumptions 1 and 2 hold, and α 0 is uniquely identified. Then G 0 except the following situations: (i) T 3, α 0 = 1, E(c 2) = 0, and i E(v2 ) = it 1 E(v2 ) for all t = 2,..., T 1. it (ii) T = 3, ( 5 1)/2 α 0 < 1, (1 α 0 )E(y i0 ) = E(c i ), (1 α 0 )E(y 2 i0 ) = E(y i0c i ), E(v 2 i1 ) = α 0E(c i y i0 ) + α 0 (1 α 0 ) 1 E(c 2 i ), and E(v2 i2 ) = (α2 0 + α 0 1)α 1 0 E(v2 i1 ).

11 9 A proof is provided in Appendix A.1. Interestingly, Theorem 3 shows that heteroskedasticity is important for obtaining standard root-n asymptotic results in the well-known random walk case where α 0 = 1 and E(c 2 i ) = 0. The answer to the second question is provided in Theorem 4. Briefly, when G = 0 the GMM estimator converges at a slow O p (n 1/4 ) rate, and the asymptotic distribution is highly nonstandard. For convenience, define δ = α α 0 and δ n = α n α 0, and consider the reparameterized loss function g n (δ) W n g n (δ), where g n is defined by g n (δ) = g n (δ + α 0 ). Then g n (δ) W n g n (δ) is globally minimized at δ = δ n. To state the results some additional notation is needed. First, define h 0i = h 2i α 2 0 h 1iα 0 + h 0i, h 1i = 2h 2i α 0 + h 1i, and h 2i = h 2i. Then we have g n (δ) = n 1 n i=1 ( h 2i δ 2 h 1i δ+ h 0i ). Second, define H jn = n 1 n i=1 h ji for j = 0, 1, 2. Third, define A 0n = H 0n W nh 0n, A 1n = 2H 0n W nh 1n, A 2n = H 1n W nh 1n + 2H 0n W nh 2n, A 3n = 2H 1n W nh 2n, and A 4n = H 2n W nh 2n. Then we have g n (δ) W n g n (δ) = A 4n δ 4 + A 3n δ 3 + A 2n δ 2 + A 1n δ + A 0n. (19) Finally, define L n = A 3n 4A 4n, (20) and B 1n = 4A 4nL 3 n + 3A 3nL 2 n + 2A 2nL n + A 1n 4A 4n, (21) B 2n = 6A 4nL 2 n + 3A 3nL n + A 2n 2A 4n. (22) Let { } denote the indicator function. Then we have the following result. Theorem 4 Suppose the assumptions of Theorem 1 are satisfied. If α 0 is in the interior of Θ and if G = 0, then n 1/2 (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} (w L w 1 /w 2 ){w 2 0} and n 1/4 (α n α 0 ){B 2n > 0} sgn(w 1 )w 1/2 2 {w 2 > 0}, where (w L, w 1, w 2 ) is the weak limit of (n 1/2 L n, nb 1n, n 1/2 B 2n ). Also P(B 2n 0) 1/2.

12 10 Theorem 4 covers both exceptions given in Theorem 3; in particular, it provides the asymptotic distribution for the quadratic GMM estimator in the random walk case where α 0 = 1, c i = 0 for all i, and the variances of the idiosyncratic errors are constant over time. A proof of Theorem 4 can be found in Appendix A.2. The proof does not use the explicit formula for α n. Instead, it is based on first establishing the rate of convergence, and then establishing that a normalized version of the loss function weakly converges locally uniformly; the limiting distribution of the estimator is then the same as the limiting distribution of the (unique) minimizer of the normalized loss function. Theorem 4 shows that the asymptotic distribution in the nonstandard cases is a mixture of two nonnormal distributions. Different scale normalizations are needed depending on the sign of B 2n, and the overall rate of convergence is very slow. Moreover, working directly with the explicit formula for α n, it can be shown that the rate of convergence of the normalized estimator n 1/2 (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} to (w L w 1 /w 2 ){w 2 0} is also slow. That is, both the first-order and the higher-order approximation errors vanish only slowly as the sample size increases. Division by the mean-zero normal random variable w 2 in (w L w 1 /w 2 ){w 2 0} results in a limiting distribution with a very long and thick left tail. Since n 1/2 B 2n = O p (1), we may normalize by nb 2n instead of n 1/2. The asymptotic result is then nb 2n (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} (w L w 2 w 1 ){w 2 0}. This is likely to provide a better approximation, especially in the left tail of the distribution. In the next section we verify the theoretical results in a small simulation study. The slow rate of convergence in nonstandard cases means that only when enormous sample sizes are employed is there good agreement between the asymptotic and the finite-sample distributions. (This is also likely to be true for data-generating processes which are near a nonstandard case.) In sample sizes typically encountered in practice, the approximation appears to be poor.

13 11 4 Simulation evidence In this short section we present simulation evidence to confirm the theoretical results in three cases. 2 First we confirm the asymptotic distribution for the nonstandard random walk case. Specifically, for DGP1 we set T = 4, α 0 = 1, E(y 2 ) = 1, i0 E(c2) = 0, E(y i i0c i ) = 0, and E(v 2 ) = it 1 for t = 1,..., T. This design satisfies part (i) of Theorem 3. Figure 1 shows kernel density estimates for nb 2n (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0}. (The mass point at 0 is omitted.) Asymptotically, the density is unimodal and somewhat skewed to the right. Figure 2 shows the difference between the finite-sample and the limiting CDF, and confirms convergence in distribution. Figures 3 and 4 provide similar graphs for n 1/4 (α n α 0 ){B 2n > 0}. Asymptotically, the density is bimodal, with a large mode between 1 and 0 and a smaller model between 0 and 1. The difference between the finite-sample and the limiting CDFs obviously vanishes as the sample size increases, confirming convergence in distribution. Figures 2 and 4 show that the first-order asymptotic distributions provide poor approximations to the finite-sample distributions for DGP1. Indeed, enormous sample sizes are required for the finite-sample distributions to resemble the limiting distributions. Interestingly, the magnitude of the differences is similar, despite very different rates of convergence. This is further evidence that the order of the approximation errors are relatively higher than usual. DGP2 is chosen to illustrate that the nonstandard limiting theory applies in cases other than the random walk. Here we set T = 3, α 0 = 0.8, E(y 2 i0 ) = 1, E(c2 i ) = 1, E(y i0c i ) = 0.2, E(v 2 ) = 1.96, i1 E(v2 ) = 1.45, i2 E(v2 ) = 1, and i2 E(v2 ) = 1. This design satisfies part (ii) of i2 Theorem 3. Figures 5 and 6 show results for nb 2n (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0}, and Figures 7 and 8 show results for n 1/4 (α n α 0 ){B 2n > 0}. The patterns are similar to those for DGP1. The last experiment illustrates that standard asymptotics apply in the random walk case when the idiosyncratic errors are heteroskedastic. In DGP3, we set T = 4, α 0 = 1, E(y 2 i0 ) = 1, E(c 2) = 0, E(y i i0c i ) = 0, E(v 2 ) = 1, i1 E(v2 ) = 2, i2 E(v2 ) = 0.5, and i2 E(v2 ) = 1. Figure 9 i2 shows kernel density estimates of the finite-sample distributions of n 1/2 V 1/2 (α n α 0 ) as 2 The basic variables y i0, c i, and v i1,..., v it have mean 0 and are normally distributed in all experiments. All simulations have Monte Carlo replications and use the optimal weight matrix.

14 12 well as the theoretical N(0, 1) limiting distribution. The agreement is obvious, even for moderate sample sizes. Figure 10 shows the difference between the finite-sample CDF and the standard normal CDF, and the convergence is clear. 5 Concluding remarks The literature concerned with the linear AR(1) dynamic panel data model with fixed effects is large. Authors have considered different assumptions and different estimators. In this paper, we focused on the quadratic GMM estimator, which is based on all moment restrictions available under the standard minimal assumptions. If optimal weight matrices are used, the quadratic GMM estimator is more efficient than the popular difference GMM estimator, which is based on the linear moment restrictions only. We investigated the asymptotic properties of the quadratic GMM estimator, under the maintained assumption that the autoregressive parameter is uniquely identified. We characterized the data-generating processes for which standard asymptotic results are and are not applicable. The nonstandard cases include the well-known random walk case when the variances of the idiosyncratic errors are constant over time, as well as other cases that have not previously been discussed in the literature. We derived the limiting distribution for the nonstandard cases, and found that the rate of convergence is very slow and the limiting distribution is not normal. Finally, we verified the theoretical limiting distributions is a small set of Monte Carlo experiments. In other recent work, we investigated identification of the autoregressive parameter, both in terms of observed data and in terms of the underlying data-generating process (Gørgens, Han, and Xue, 2016). The autoregressive parameter is uniquely identified in most cases. It is fully unidentified only when there is no time variation in the data, which is not particularly interesting case from a practical point of view. However, there are also cases where the autoregressive parameter is partially identified. When it is partially identified, there are precisely two solutions to the moment restrictions. In the present paper, we have assumed the autoregressive parameter is known to be uniquely identified. If it is not possible to rule out partial identification a priori, then the analysis is more complicated. Intuitively,

15 13 in case of partial identification, both empirical roots converge to the respective population roots. However, it does not follow that the global minimizer converges to the true parameter value. Moreover, the finding of two roots in a particular empirical study does not necessarily indicate partial identification. We defer the question of inference in the presence of partial identification to future research. A Proofs A.1 Proof of Theorem 3 To prove Theorem 3, we need to describe data-generating processes for which the linear (first moment or AB) moment restrictions fail to identify α 0 but the quadratic AS moment restrictions provide unique identification in the form of a common double root. Identification of α 0 under Assumptions 1 and 2 was characterized by Gørgens, Han, and Xue (2016), and the proof here borrows heavily from the arguments in our earlier work. For convenience, define Ψ = (α 0 1)E(c i y i0 ) + E(c 2). i Case Ψ = 0 and E(v 2 ) = 0 for all t = 1,..., T 2 it In their Appendix A.3, Gørgens, Han, and Xue (2016) showed that when the linear AB moment restrictions do not identify α 0, then the quadratic AS moment restrictions for t = 1,..., T 2 are satisfied for any value of α, while the restriction for t = T 1 becomes a linear equation, α 0 E(v 2 ) it 1 E(v2 )α = 0. (23) it 1 It follows that the quadratic AS moment restrictions uniquely identify α 0 if and only if E(v 2 it 1 ) 0. Therefore, if α 0 is uniquely identified, then G is a vector of 0s except for the last element which is nonzero, so G W G is nonsingular.

16 14 Case Ψ = 0 and E(v 2 ) 0 for some t = 1,..., T 2 it In their Appendix A.3, Gørgens, Han, and Xue (2016) showed that the linear AB moment restrictions do not identify α 0 if and only if α 0 = 1 and E(c 2 ) = 0. Moreover, the quadratic i AS moment restrictions become E(v 2 it 1 )α2 + [E(v 2 ) + it 1 E(v2 )]α it E(v2 ) = 0, t = 2,..., T 1. (24) it At least one of these equation is of degree 2, because E(v 2 ) 0 for some t = 1,..., T 2. it If T = 3, then there are roots at α = 1 and α = E(v 2 i1 )/E(v2 ). Hence, there is a double i1 root (and G W G is singular) if and only if E(v 2 i2 ) = E(v2 i1 ). If T 4, then the equations have two common roots at α = 1 and α = λ if and only if E(v 2 ) = it λe(v2 ) for all t = 2,..., T 1. Hence, there is a double root if and only if it 1 E(v 2 it ) = E(v2 it 1 ) for all t = 2,..., T 1. That is, if α 0 is uniquely identified, then G W G is singular if and only if E(v 2 ) = it E(v2 ) for all t = 2,..., T 1. it 1 Case Ψ 0 In their Theorem 3 and Appendix A.3, Gørgens, Han, and Xue (2016) showed that the linear AB moment restrictions do not identify α 0 if and only if 0 α 0 < 1, (α 0 1)E(y 2 ) + i0 E(y i0 c i ) = 0, and E(v 2 ) = it αt (1 α 0 0) 1 Ψ for t = 1,..., T 2. Moreover, the quadratic AS moment restrictions can be written α t 1 0 (α t α t 2 0 )α + α t 2 0 α 2 = 0, t = 2,..., T 2, (25a) (α T α 0 Σ) (α T α T Σ)α + α T 3 0 α 2 = 0, (25b) where Σ = (1 α 0 )Ψ 1 E(v 2 it 1 ) αt 1 0 and where we use the convention 0 0 = 1. If T = 3, then (25a) is empty and (25b) has roots α = α 0 and α = (1 α 2 0 ) + E(v2 i2 )(1 α 0 )Ψ 1. Suppose 0 < α 0 < 1. Then E(v 2 ) 0. By definition of Ψ, (25b) has roots at i1 α = α 0 and α = (1 α 2) + α 0 0E(v 2 i2 )/E(v2 ). Hence there is a double root if and only if i1 E(v 2 i2 ) = (α2 0 + α 0 1)α 1 0 E(v2 i1 ). This equation has a solution for α 0 in [0, 1) when ( 5

17 15 1)/2 α 0 < 1. Suppose α 0 = 0. Then E(v 2 ) = 0. By definition of Ψ, (25b) has roots i1 at α = 0 and α = 1 + E(v 2 i2 )/(E(c2 i ) E(y i0c i )). Hence there is a double root if and only if E(v 2 i2 ) = (E(c2 i ) E(y i0c i )). The requirements Ψ 0 and E(v 2 i2 ) 0 imply E(y i0c i ) > E(c 2 i ). However, the first equation in the text above (25) implies E(y i0 c i ) = E(y 2 ), and then the i0 Cauchy-Schwarz inequality E(y i0 c i ) 2 E(y 2 i0 )E(c2) simplifies to E(y i i0c i ) E(c 2 ). Since the i two inequalities are incompatible, a double root is not possible, so G W G is nonsingular. If T 4, then (25a) and (25b) have two common roots if and only if Σ = 0. The roots are α = α 0 and α = 1. Since α 0 1, a double root is not possible, so G W G is nonsingular. A.2 Proof of Theorem 4 As mentioned, we work with reparameterized GMM loss function g n (δ) W n g n (δ), which is minimized at δ n = α n α 0 as noted before. Depress the cubic term by the further reparameterization from δ to γ where γ = δ L n, where L n = A 3n /(4A 4n ) is given in (20). Then g n (δ) W n g n (δ) = 4 A jn δ j = A 4n γ 4 + K 2n γ 2 + K 1n γ + K 0n, γ = δ L n, (26) j=0 where K 0n = A 4n L 4 n + A 3nL 3 n + A 2nL 2 n + A 1nL n + A 0n, (27) K 1n = 4A 4n L 3 n + 3A 3nL 2 n + 2A 2nL n + A 1n, (28) K 2n = 6A 4n L 2 n + 3A 3nL n + A 2n. (29) Dividing by 4A 4n and ignoring the constant term (which does not affect the minimization problem), we can write the objective function as Q n (γ) = 1 4 γ4 1 2 B 2nγ 2 B 1n γ, (30) where B 1n = K 1n /(4A 4n ) and B 2n = K 2n /(2A 4n ) are given in (21) and (22). This Q n is globally minimized at γ n where γ n = δ n L n = α n α 0 L n.

18 16 Before embarking on the main proof, we need some lemmas. The first two are used to sign and bound the global minimizer γ n of the depressed quartic polynomial Q n for given n. Lemma 1 characterizes the sign of γ n. Lemma 1 Consider equation (30). If B 1n = 0 and B 2n 0, then γ n = 0. If B 1n = 0 and B 2n > 0, then γ n = ±B 1/2 2n. If B 1n 0, then sgn(γ n ) = sgn(b 1n ). PROOF Suppose that B 1n = 0. Then Q n (γ) = 1 4 γ4 1 2 B 2nγ 2. If B 2n 0, this is globally minimized at zero; otherwise, the global minimum is attained when γ 2 = B 2n. Next, note that Q n (γ) Q n ( γ) = 2B 1n γ. Suppose that B 1n > 0. Then for any γ < 0, we have Q n (γ) > Q n ( γ). It follows that the minimum of Q n occurs on [0, ); that is, γ n 0. Also γ n 0 because D Q n (0) = B 1n 0. Thus, γ n > 0 if B 1n > 0. We can similarly show that γ n < 0 if B 1n < 0. Lemma 2 provides bounds for γ n. Lemma 2 Consider equation (30). If B 2n 0, then B 2n γ n B 1n. If B 2n > 0, then B 1/2 2n γ n B 1/2 2n + B 1n 1/3. PROOF Consider the case B 2n 0. Clearly there is a unique solution to the first-order condition, D Q n (γ) = γ 3 B 2n γ B 1n = 0, because γ 3 is increasing and B 2n γ+b 1n is decreasing. Obviously that unique solution must be the global minimizer, γ n. Suppose B 1n > 0. By Lemma 1, we have γ n > 0 and then, since B 2n γ n + B 1n = γ 3 n 0, we have B 2nγ n B 1n. Since B 2n 0, we have B 1n B 2n γ n 0, and so B 2n γ n B 1n. The case B 1n < 0 is similar. The case B 1n = 0 is trivial. Consider the case B 2n > 0. First, suppose B 1n = 0. By Lemma 1, there are two global minimizers, B 1/2 2n and B1/2 2n, and obviously B1/2 2n γ n B 1/2 2n. Now suppose B 1n > 0. The first-order condition D Q n (γ) = γ 3 B 2n γ B 1n = 0 may have 1 or 3 real solutions. By Lemma 1, the global minimizer satisfies γ n > 0. Fortunately, since γ 3 is increasing at an increasing rate and is 0 at γ = 0, while B 2n γ + B 1n is increasing at a constant rate and is strictly positive at γ = 0, there is a unique positive solution to the first-order condition. Furthermore, since D Q n (B 1/2 2n ) = B 1n < 0 and D Q n (B 1/2 2n +B1/3 1n ) = 2B 2nB 1/3 1n +3B1/2 2n B2/3 1n > 0, we have B 1/2 2n γ n B 1/2 2n + B1/3 1n. The case B 1n < 0 is similar.

19 17 Define w Ln = n 1/2 L n, w 1n = nb 1n, and w 2n = n 1/2 B 2n. Lemma 3 Under the assumptions of Theorem 4, there is a random variable (w L, w 1, w 2 ) such that (w Ln, w 1n, w 2n ) (w L, w 1, w 2 ). The lemma implies that w Ln = O p (1), w 1n = O p (1), and w 2n = O p (1) or, equivalently, that L n = O p (n 1/2 ), B 1n = O p (n 1 ), and B 2n = O p (n 1/2 ). Moreover, these rates are sharp in the sense that generally Var(w L ) > 0, Var(w 1 ) > 0, and Var(w 2 ) > 0. PROOF Recall from Section 3 that g(δ) = g(δ +α 0 ) and g(δ) = E( h 2i )δ 2 E( h 1i )δ +E( h 0i ). As argued in Section 3, when α 0 is uniquely identified and G = 0, then the nonconstant elements of g are all second-degree polynomials whose derivative is 0 at 0. Since also g(0) = 0 by the assumption of unique identification, and G = 2E(h 2i )α 0 E(h 1i ) = E( h 1i ) by definition, it follows that E( h 0i ) = 0, E( h 1i ) = 0 and E( h 2i ) 0. By Assumptions 1 and 2, the data are iid across individuals and all variances exist. Hence, it follows by the Lindeberg-Lévy central limit theorem and the Cramér-Wold device that n 1/2 H 0n e 0 and n 1/2 H 1n e 1, where e 0 and e 1 are normal random variables. Furthermore, it follows by Khinchin s law of large numbers that H 2n p E( h 2i ). Therefore, A 1n = 2H W 0n nh 1n = O p (n 1 ), A 2n = H W 1n nh 1n + 2H W 0n nh 2n = O p (n 1/2 ), A 3n = 2H W 1n nh 2n = O p (n 1/2 ), and plim A 4n = plim H W 2n nh 2n p E( h 2i ) WE( h 2i ). Since W is positive semidefinite and preserves identification, we have E( h 2i ) WE( h 2i ) > 0. Finally, L n = O p (n 1/2 ), K 1n = O p (n 1 ), K 2n = O p (n 1/2 ), B 1n = O p (n 1 ), and B 2n = O p (n 1/2 ). For simplicity, define A 4 = E( h 2i ) WE( h 2i ). It then follows that and L n = A 3n 4A 4 + o p (n 1/2 ) = H 1n WE( h 2i) 2A 4 + o p (n 1/2 ), B 1n = 2A 2nL n + A 1n 4A 4 W + o p (n 1 ) = H WE( h 2i )E( h 2i ) W 0n 2A 4 2A 2 4 H 1n + o p (n 1 ), B 2n = A 2n 2A 4 + o p (n 1/2 ) = H 0n WE( h 2i) A 4 + o p (n 1/2 ).

20 18 Define w L, w 1, and w 2 as the leading terms on the right-hand sides in the above equations with e 0 and e 1 replacing H 0n and H 1n. Then (w Ln, w 1n, w 2n ) p (w L, w 1, w 2 ), which in turn implies (w Ln, w 1n, w 2n ) (w L, w 1, w 2 ). Note that the distribution of (w L, w 1, w 2 ) follows from the underlying normality of (e 0, e 1 ) and the continuous mapping theorem. The asymptotic behavior of α n is very different when B 2n 0 and when B 2n > 0. Lemma 4 provides rates of convergence. Lemma 4 Under the assumptions of Theorem 4, we have nb 2n (α n α 0 L n ){B 2n 0} = O p (1), n 1/4 (α n α 0 L n ){B 2n > 0} = O p (1), nb 2n (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} = O p (1) and n 1/4 (α n α 0 ){B 2n > 0} = O p (1). PROOF Write γ n = γ n {B 2n 0} + γ n {B 2n > 0}. By Lemmas 2 and 3, B 2n γ n {B 2n 0} B 1n {B 2n 0} = O p (n 1 ) and γ n {B 2n > 0} (B 1/2 2n + B 1n 1/3 ){B 2n > 0} = O p (n 1/4 ). The conclusion now follows since α n α 0 = γ n + L n, and L n = O p (n 1/2 ) by Lemma 3. As mentioned in Section 3, nb 2n can be replaced with n 1/2 when B 2n 0. However, normalizing by nb 2n is likely to yield a more useful asymptotic distribution. Also, notice that it is not possible to improve on the slow convergence rate when B 2n > 0, because B 1/2 2n {B 2n > 0} γ n {B 2n > 0} and B 1/2 2n = O p(n 1/4 ) by Lemmas 2 and 3. That is, the rate n 1/4 is sharp. For the proof of Theorem 4, we consider the cases B 2n 0 and B 2n > 0 separately. First consider the case B 2n 0. We reparameterize from γ to θ where θ = nb 2n γ. Define N n by N n (θ) = n 1/2 (nb 2n ) 4 Q n (n 1 θ/b 2n ) = 1 4 n 1/2 θ w3 θ 2 w 2n 1n w 3 θ. (31) 2n Let θ N n denote the minimizer of N n, and note that θ N n = nb 2n γ n = nb 2n (α n α 0 L n ). Define N n and N by N n (θ) = N n(θ){b 2n 0} + θ 2 {B 2n > 0} (32)

21 19 and N (θ) = ( 1 2 w3 2 θ 2 w 1 w 3 2 θ){w 2 0} + θ 2 {w 2 > 0}. (33) Since N n (0) = 0, we have min θ N n (θ) 0, and therefore the minimizer of N n equals θ N n when B 2n 0 and 0 when B 2n > 0. Hence, the minimizer θ N n of N n can be written θ N n = θ N n{b 2n 0} = nb 2n (α n α 0 L n ){B 2n 0}. (34) Similarly the minimizer of N (θ) is unique and can be written θ N = w 1{w 2 0}. Now, since θ N n = O p(1) by Lemma 4, and since N n (θ) N (θ) locally uniformly, we have that θ N n θ N. That is, nb 2n(α n α 0 L n ){B 2n 0} w 1 {w 2 0}. Since nl n B 2n {B 2n 0} w L w 2 {w 2 0} by Lemma 3, we also have nb 2n (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} (w L w 2 w 1 ){w 2 0}. Finally, since n 1/2 B 2n has a nondegenerate limiting distribution, we have n 1/2 (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} (w L w 1 /w 2 ){w 2 0}. It is notable that fast (root-n) pointwise convergence of the quartic polynomial N n (θ) to N (θ) does not necessarily imply fast convergence of the minimizer of N (θ) to the min- n imizer of N (θ). Informal direct evaluation of the cubic roots shows that the convergence of the normalized estimator n 1/2 (α n α 0 ){B 2n 0} to its weak limit is at a slow n 1/4 rate. Now consider B 2n > 0. We reparameterize from γ to θ where θ = n 1/4 sgn(b 1n )γ. The term sgn(b 1n ) will be used to ensure that the limit function has a unique minimum. Define P n by P n (θ) = n Q n (n 1/4 sgn(b 1n )θ) = 1 4 θ w 2nθ 2 n 1/4 w 1n θ. (35) Let θ Pn denote the minimizer of P n, then θ Pn = n 1/4 sgn(b 1n )γ n = n 1/4 sgn(b 1n )(α n α 0 L n ). Importantly, θ Pn 0 since sgn(b 1n ) = sgn(γ n ) by Lemma 1. Define P n and P by P n (θ) = P n(θ){b 2n > 0, θ 0} + θ 2 (1 {B 2n > 0, θ 0}) (36)

22 20 and P (θ) = ( 1 4 θ w 2θ 2 ){w 2 > 0, θ 0} + θ 2 (1 {w 2 > 0, θ 0}). (37) Since P n (0) = 0, we have min θ P n (θ) 0, and therefore the minimizer of P n equals θ Pn when B 2n > 0 (the minimizer of P n is positive, so the factor {θ 0} does not matter) and equals 0 when B 2n 0. Hence, the minimizer θ Pn of P n can be written θ Pn = θ Pn{B 2n > 0} = n 1/4 sgn(b 1n )(α n α 0 L n ){B 2n > 0}. (38) The expression ( 1 4 θ w 2θ 2 ) in (37) has three roots; namely, w 1/2 2, 0, and w1/2 2. The root at w 1/2 2 is cancelled in P (θ) by the factor {θ 0}, and the root at 0 corresponds to a local maximum. Therefore the global minimizer of P (θ) is unique and can be written θ P = w1/2 2 {w 2 > 0}. Now, since θ Pn = O p(1) by Lemma 4, and since P n (θ) P (θ) locally uniformly, we have that θ Pn θ P. That is, n1/4 sgn(b 1n )(α n α 0 L n ){B 2n > 0} w 1/2 2 {w 2 > 0}. Finally, because L n = O p (n 1/2 ) and sgn(b 1n ) sgn(w 1 ), we have n 1/4 (α n α 0 ){B 2n > 0} sgn(w 1 )w 1/2 2 {w 2 > 0} as claimed. References Ahn, S. C. and P. Schmidt (1995). Efficient estimation of models for dynamic panel data. Journal of Econometrics 68, Arellano, M. and S. Bond (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies 58(2), Arellano, M. and O. Bover (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estiamtion of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68, Blundell, R. and S. Bond (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87, Bond, S. and F. Windmeijer (2005). Reliable inference for GMM estimators? Finite sam-

23 21 ple properties of alternative test procedures in linear panel data models. Econometric Reviews 24, Bun, M. and F. Kleibergen (2013). Identification and inference in moments based analysis of linear dynamic panel data models. Discussion paper 2013/07, Amsterdam School of Economics. Calzolari, G. and L. Magazzini (2013). A powerful test of mean stationarity in dynamic models for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence. Working paper 14, Department of Economics, University of Verona. Gørgens, T., C. Han, and S. Xue (2016). Moment restrictions and identification in linear dynamic panel data models. ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics #633, Australian National University. Han, C. and H. Kim (2014). The role of constant instruments in dynamic panel estimation. Economics Letters 124, Hayakawa, K. (2009). On the effect of nonstationary initial conditions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 153, Holtz-Eakin, D., W. Newey, and H. S. Rosen (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica 56(6), Kruiniger, H. (2009). GMM estimation and inference in dynamic panel data models with persistent data. Econometric Theory 25, Newey, W. K. and D. McFadden (1994). Large sample estimation and hypothesis testing. In R. F. Engle and D. L. McFadden (Eds.), Handbook of econometrics. Volume 4. Amsterdam; London and New York: Elsevier, North-Holland.

24 22 PDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n=10 7 Limit θ Figure 1: DGP1: Density of scaled estimator when B 2n 0 CDFn CDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n= θ Figure 2: DGP1: CDF convergence for scaled estimator when B 2n 0

25 23 PDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n=10 7 Limit θ Figure 3: DGP1: Density of scaled estimator when B 2n > 0 CDFn CDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n= θ Figure 4: DGP1: CDF convergence for scaled estimator when B 2n > 0

26 24 PDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n=10 7 Limit θ Figure 5: DGP2: Density of scaled estimator when B 2n 0 CDFn CDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n= θ Figure 6: DGP2: CDF convergence for scaled estimator when B 2n 0

27 25 PDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n=10 7 Limit θ Figure 7: DGP2: Density of scaled estimator when B 2n > 0 CDFn CDF n=10 4 n=10 5 n=10 6 n= θ Figure 8: DGP2: CDF convergence for scaled estimator when B 2n > 0

28 26 PDF n=10 2 n=10 3 n=10 4 n=10 5 N(0,1) θ Figure 9: DGP3: Density of scaled estimator CDFn CDF n=10 2 n=10 3 n=10 4 n= θ Figure 10: DGP3: CDF convergence for scaled estimator

Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity

Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity Giorgio Calzolari, Laura Magazzini WP Number: 12 July

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation

Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation Seung C. Ahn Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ 85187, USA Peter Schmidt * Michigan State University,

More information

The properties of L p -GMM estimators

The properties of L p -GMM estimators The properties of L p -GMM estimators Robert de Jong and Chirok Han Michigan State University February 2000 Abstract This paper considers Generalized Method of Moment-type estimators for which a criterion

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 5. Estimating Production Functions Using Proxy Variables 6. Pseudo Panels

More information

17/003. Alternative moment conditions and an efficient GMM estimator for dynamic panel data models. January, 2017

17/003. Alternative moment conditions and an efficient GMM estimator for dynamic panel data models. January, 2017 17/003 Alternative moment conditions and an efficient GMM estimator for dynamic panel data models Gabriel Montes-Rojas, Walter Sosa-Escudero, and Federico Zincenko January, 2017 Alternative moment conditions

More information

Linear dynamic panel data models

Linear dynamic panel data models Linear dynamic panel data models Laura Magazzini University of Verona L. Magazzini (UniVR) Dynamic PD 1 / 67 Linear dynamic panel data models Dynamic panel data models Notation & Assumptions One of the

More information

Efficient Estimation of Non-Linear Dynamic Panel Data Models with Application to Smooth Transition Models

Efficient Estimation of Non-Linear Dynamic Panel Data Models with Application to Smooth Transition Models Efficient Estimation of Non-Linear Dynamic Panel Data Models with Application to Smooth Transition Models Tue Gørgens Christopher L. Skeels Allan H. Würtz February 16, 2008 Preliminary and incomplete.

More information

1 Introduction The time series properties of economic series (orders of integration and cointegration) are often of considerable interest. In micro pa

1 Introduction The time series properties of economic series (orders of integration and cointegration) are often of considerable interest. In micro pa Unit Roots and Identification in Autoregressive Panel Data Models: A Comparison of Alternative Tests Stephen Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nuffield College, Oxford Céline Nauges LEERNA-INRA Toulouse

More information

GMM based inference for panel data models

GMM based inference for panel data models GMM based inference for panel data models Maurice J.G. Bun and Frank Kleibergen y this version: 24 February 2010 JEL-code: C13; C23 Keywords: dynamic panel data model, Generalized Method of Moments, weak

More information

Nonparametric Identification of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data - Supplemental Appendix

Nonparametric Identification of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data - Supplemental Appendix Nonparametric Identification of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data - Supplemental Appendix Yingying Dong and Arthur Lewbel California State University Fullerton and Boston College July 2010 Abstract

More information

Consistent OLS Estimation of AR(1) Dynamic Panel Data Models with Short Time Series

Consistent OLS Estimation of AR(1) Dynamic Panel Data Models with Short Time Series Consistent OLS Estimation of AR(1) Dynamic Panel Data Models with Short Time Series Kazuhiko Hayakawa Department of Economics Hitotsubashi University January 19, 006 Abstract In this paper, we examine

More information

Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection

Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection === Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection Anastasia Semykina* Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, FL 32306-2180 asemykina@fsu.edu Jeffrey M. Wooldridge

More information

Threshold regression with endogeneity for short panels. Tue Gørgens and Allan H. Würtz. CREATES Research Paper

Threshold regression with endogeneity for short panels. Tue Gørgens and Allan H. Würtz. CREATES Research Paper Threshold regression with endogeneity for short panels Tue Gørgens and Allan H. Würtz CREATES Research Paper 2018-27 Department of Economics and Business Economics Aarhus University Fuglesangs Allé 4 DK-8210

More information

University of Pavia. M Estimators. Eduardo Rossi

University of Pavia. M Estimators. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia M Estimators Eduardo Rossi Criterion Function A basic unifying notion is that most econometric estimators are defined as the minimizers of certain functions constructed from the sample

More information

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics ISSN 440-77X Australia Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics http://wwwbusecomonasheduau/depts/ebs/pubs/wpapers/ The Asymptotic Distribution of the LIML Estimator in a artially Identified

More information

An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic

An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic Chapter 6 ESTIMATION OF THE LONG-RUN COVARIANCE MATRIX An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic standard errors for the OLS and linear IV estimators presented

More information

Analogy Principle. Asymptotic Theory Part II. James J. Heckman University of Chicago. Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006

Analogy Principle. Asymptotic Theory Part II. James J. Heckman University of Chicago. Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006 Analogy Principle Asymptotic Theory Part II James J. Heckman University of Chicago Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006 Consider four methods: 1. Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) 2. (Nonlinear) Least

More information

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Chirok Han Victoria University of Wellington New Zealand Robert de Jong Ohio State University U.S.A October, 2003 Abstract This paper considers Closest

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 6 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 6 1 / 36 Outline 1 The First-Difference (FD) estimator 2 Dynamic panel data models 3 The Anderson and Hsiao

More information

X-Differencing and Dynamic Panel Model Estimation

X-Differencing and Dynamic Panel Model Estimation X-Differencing and Dynamic Panel Model Estimation Chirok Han Korea University PeterC.B.Phillips Yale University, University of Auckland University of Southampton & Singapore Management University Donggyu

More information

Department of Economics. Working Papers

Department of Economics. Working Papers 10ISSN 1183-1057 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Working Papers 08-07 "A Cauchy-Schwarz inequality for expectation of matrices" Pascal Lavergne November 2008 Economics A Cauchy-Schwarz

More information

Review of Classical Least Squares. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Review of Classical Least Squares. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Review of Classical Least Squares James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley The Classical Linear Model The object of least squares regression methods is to model and estimate

More information

A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure

A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure Kyoo il Kim Michigan State University Yao Luo University of Toronto Yingjun Su IESR, Jinan University August 2018

More information

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models Takashi Yamagata y Department of Economics and Related Studies, University of York, Heslington, York, UK January

More information

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Chirok Han and Robert de Jong January 28, 2002 Abstract This paper considers Closest Moment (CM) estimation with a general distance function, and avoids

More information

New GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models

New GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models I: 2319-8753 ew GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models Ahmed H. Youssef 1, Ahmed A. El-sheikh 2, Mohamed R. Abonazel 3 Professor, Department of tatistics, Faculty of cience, King Abdulaziz University,

More information

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models Econ. 513, Time Series Econometrics Fall 00 Chris Sims Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models 1. THE PROBLEM We consider here the problem of comparing two parametric models for the data X, defined by

More information

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation 1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation Consider the following Dynamic Panel Data (DPD) model y it = y it 1 ρ + x it β + µ i + v it (1.1) with i = {1, 2,..., N} denoting the individual

More information

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Article Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Fei Jin 1,2 and Lung-fei Lee 3, * 1 School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics,

More information

Testing Overidentifying Restrictions with Many Instruments and Heteroskedasticity

Testing Overidentifying Restrictions with Many Instruments and Heteroskedasticity Testing Overidentifying Restrictions with Many Instruments and Heteroskedasticity John C. Chao, Department of Economics, University of Maryland, chao@econ.umd.edu. Jerry A. Hausman, Department of Economics,

More information

LM threshold unit root tests

LM threshold unit root tests Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C., & Chul Yu, B. (2011). LM Threshold Unit Root Tests. Economics Letters, 110(2): 113-116 (Feb 2011). Published by Elsevier (ISSN: 0165-1765). http://0- dx.doi.org.wncln.wncln.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2010.10.014

More information

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors Tatsuma Wada Wayne State University This version: December 19, 11 Abstract This note provides explanations for an unexpected result, namely, the estimated parameter

More information

Equivalent representations of discrete-time two-state panel data models

Equivalent representations of discrete-time two-state panel data models Equivalent representations of discrete-time two-state panel data models by Tue Gorgens and Dean Hyslop ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # WP654 27 October 2017 JEL: C33, C35, C41 ISBN:

More information

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on Chapter 12 COINTEGRATING AND SPURIOUS REGRESSIONS This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on the estimators when the regressors and regressant are difference

More information

GMM ESTIMATION OF SHORT DYNAMIC PANEL DATA MODELS WITH INTERACTIVE FIXED EFFECTS

GMM ESTIMATION OF SHORT DYNAMIC PANEL DATA MODELS WITH INTERACTIVE FIXED EFFECTS J. Japan Statist. Soc. Vol. 42 No. 2 2012 109 123 GMM ESTIMATION OF SHORT DYNAMIC PANEL DATA MODELS WITH INTERACTIVE FIXED EFFECTS Kazuhiko Hayakawa* In this paper, we propose GMM estimators for short

More information

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science Introduction to Econometrics FIFTH EDITION Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents INTRODU CTION 1 Why study econometrics? 1 Aim of this

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Songnian Chen a, Xun Lu a, Xianbo Zhou b and Yahong Zhou c a Department of Economics, Hong Kong University

More information

The Time Series and Cross-Section Asymptotics of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models

The Time Series and Cross-Section Asymptotics of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models The Time Series and Cross-Section Asymptotics of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models Günce Eryürük August 200 Centro de Investigación Económica, Instituto Tecnológico Autónomo de

More information

Nonparametric Identication of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data and

Nonparametric Identication of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data and . Nonparametric Identication of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data and Returns to Lying? Identifying the Effects of Misreporting When the Truth is Unobserved Arthur Lewbel Boston College This

More information

Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study

Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study Discussion Paper: 2015/02 Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study Artūras Juodis www.ase.uva.nl/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Roetersstraat 11 1018

More information

Asymptotic Properties of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models

Asymptotic Properties of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models Asymptotic Properties of Empirical Likelihood Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models Günce Eryürük North Carolina State University February, 2009 Department of Economics, Box 80, North Carolina State University,

More information

Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation

Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation Jinhyuk Lee Kyoungwon Seo September 9, 016 Abstract This paper examines the numerical properties of the nested

More information

Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments

Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments Yoonseok Lee and Ryo Okui April 009 Preliminary; comments are welcome Abstract This paper considers specification testing

More information

Bias Correction Methods for Dynamic Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects

Bias Correction Methods for Dynamic Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Bias Correction Methods for Dynamic Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects Mohamed R. Abonazel Department of Applied Statistics and Econometrics, Institute of Statistical

More information

Exponential Tilting with Weak Instruments: Estimation and Testing

Exponential Tilting with Weak Instruments: Estimation and Testing Exponential Tilting with Weak Instruments: Estimation and Testing Mehmet Caner North Carolina State University January 2008 Abstract This article analyzes exponential tilting estimator with weak instruments

More information

Dealing With Endogeneity

Dealing With Endogeneity Dealing With Endogeneity Junhui Qian December 22, 2014 Outline Introduction Instrumental Variable Instrumental Variable Estimation Two-Stage Least Square Estimation Panel Data Endogeneity in Econometrics

More information

A forward demeaning transformation for a dynamic count panel data model *

A forward demeaning transformation for a dynamic count panel data model * A forward demeaning transformation for a dynamic count panel data model * Yoshitsugu Kitazawa January 21, 2010 Abstract In this note, a forward demeaning transformation is proposed for the linear feedback

More information

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis Muhammad Irfan Malik and Atiq-ur- Rehman International Institute of Islamic Economics, International

More information

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy y Bureau of Economic Analysis Chirok Han Korea University February 7, 202 Donggyu Sul University

More information

A Practical Test for Strict Exogeneity in Linear Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects

A Practical Test for Strict Exogeneity in Linear Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects A Practical Test for Strict Exogeneity in Linear Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects Liangjun Su, Yonghui Zhang,JieWei School of Economics, Singapore Management University School of Economics, Renmin

More information

On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models

On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models Discussion Paper: 007/08 On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models Jan F Kiviet wwwfeeuvanl/ke/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Department

More information

Subset-Continuous-Updating GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models

Subset-Continuous-Updating GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models econometrics Article Subset-Continuous-Updating GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models Richard A Ashley 1 and Xiaojin Sun 2, * 1 Department of Economics, Virginia Tech, Blacksburg, VA 24060, USA;

More information

Working Paper No Maximum score type estimators

Working Paper No Maximum score type estimators Warsaw School of Economics Institute of Econometrics Department of Applied Econometrics Department of Applied Econometrics Working Papers Warsaw School of Economics Al. iepodleglosci 64 02-554 Warszawa,

More information

ESTIMATION OF NONLINEAR BERKSON-TYPE MEASUREMENT ERROR MODELS

ESTIMATION OF NONLINEAR BERKSON-TYPE MEASUREMENT ERROR MODELS Statistica Sinica 13(2003), 1201-1210 ESTIMATION OF NONLINEAR BERKSON-TYPE MEASUREMENT ERROR MODELS Liqun Wang University of Manitoba Abstract: This paper studies a minimum distance moment estimator for

More information

A Bias-Corrected Method of Moments Approach to Estimation of Dynamic Short-T Panels *

A Bias-Corrected Method of Moments Approach to Estimation of Dynamic Short-T Panels * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 37 https://doi.org/10.4149/gwp37 A Bias-Corrected Method of Moments Approach to Estimation of Dynamic Short-T

More information

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED by W. Robert Reed Department of Economics and Finance University of Canterbury, New Zealand Email: bob.reed@canterbury.ac.nz

More information

IDENTIFICATION OF THE BINARY CHOICE MODEL WITH MISCLASSIFICATION

IDENTIFICATION OF THE BINARY CHOICE MODEL WITH MISCLASSIFICATION IDENTIFICATION OF THE BINARY CHOICE MODEL WITH MISCLASSIFICATION Arthur Lewbel Boston College December 19, 2000 Abstract MisclassiÞcation in binary choice (binomial response) models occurs when the dependent

More information

Rank based cointegration testing for dynamic panels with fixed T

Rank based cointegration testing for dynamic panels with fixed T Empir Econ (218 55:349 389 https://doi.org/1.17/s181-17-134-8 Rank based cointegration testing for dynamic panels with fixed T Artūras Juodis 1 Received: 1 November 215 / Accepted: 11 April 217 / Published

More information

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Chapter 6. Panel Data Joan Llull Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Introduction Chapter 6. Panel Data 2 Panel data The term panel data refers to data sets with repeated observations over

More information

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems *

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * February, 2005 Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * Peter Pedroni Williams College Tim Vogelsang Cornell University -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

Missing dependent variables in panel data models

Missing dependent variables in panel data models Missing dependent variables in panel data models Jason Abrevaya Abstract This paper considers estimation of a fixed-effects model in which the dependent variable may be missing. For cross-sectional units

More information

Econometrics II. Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the. Practitioner

Econometrics II. Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the. Practitioner Econometrics II Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the Practitioner Måns Söderbom 10 May 2011 Department of Economics, University of Gothenburg. Email: mans.soderbom@economics.gu.se. Web: www.economics.gu.se/soderbom,

More information

NUCLEAR NORM PENALIZED ESTIMATION OF INTERACTIVE FIXED EFFECT MODELS. Incomplete and Work in Progress. 1. Introduction

NUCLEAR NORM PENALIZED ESTIMATION OF INTERACTIVE FIXED EFFECT MODELS. Incomplete and Work in Progress. 1. Introduction NUCLEAR NORM PENALIZED ESTIMATION OF IERACTIVE FIXED EFFECT MODELS HYUNGSIK ROGER MOON AND MARTIN WEIDNER Incomplete and Work in Progress. Introduction Interactive fixed effects panel regression models

More information

Robust Standard Errors in Transformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity

Robust Standard Errors in Transformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity Robust Standard Errors in ransformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity Kazuhiko Hayakawa Hiroshima University M. Hashem Pesaran USC Dornsife IE

More information

A Primer on Asymptotics

A Primer on Asymptotics A Primer on Asymptotics Eric Zivot Department of Economics University of Washington September 30, 2003 Revised: October 7, 2009 Introduction The two main concepts in asymptotic theory covered in these

More information

1 Appendix A: Matrix Algebra

1 Appendix A: Matrix Algebra Appendix A: Matrix Algebra. Definitions Matrix A =[ ]=[A] Symmetric matrix: = for all and Diagonal matrix: 6=0if = but =0if 6= Scalar matrix: the diagonal matrix of = Identity matrix: the scalar matrix

More information

The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications. Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University

The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications. Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University Motivation: Poor Asymptotic Approximation Most of statistical inference relies on asymptotic theory. Motivation: Poor

More information

Robust Standard Errors in Transformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity

Robust Standard Errors in Transformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity Robust Standard Errors in ransformed Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Heteroskedasticity Kazuhiko Hayakawa Hiroshima University M. Hashem Pesaran University of Southern

More information

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Ralf Brüggemann a Carsten Jentsch b Carsten Trenkler c University of Konstanz University of Mannheim University of Mannheim IAB Nuremberg

More information

Economic modelling and forecasting

Economic modelling and forecasting Economic modelling and forecasting 2-6 February 2015 Bank of England he generalised method of moments Ole Rummel Adviser, CCBS at the Bank of England ole.rummel@bankofengland.co.uk Outline Classical estimation

More information

Quantile methods. Class Notes Manuel Arellano December 1, Let F (r) =Pr(Y r). Forτ (0, 1), theτth population quantile of Y is defined to be

Quantile methods. Class Notes Manuel Arellano December 1, Let F (r) =Pr(Y r). Forτ (0, 1), theτth population quantile of Y is defined to be Quantile methods Class Notes Manuel Arellano December 1, 2009 1 Unconditional quantiles Let F (r) =Pr(Y r). Forτ (0, 1), theτth population quantile of Y is defined to be Q τ (Y ) q τ F 1 (τ) =inf{r : F

More information

EC402: Serial Correlation. Danny Quah Economics Department, LSE Lent 2015

EC402: Serial Correlation. Danny Quah Economics Department, LSE Lent 2015 EC402: Serial Correlation Danny Quah Economics Department, LSE Lent 2015 OUTLINE 1. Stationarity 1.1 Covariance stationarity 1.2 Explicit Models. Special cases: ARMA processes 2. Some complex numbers.

More information

Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability

Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability Federico A. Bugni Department of Economics Duke University federico.bugni@duke.edu. September 22,

More information

Computational statistics

Computational statistics Computational statistics Markov Chain Monte Carlo methods Thierry Denœux March 2017 Thierry Denœux Computational statistics March 2017 1 / 71 Contents of this chapter When a target density f can be evaluated

More information

Estimation, Inference, and Hypothesis Testing

Estimation, Inference, and Hypothesis Testing Chapter 2 Estimation, Inference, and Hypothesis Testing Note: The primary reference for these notes is Ch. 7 and 8 of Casella & Berger 2. This text may be challenging if new to this topic and Ch. 7 of

More information

Fall, 2007 Nonlinear Econometrics. Theory: Consistency for Extremum Estimators. Modeling: Probit, Logit, and Other Links.

Fall, 2007 Nonlinear Econometrics. Theory: Consistency for Extremum Estimators. Modeling: Probit, Logit, and Other Links. 14.385 Fall, 2007 Nonlinear Econometrics Lecture 2. Theory: Consistency for Extremum Estimators Modeling: Probit, Logit, and Other Links. 1 Example: Binary Choice Models. The latent outcome is defined

More information

Dynamic Panels. Chapter Introduction Autoregressive Model

Dynamic Panels. Chapter Introduction Autoregressive Model Chapter 11 Dynamic Panels This chapter covers the econometrics methods to estimate dynamic panel data models, and presents examples in Stata to illustrate the use of these procedures. The topics in this

More information

Small Sample Bias Properties of the System GMM Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models

Small Sample Bias Properties of the System GMM Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models Small Sample Bias Properties of the System GMM Estimator in Dynamic Panel Data Models Kazuhiko Hayakawa Graduate School of Economics, Hitotsubashi University and JSPS Research Fellow June 9, 006 Abstract

More information

Modified Variance Ratio Test for Autocorrelation in the Presence of Heteroskedasticity

Modified Variance Ratio Test for Autocorrelation in the Presence of Heteroskedasticity The Lahore Journal of Economics 23 : 1 (Summer 2018): pp. 1 19 Modified Variance Ratio Test for Autocorrelation in the Presence of Heteroskedasticity Sohail Chand * and Nuzhat Aftab ** Abstract Given that

More information

Testing in GMM Models Without Truncation

Testing in GMM Models Without Truncation Testing in GMM Models Without Truncation TimothyJ.Vogelsang Departments of Economics and Statistical Science, Cornell University First Version August, 000; This Version June, 001 Abstract This paper proposes

More information

Parametric Identification of Multiplicative Exponential Heteroskedasticity

Parametric Identification of Multiplicative Exponential Heteroskedasticity Parametric Identification of Multiplicative Exponential Heteroskedasticity Alyssa Carlson Department of Economics, Michigan State University East Lansing, MI 48824-1038, United States Dated: October 5,

More information

We saw in the previous lectures that continuity and differentiability help to understand some aspects of a

We saw in the previous lectures that continuity and differentiability help to understand some aspects of a Module 3 : Differentiation and Mean Value Theorems Lecture 9 : Roll's theorem and Mean Value Theorem Objectives In this section you will learn the following : Roll's theorem Mean Value Theorem Applications

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis.

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis. A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis Author(s) Chigira, Hiroaki Citation Issue 2006-01 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13683 Right

More information

Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation

Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation Yale University Xu Cheng Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania First Draft: August, 2007 Revised: March

More information

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models School of Economics and Management - University of Geneva Christophe Hurlin, Université of Orléans University of Orléans April 2018 C. Hurlin (University of Orléans)

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

A better way to bootstrap pairs

A better way to bootstrap pairs A better way to bootstrap pairs Emmanuel Flachaire GREQAM - Université de la Méditerranée CORE - Université Catholique de Louvain April 999 Abstract In this paper we are interested in heteroskedastic regression

More information

On asymptotic properties of Quasi-ML, GMM and. EL estimators of covariance structure models

On asymptotic properties of Quasi-ML, GMM and. EL estimators of covariance structure models On asymptotic properties of Quasi-ML, GMM and EL estimators of covariance structure models Artem Prokhorov November, 006 Abstract The paper considers estimation of covariance structure models by QMLE,

More information

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics Eric Zivot January 14, 2013 The two main concepts in asymptotic theory that we will use are Consistency Asymptotic Normality Intuition consistency:

More information

Joakim Westerlund. Testing for Error Correction in Panel Data RM/06/056. JEL code : C12, C32

Joakim Westerlund. Testing for Error Correction in Panel Data RM/06/056. JEL code : C12, C32 Joakim Westerlund Testing for Error Correction in Panel Data RM/6/56 JEL code : C12, C32 Maastricht research school of Economics of TEchnology and ORganizations Universiteit Maastricht Faculty of Economics

More information

A Local Generalized Method of Moments Estimator

A Local Generalized Method of Moments Estimator A Local Generalized Method of Moments Estimator Arthur Lewbel Boston College June 2006 Abstract A local Generalized Method of Moments Estimator is proposed for nonparametrically estimating unknown functions

More information

Revisiting the Synthetic Control Estimator

Revisiting the Synthetic Control Estimator MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Revisiting the Synthetic Control Estimator Bruno Ferman and Cristine Pinto Sao Paulo School of Economics - FGV 23 November 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/77930/

More information

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments Comment on Weak instrument robust tests in GMM and the new Keynesian Phillips curve By Anna Mikusheva We are witnessing a growing awareness among applied researchers about the possibility of having weak

More information

Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges. Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006

Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges. Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006 Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006 This paper provides an impressive, yet compact and easily accessible review of the econometric literature

More information

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions By Maria Kyriacou

More information

HETEROSKEDASTICITY, TEMPORAL AND SPATIAL CORRELATION MATTER

HETEROSKEDASTICITY, TEMPORAL AND SPATIAL CORRELATION MATTER ACTA UNIVERSITATIS AGRICULTURAE ET SILVICULTURAE MENDELIANAE BRUNENSIS Volume LXI 239 Number 7, 2013 http://dx.doi.org/10.11118/actaun201361072151 HETEROSKEDASTICITY, TEMPORAL AND SPATIAL CORRELATION MATTER

More information

GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY. Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips.

GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY. Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips. GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY By Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips January 2007 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1599 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR

More information

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics Volume 9, Issue 2 2005 Article 4 A Note on the Hiemstra-Jones Test for Granger Non-causality Cees Diks Valentyn Panchenko University of Amsterdam, C.G.H.Diks@uva.nl

More information