Communities, Competition, Spillovers and Open. Space 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Communities, Competition, Spillovers and Open. Space 1"

Transcription

1 Communities, Competition, Spillovers and Open Space 1 Aaron Strong 2 and Randall Walsh 3 October 12, The invaluable assistance of Thomas Rutherford is greatfully acknowledged. 2 Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder 3 Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder.

2 Abstract We explore the impact of both the number and spatial distribution of local jurisdictions on the decision to commit developable acreage to the provision of open space. Our analysis differs from the existing literature on the provision of public goods in a number of ways. First, we demonstrate that the mixed public good nature of open space (in relation to private lot consumption) can yield outcomes where a single land rent-maximizing community over-supplies open space relative to the utility maximizing open space level. Second, by explicitly incorporating the spatial distribution of open space spillovers, our stylized model shows how competition can lead not only to inefficient levels of open space provision, but also to inefficiencies in the spatial distribution of open space. Finally, the efficacy of a market-based approach to restore open space levels is considered. Key Words: Open Space, Competition, Land Use. JEL: H41, R14, Q15

3 1 Introduction Open space protection is a focus of local governments across the United States. Communities are motivated to protect open space both for its amenity and recreation value and as a tool to manage urban growth. In the 2003 election alone, there were at least 134 ballot initiatives regarding open space preservation in the United States. Of those, 100, or 75%, were passed by voters generating over $1.8 billion for land conservation(land Trust Alliance). With this ongoing policy focus on land protection, it is important to understand how competition between jurisdictions affects the provision of open space. To this end, we evaluate the impacts of competition between jurisdictions on the provision of protected open space in a spatially differentiated general equilibrium framework. Open space is an interesting public good for two reasons that we explore in this paper. First, the input to open space is land. Land is also an input to the private good in question, namely residential lots. That is, through the provision of open space, we are automatically increasing the scarcity of land for residential development. We know from hedonic studies that proximity to undeveloped land can have a marked impact on housing prices. 1 Hence, open space protection impacts housing prices through two channels the amenity value of open space increases the value of proximate houses and additional land protection leads to reductions in the supply of residential land. The second key characteristic of open space as a public good is that the spatial distribution of open space is equally as important as the level of provision. This spatial link implies that even when a large quantity of land is allocated to open space, it is possible that only a few residents will benefit due to suboptimal distribution(al) patterns. For instance, from the perspective of households located near the urban core, the amenity benefits of large quantities of open space at the urban fringe may be much lower than those provided by small parks in the immediate vicinity. 1 Examples of this include: Riddel (2001), Bolitzer and Netusil (2000) and Schultz and King (2001) 1

4 To explore these issues, a general equilibrium model incorporating homogeneous residents and land rent maximizing spatially delineated jurisdictions is constructed. Our analysis within the framework of the model starts by considering the implications of different spatially delineated competition regimes on open space allocation, jurisdiction land values and welfare. We then consider the efficacy of market based and command and control policy approaches for addressing inefficiencies in open space provision. Our basic problem is to model how jurisdictions in close proximity compete in scalable public goods with spillover benefits to the residents of neighboring jurisdictions. Our approach draws on several strands of the literature. Key concepts include: the link between urban spatial structure and amenities; the capitalization effect of public goods when there are spillovers; and the role of a jurisdiction/social planner s decision in the allocation of public goods. First, consider the relationship between urban spatial structure and open space amenities. Begin with an area of land that is slated for residential development. The question that this paper asks is are more or fewer jurisdictions adventageous to the optimal provision of open space? Our approach builds on earlier work by Brueckner (1983) in which he explicitly models the trade off between land in the residential building footprint and land in yard space within the context of the monocentric city model. We extend this work by incorporating the spillovers of communal undeveloped land from one jurisdiction to another and consider the impact of differing competition structures. Wu and Plantinga (2003) also consider the impact of environmental amenities on urban spatial structure. Their work focuses on how municipalities may develop given an exogenous environmental amenity such as a hill or stream. Our work differs from this by considering an endogenous environmental amenity. We focus on how much open space is provided under different competition regimes. Each competition regime implies different patterns of spatial capitalization. We model 2

5 these spillovers as a continuous analog to the work of Cremer, Marchand, and Pestieau (1997). In their work, they consider how two neighboring municipalities decide to allocate a single non-scalable public good such as a recreation center or stadium. They consider a Nash equilibrium in public good provision and find that although the efficient level of the public good is not typically provided in the non-cooperative equilibrium, there does exist a cooperative system such that both municipalities share the cost and construct a single public good the efficient outcome of their model. Our model constructs reaction functions for each jurisdiction in open space and suggests a result similar to that of Cremer et al. (1997). Specifically, that when the spillovers of open space provision cannot be captured, in general, competition will lead to under provision. In order to highlight capitalization effects in our model, we fix the boundaries of the development region. As suggested by Brasington (2002), if the jurisdictional boundary may fluctuate, capitalization may not occur since more land can be allocated if the boundary is not fixed, driving down the price to marginal cost. Thus, communities located at the center of a metropolitan area may have greater capitalization effects than edge cities. Further, if the boundaries are allowed to fluctuate, any jurisdiction may capture all of the amenity rents that a potential buyer may have for the amenity. The role of the jurisdiction in our model is that of a land rent maximizer. There is a large body of work on the role of property value maximization in the provision of efficient public good levels. Early examples of this literature include: Sonstelie and Portney (1978), Sonstelie and Portney (1984), Bruekner (1983), and Epple and Zelenitz (1984). These papers outline assumptions that equate property value maximization with the efficient provision of public goods. In contrast, we find that under a variety of competition assumptions, including a single jurisdiction, property value maximization does not equate to the efficient provision of public goods. This is the result of the dual nature of open space and the fact that an individual jurisdiction may not be able to capture all of the amenity benefits of provision. Thus, by explicitly incorporating the input to public goods production, the results 3

6 of the previous work is overturned. 2 The Model The model is comprised of a set of N identical households, J spatially delineated developable regions of area A j and a set of K jurisdictions each controlling a development district comprised of one or more development regions. Households choose consumption of a numeraire good (which includes housing but not the residential lot) whose price is normalized to 1, a location in one of the development regions and conditional on location choice, a quantity of land (residential lot size). We abstract from the notion of housing in order to reduce the jurisdictions decision on vertical development and concentrate only on the horizontal aspect of development. The relationship between lots, regions, and districts is shown in Figure 1. Households choose development region j to maximize their indirect utility function: V j = V (P j, Q j, Y ), (2.1) where Y is the shared income level, P j is the price of land in region j and Q j measures the open space amenity in region j. This choice of price-environmental quality pair is similar to the choice faced in jurisdictional competition models where households face a price-public good pair. The open space amenity level is the spatially weighted sum of the amount of open space O j in the given region and its neighboring regions. The level of the open space amenity in region j is given by: Q j = j J φ j,j (O j ); (2.2) where φ j,j is a weighting matrix that defines how the contribution of open space to environmental quality decays as a function of distance from region j. Because all individuals are identical, in equilibrium, prices adjust such that V j is identical across all regions. Con- 4

7 ditional on region choice, demand for lot size is given by Roy s identity. D j = D(P j, Q j, Y ) (2.3) Jurisdictions control a set of development regions, which are aggregated into a district, and choose the quantity of open space to provide in each region subject to the constraint that developable land in a given region L j is given by L j = A j O j. A jurisdiction s rent from a given region,π j is then given by P j L j. Where P j is determined by the market clearing conditions: V (P j, O j, Y ) = V (P k, O k, Y ); j, k, (2.4) D(P j, O j, Y ) n j = A j O j ; j, (2.5) and, n j = N. J (2.6) We consider a closed model for simplicity of analysis. 2 The equilibrium outcome that arises from competition between rival jurisdictions in quantity of open space is characterized as a Nash Equilibrium in which each jurisdiction plays the rent maximizing strategy contingent on the actions of their competitors. For the second set of analyses, we incorporate a market-based policy mechanism. It is assumed that an income tax τ is assessed on each household. The income tax is used to finance a per acre subsidy on open space provision. A further discussion of the income tax is provided below. Finally, to close the model and simplify the welfare analysis, jurisdictional 2 Qualitatively the results of an open city model as well as an intermediate migration scenario provide similar results. 5

8 land rents are recycled equally to all households. This allows us to focus exclusively on the welfare of the households. These assumptions yield the following two budget constraints: P j L j + X j = (Y + ( j π j )/N)(1 τ) (2.7) τ(y + j π j /N)N = j subsidyo j (2.8) The complexity of the model s spatial Nash equilibrium precludes analytical solutions. 3 We therefore adopt a numerical strategy for analyzing the implications of the model. Toward this end, it is assumed that household utility takes a nested constant elasticity of substitution (NCES) form. Environmental quality and lot size are placed in one nest and numeraire consumption in the other. Thus, residents maximize utility with choice of development region: U(X j, L j, Q j ) = (αx ρ j + (1 α)(βlγ j + (1 β)qγ j )ρ/γ ) 1/ρ (2.9) subject to the budget constraint: X j + P j L j = (Y + j π j /N)(1 τ). (2.10) The environmental quality function is assumed to take the form: Q j = φ 0 / dist j,j (2.11) j J We calibrate the numerical model to a benchmark. In this benchmark, individuals spend 70% of their income on consumption of the numeraire good, leaving 30% for housing lot consumption. Further in the benchmark, individuals live on approximately 1 4 acre lots and approximately 1 6 of the land in any development region is allocated to open space. We 3 Cremer et al. (1997) are able to derive analytical results in a two location model with a non-scalable public good and no explicit consideration of space. 6

9 assume an elasticity of substitution on the upper level of the nesting structure of 1.2 and an elasticity of substitution between land and open space of 0.8. Under this specification, the lot-open space bundle has a stronger substitutes relationship with the numeraire than do open space and lot size in the lower nest. The development area is defined as follows. We assume that there are 100 one acre regions of developable land arranged in a square 10 X 10 grid and parameterize to a population of Note also that household income is normalized to one. This corresponds to a baseline utility level of 1 using the calibrated share form of the NCES utility. That is, if the resident purchases the baseline lot-numeraire bundle with the environmental quality as specified under the baseline assumptions the individual will achieve a utility of 1. 3 Numerical Method We solve for the Nash Equilibrium in the model using a diagonalization method. In our model, once the choice of open space for each development region is made by the jurisdictions, all other variables are uniquely determined by the market clearing equilibrium conditions. Here, individual jurisdictions compete in both quantity of residential land and environmental quality. From a given choice of open space, we derive the open space amenity associated with all development regions using the weighting matrix defined in equation 2.2 with the weights declining with the sqareroot of distance. The solution algorithm is as follows. For each jurisdiction, we initialize the amount of open space that they provide to an initial level. Next, consider first one of the jurisdictions. Taking all other jurisdictions open space allocations as given, the jurisdiction maximizes rents by choosing a level of open space in each of the regions that it controls. Next, we iterate over each of the jurisdictions in the economy identifying their optimal reponse and 4 This population corresponds with the benchmark condition on land consumption. 7

10 updating the open space levels in their region. 5 We continue to iterate over the set of jurisdictions until the system converges. For the social planner s problem (shared utility maximization), we simply iterate over choices of open space in each parcel until the system converges to a maximal shared utility level. 4 Baseline Results and Welfare Calculations We first consider the case of a social planner maximizing the shared utility level of the residents. Results are presented in Figure 4a and Table 4. Given our calibration, under the socially optimal outcome, in the aggregate there is a 14.5% allocation of open space in the development area. 6 Because fewer regions benefit from spillovers when land is protected near the boundary, this open space is not evenly distributed over the development area. Thus, we see in Figure 4a, there is a greater concentration of open space in the center of the development area. Under the social planner, the allocation maximizes the value of any parcel of open space accounting for the spillovers. As we perturb the spillover coefficient, φ 0, not only is the amount of open space perturbed but also the distribution. As we decrease spillovers, the total amount of open space increases and the slope, as we move from the center, decreases. That is, the distribution becomes flatter and more uniformly distributed. Analysis of welfare changes in the model is complicated by the general equilibrium nature of the simulations. To assess these issues, we adopt a specification of compensating variation that is consistent with the model. As a baseline utility for the welfare calculations we use the socially optimal shared utility level. Because households at different locations consume different bundles of numeraire, land and environmental quality implying different 5 Each iteration requires identifying the equilibrium outcome under each possible set of open space levels and identifying those levels which maximize jurisdiction s profit. 6 Note this outcome is not identical to the calibration used for the utility paramaters becuase in our calibration, we have not taken into account the spatial nature of open space provision. Thus, the calibration is not supportable as an equilibrium even given the pricing structure derived to calibrate the parameters. 8

11 welfare implications for the uses of land resources, we do not allow households to relocate in the welfare calculation. Further, because location is fixed and open space level within the region is fixed, we also do not allow lot size adjustments in the welfare calculation. Thus, the only portion of households allocations that will be allowed to adjust in the welfare calculation is that of the numeraire good. Thus, to identify the compensating variation for a given location under a given regime, we compute the amount of income that would have to be given to an individual in order to restore their utility level to that of the socially optimal utility level conditional on that money being spent on the numeraire good. Further, since incomes may vary across regimes due to the recycling of jurisdictional land rents, we normalize by the income level, 1 + j J Π j, of the regime outcome in question. Thus, compensating variation (CV) is given by: U(x j + CV, L j, Q j ) = U(x SO j, L SO j, Q SO j ) = U SO (4.12) where the superscript represents the socially optimal allocation and barred variables are fixed according to the regime and location under consideration. Our welfare measure therefore monetizes the welfare loss to the household under a given regime relative to the socially optimal utility level. 5 Competition without Spillovers In order to analyze the role of competition in a systematic manner, we begin by isolating the market power effect of open space provision and abstract from the role of benefit spillovers across jurisdictions and within jurisdictions. In our model, this amounts to setting φ j = 0, j J. First, we consider a duopoly case and evaluate different configurations of land within the development area. Second, we consider symmetric configurations with increasing numbers of jurisdictions. To consider the role of market power in the duopoly case, we assume that a small 9

12 developer is located along one edge of the development region. Results for this analysis are contained in Table 1 and Figure 2. The first observation to make is that moving from a monopoly case to a case with a small competing jursidiction (90%-10% split), has a large effect on the provision of open space. This small decrease in market power leads to a large decrease in welfare loss relative to the socially optimal, on the order of 66%, as competition alleviates the under provision of residential land that occurs in the single jurisdiction case. As we further decrease this market power in steps of 10%, we see roughly a halving of the welfare loss at each step. Thus, market power plays a key role in the provision of open space. With even a small amount of competition, we see a reduction in excess open space provision by the dominant jurisdiction. This relaxes the monopoly derived housing supply restriction by 41%. 7 As a second approach to the analysis of the impact of market power in the absence of spillovers, we consider the impact of moving from a single jurisdiction to a model with multiple symmetric jurisdictions. We progress from a monopoly jurisdiction through the case of two and 4 jurisdicitons to a case of 100 separate jurisdicitons that we call the competitive model. Results from this analysis appear in Table 2. As with the case of an increasingly larger competing jurisdiction without spillovers, decreased market power moves each jurisdicition toward the socially optimal allocation. The largest increase in welfare from competition comes at the first step, that of moving from the monopoly to the duopoly. Under this change, we see a weakening of the over provision of open space on the order of 86%. 7 The reduction in the over provision of open space is given by:

13 6 Competition with Spillovers We now consider how competition affects the allocation of open space when spillovers are present. As discussed in the model section, in this experiment we assume that there exist spillovers between each development region and not just between jurisdicitons. As in the no spillovers case, we begin by considering the duopoly case and consider the role of market power with different initial allocations of land. Results are presented in Table 3 and Figure 3. First, with a very small jurisdiction, we see free riding by the small jurisdiction on the over provision by the large jurisdiction. In fact, the small jurisdiction would like to expand its boundaries in order to provide even more area for residential lots. Our second observation is that as market power decreases and jurisdictions become more symmetric, welfare increases. Although in the limit, we have an underprovision of open space, the welfare loss is not that great. Finally, decreasing the market power beyond a split has virtually no effect on welfare. Although jurisdicitons are better able to capture spillovers and there is less market power, these effects move in opposite directions and almost perfectly offset each other. The next step in the analysis is to consider the role of symmetric competition in the presence of spillovers. As above, the analysis begins with a single jursidiction and progresses through a system of symmetric jurisdictions ending with each parcel of land owned by one of 100 different jurisdictions. The analysis assumes that the jurisdictions have perfect information regarding the preferences of potential residents. Thus, in the monopolist case with a fixed population size, we have a perfectly price discriminating jurisdiction. Under this framework, initial intuition might suggest that the monopolist will provide the optimal level of open space because the value of open space is capitalized in the price of the lot and all spillovers are captured by the monopolist. As we have already seen in the case without spillovers, this is not the case. Given the dual nature of open space as an input to both the private as well as public good 11

14 and the fact that there is a fixed a set of individuals in the development area, the closed city assumption, the monopolist chooses to over-provide the public good in order to restrict the amount of the private good available on the market. Thus, we may say that, in general, property value maximization does not necessarily lead to utility maximization. However, the general shape of the distribution is similar to that of the socially optimal distibution, that of larger amounts of open space at the center of the development area with decreasing open space toward the edge of the development area. Results for this analysis appear in Table 4 and Figure 4. Next, consider the case of a duopoly. Assume that the two jurisdictions have equal areas and are symmetric within the development area. Under this specification, not only is the total amount of open space provided below the efficient level, but the spatial distribution is also much more inefficient than under the monopolist. Because the jurisdictions are acting to maximize their land rents, in the Nash equilibrium they will allocate most of the open space away from where the other jurisdiction is located in order to maximize the internalization of the spillovers. This implies that most of the open space occurs not at the center of the development area, but at the center of the district controlled by each of the two competing jurisdictions. Under this competition regime, each jurisdiction provides approximately 12.1% of their area to open space. Thus, we see a shift from an over provision by the monopolist to a slight under provision with the imposition of competition. As we move to greater competition, these results are further exacerbated in both levels and distribution. In the competition without spillovers case, we saw a move toward the socially optimal with increased competition. By introducing spillovers, competition reduces the ability of the jurisdiction to capture rents from open space provision. There is an inherant trade off with increased competition between reducing the supply restriction and the ability of the jurisdiction to capture rents. Thus, as competition increases, open space necessarily decreases and the inablity to capture benefits dominates, causing an underprovision. 12

15 7 Market Based Instrument vs. Command and Control Finally, we consider the effectiveness of a uniform market-based instrument in the presence of inter-jurisdictional competition and cross-jurisdiction spillovers identifying the utility maximizing income tax-open space subsidy pair under each competition regime. Under this market-based instrument, a per unit open space subsidy is first identified and then in equilibrium an income tax rate is set which raises exactly the level of revenue needed to fund the resulting subsidies. The subsidy level is then chosen to maximize the shared utility level. We compare the outcome under this optimal uniform market-based instrument to a command and control regulation that mandates a uniform quantity of open space per acre. Table 5 and Figure 5 present the results from this analysis. First note that in the singlejurisdiction model, because the unregulated equilibrium leads to an overprovision of open space, the optimal tax and subsidy are both negative. As the first column in Table 5 shows, in the case of a single jurisdiction, a subsidy of units of income per acrereturns the system to the socially optimal levels of open space, land rents, income and shared utility level. This result is fairly intuitive. Because all households receive the same income, the income tax is identical to a non-distortionary head tax. In equilibrium, each subsidy level is associated with a specific aggregate open space level. And, because the single jurisdiction internalizes all spillovers, the jurisdiction chooses the optimal distribution of open space across locations for each unique aggregate open space level. For comparison, the final column of table 5 reports the optimal level of open space under a uniform command and control regulation. Because the command and control regulation does not allow for adjustments to reflect the variation in spillovers across location, the command and control policy slightly under-performs the market instrument under a single jurisdiction. 8 Once we move from the single jurisdiction case, because of the spatial inefficiencies 8 Since we are uniformly fixing the open space percentage for each region in this command and control regulation, the command and control level is independent of competition regime. 13

16 that are introduced by spatially discrete competing jurisdictions, it is no longer possible to return the system to the social optimal via the tax-subsidy instrument. As is shown in Table 5, once competition is introduced the open space tax is replaced by a subsidy. The required subsidy increases with competition from under the duopoly case to in the competitive model. Further, in contrast to the single jurisdiction case, once spatial inefficiencies in open space associated with the competing jurisdictions are introduced the uniform command and control regulation clearly dominates the optimal uniform tax-subsidy pair. 8 Conclusion This paper highlights two important types of market failure that link the spatial structure of jurisdictional competition to the provision of open space. First, because open space is an essential input to the development of residential lots, when rent-maximizing jurisdictions are able to exert market power they may provide open space purely as a by-product of their attempts to drive up prices through supply restrictions. Second, when open space amenities spillover across jurisdictional boundaries, changes in the spatial distribution of of competing jurisdictions lead to changes in the ability of these jurisdictions to internalize the benefits of open space provision. Our analysis considers the tradeoffs inherent between these two types of market failure. Specifically, we demonstrate that the incentives for a monopoly jurisdiction to restrict supply (potentially leading to the provision of open space beyond the efficient levels) provides an incentive to encourage greater levels of jurisdictional competition while the inability of multiple spatially fragmented jurisdictions to internalize the spillover benefits of open space encourages reductions in jurisdictional competition. The results from our numerical simulations suggest that externalities related to market power are largely ameliorated at low levels of competition. Given the problem of internalizing amenity spillovers as the 14

17 number of competing jurisdictions grows, the analysis therefore finds that social welfare is maximized when jurisdictional competition exists, but at low levels. Although these results are for a single parameterization of the model, the qualitative results will hold for most parameterizations of the model. The final thrust of our analysis considers the efficacy of uniform market-based instruments relative to a uniform command and control regulatory approach in the face of these competing market failures. In the case of a single jurisdiction, we find that the market based-instrument is capable of restoring the socially optimal open space allocation and therefore clearly dominates the command and control regime. However, once jurisdictional competition is introduced, inefficiencies in the spatial distribution of open space that are introduced through this competition cause the market-based approach to under-perform relative to the command and control strategy. 15

18 Figure 1: Definition of the Development Area Development Area District Region Lot 16

19 Figure 2: Open Space Percentage Under Duopoly Competition with Different Levels of Market Power and No Spillovers (a) Split (b) Split (c) Split (d) Split 17

20 Figure 3: Open Space Percentage Under Duopoly Competition with Different Levels of Market Power with Spillovers (a) Split (b) Split (c) Split (d) Split 18

21 Figure 4: Open Space Percentage Under Competition with Increased Number of Jurisdictions with Spillovers (a) Socially Optimal (b) Monopoly (c) Duopoly 0 (d) Quadopoly (e) Perfectly Competitive 0 19

22 Figure 5: Open Space Percentage Under Optimal Tax Instrument and Spillovers (a) Socially Optimal 0 (b) Monopoly (c) Duopoly 0.06 (d) Quadopoly (e) Competitive 20

23 Table 1: Impact of Size of Jurisdiction in Duopoly Case with No Spillovers Social Optimal Monopoly 10% and 20% & 30% & 40% & 90% 80% 70% 60% Percent Open Space & & & & CV as % of income % 0.79% 0.34% % 0.08% Rents & & & & Ave Lot Size & & & & Welfare Rank Table 2: Impact of Competition on Open Space Provision with No Spillovers Social Optimal Monopoly Duopoly Quadopoly Competitive Percent Open Space CV as % of income % 0.06% 0.009% % Rents Ave Lot Size Welfare Rank

24 Table 3: Impact of Size of Jurisdiction in Duopoly Case with Spillovers Social Optimal Monopoly 10% and 20% & 30% & 40% & 90% 80% 70% 60% Percent Open Space & 5.39 & 8.69 & & CV as % of income % 0.36% 0.21% % % Rents & & & & Ave LotSize & & & & Welfare Rank Table 4: Impact of Competition on Open Space Provision with Spillovers Social Optimal Monopoly Duopoly Quadopoly Competitive Percent Open Space CV as % of income % % 0.55% 2.16% Rents Ave Lot Size Welfare Rank

25 Table 5: Comparison of levels of optimal tax with different levels of competition and Command and Control Monopoly Duopoly Quadopoly Competitive Command & Control Percent Open Space Shared Utility CV as % of income 0.000% 0.053% 0.061% 0.043% 0.009% Rents Ave Lot Size Optimal Income Tax -1.09% % 3.03% NA Open Space Subsidy/Tax NA Welfare Rank

26 References Bolitzer, B. and Netusil, N. (2000). The Impact of Open Spaces on Property Values in Portland, Oregon. Journal of Environmental Management, 59, Brasington, D. M. (2002). Edge versus Center: Finding Common Ground in the Capitalizatino Debate. Journal of Urban Economics, 52, Brueckner, J. (1983). The Economics of Urban Yard Space: An Implicit-Market Model for Housing Attributes. Journal of Urban Economics, 46, Bruekner, J. (1983). Property Value Maximization and Public Sector Efficiency. Journal of Urban Economics, 14, Cremer, H., Marchand, M., and Pestieau, P. (1997). Investment in Local Public Servies: Nash Equilibrium and Social Optimum. Journal of Public Economics, 65 (1), Epple, D. and Zelenitz, A. (1984). Profit Maximizing Communities and the Theory of Local Public Expenditure: Comment. Journal of Urban Economics, 16, Riddel, M. (2001). A Dynamic Approach to Estimating Hedonic Prices for Environmental Goods: An Application to Open Space Purchases. Land Economics, 77, Schultz, S. and King, D. (2001). The Use of Census Data for Hedonic Price Estimates of Open-Space Amenities and Land Use. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22, Sonstelie, J. and Portney, P. (1978). Profit Maximizing Communities and the Theory of Local Public Expenditure. Journal of Urban Economics, 5, Sonstelie, J. and Portney, P. (1984). Profit Maximizing Communities and the Theory of Local Public Expenditure: Reply. Journal of Urban Economics, 20, Wu, J. and Plantinga, A. J. (2003). The Influence of Public Open Space on Urban Spatial Structure. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46 (2),

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Modern Urban and Regional Economics Modern Urban and Regional Economics SECOND EDITION Philip McCann OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents List of figures List of tables Introduction xii xiv xvii Part I Urban and Regional Economic Models and

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport

Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport Daniel Hörcher 1, Woubit Seifu 2, Bruno De Borger 2, and Daniel J. Graham 1 1 Imperial College London. South Kensington Campus,

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Trade policy III: Export subsidies The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw June 25, 2015 Overview Overview 1 1 Under perfect competition lead to welfare loss 2 Effects depending on market structures 1 Subsidies to

More information

AGEC 603. Stylized Cited Assumptions. Urban Density. Urban Density and Structures. q = a constant density the same throughout

AGEC 603. Stylized Cited Assumptions. Urban Density. Urban Density and Structures. q = a constant density the same throughout AGEC 603 Urban Density and Structures Stylized Cited Assumptions q = a constant density the same throughout c = constant structures the same throughout Reality housing is very heterogeneous Lot size varies

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

When Trade Leads to Inefficient Public Good Provision: a Tax competition model

When Trade Leads to Inefficient Public Good Provision: a Tax competition model When Trade Leads to Inefficient Public Good Provision: a Tax competition model Emmanuelle Taugourdeau Abderrahmane Ziad April 8, 2015 Abstract This paper analyses the tax competition mechanisms in a context

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. What is market design? Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. This requires different tools and ideas than neoclassical economics, which

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, A. Spatial issues

Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, A. Spatial issues Page 1 of 6 Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, 2009 A. Spatial issues 1. Spatial issues and the South African economy Spatial concentration of economic

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? Jean Louis Brillet, France For presentation at the LINK 2014 Conference New York, 22nd 24th October, 2014 Advertisement!!! The model uses EViews The

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Blocking Development

Blocking Development Blocking Development Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology October 11, 2005 Taking Stock Lecture 1: Institutions matter. Social conflict view, a useful perspective

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Schumpeterian Growth Models Schumpeterian Growth Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch14 Introduction Most process innovations either increase the quality of an existing

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Daron Acemoglu MIT September 12, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 3 September 12, 2007 1 / 40 Introduction

More information

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2 SGZ Macro Week 3, : Suboptimal Equilibria 1 Basic Points Effects of shocks can be magnified (damped) in suboptimal economies Multiple equilibria (stationary states, dynamic paths) in suboptimal economies

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

217 2013 8 1002-2031 2013 08-0095 - 06 F293. 3 B 6500-7500 / 39% 26% 1. 5 2 3 1 10% 60% 2007 1977 70973065 /71273154 2013-01 - 11 2013-03 - 14 95 2013 8 5 Oates 70% 54 4 residential sorting 6 7-8 9-11

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly Yasuo Sanjo Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University Abstract We investigate a mixed duopoly market by introducing quality choice

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? APPENIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? Santanu Chatterjee epartment of Economics Terry College of Business University of eorgia Appendix A The appendix describes the optimization problem

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo June 8, 2010 Abstract I investigate an asymmetric duopoly where

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Urban Economics. Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics. July 17, 2006

Urban Economics. Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics. July 17, 2006 Urban Economics Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics July 17, 2006 1. The basic model with identical agents We assume that the city is linear and monocentric. This means that the city

More information

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES University of Wisconsin-Madison March 1996 No. 393 On Market Equilibrium Analysis By Jean-Paul Chavas and Thomas L. Cox AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES Copyright 1996 by Jean-Paul Chavas and

More information

The effects of public transportation on urban form

The effects of public transportation on urban form Abstract The effects of public transportation on urban form Leonardo J. Basso Departamento de Ingeniería Civil, Universidad de Chile ljbasso@ing.uchile.cl Matías Navarro Centro de Desarrollo Urbano Sustentable

More information

Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV

Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV Keynes and the Classics Notes on the Monetary Theory of Production Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV Social production, value and distribution (436-445) The starting point is a Leontief price system:

More information

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum R. erry, M. Honig, T. Nguyen, V. Subramanian & R. V. Vohra Abstract We consider a model of Cournot competition with congestion motivated by recent initiatives

More information

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann Chapter 3 Task 1-4 Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann Recept on how to derive the Euler-Equation (Keynes-Ramsey-Rule) 1. Construct the Hamiltonian Equation (Lagrange) H c, k, t, μ = U + μ(side Condition)

More information

Expanding Variety Models

Expanding Variety Models Expanding Variety Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch13 Introduction R&D and technology adoption are purposeful activities The simplest

More information

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1 Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1 Zheng Liu 1 Pengfei Wang 2 Zhiwei Xu 3 1 Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 2 Hong Kong University of Science and Technology 3 Shanghai Jiao

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress Daron Acemoglu MIT September 15, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 15, 2016.

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

MODELING CITIES WITH CONGESTION AND AGGLOMERATION EXTERNALITIES: THE EFFICIENCY OF CONGESTION TOLLS, LABOR SUBSIDIES, AND URBAN GROWTH BOUNDARIES

MODELING CITIES WITH CONGESTION AND AGGLOMERATION EXTERNALITIES: THE EFFICIENCY OF CONGESTION TOLLS, LABOR SUBSIDIES, AND URBAN GROWTH BOUNDARIES MODELING CITIES WITH CONGESTION AND AGGLOMERATION EXTERNALITIES: THE EFFICIENCY OF CONGESTION TOLLS, LABOR SUBSIDIES, AND URBAN GROWTH BOUNDARIES Wenjia Zhang Community and Regional Planning Program School

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class. Political Economy of Institutions and Development: 14.773 Problem Set 1 Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class. Answer Questions 1-3. handed in. The other two questions are for practice and are not

More information

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth Vahagn Jerbashian Universitat de Barcelona June 2016 Early growth theory One of the seminal papers, Solow (1957) discusses how physical capital

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium 1 Competitive equilibrium Handout: Competitive Equilibrium Definition 1. A competitive equilibrium is a set of endogenous variables (Ĉ, N s, N d, T, π, ŵ), such that given the exogenous variables (G, z,

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics 7. Special-interest politics Motivation Why do some groups in society receive more generous support than other (e.g. farmers)? Homogeneity in interests which allows more efficient organization of lobby

More information

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition Alessia Campolmi Università di Verona Harald Fadinger University of Mannheim and CEPR Chiara Forlati University of Southampton February

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses taught

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination.

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination. Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power Chapter 1: Monopoly Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination. Best known monopoly distortion: p>mc DWL (section 1). Other

More information

National Spatial Development Perspective (NSDP) Policy Coordination and Advisory Service

National Spatial Development Perspective (NSDP) Policy Coordination and Advisory Service National Spatial Development Perspective (NSDP) Policy Coordination and Advisory Service 1 BACKGROUND The advances made in the First Decade by far supersede the weaknesses. Yet, if all indicators were

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration Ian Sheldon and Brian Roe (The Ohio State University Quality Promotion through Eco-Labeling:

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics Endogenous Growth Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Endogenous growth 1 / 18 Introduction The Solow and Ramsey models are exogenous growth

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 37

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 37 1 / 37 Political Economics Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich Summer term 2010 4 / 37 Table of contents 1 Introduction(MG) 2 Preferences and voting (MG) 3 Voter turnout (MG) 4 Electoral competition (SÜ)

More information

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 11.433J / 15.021J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms. Recitation 3 Real

More information

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition Taku Masuda and Susumu Sato Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Graduate School of Economics,

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

Modeling firms locational choice

Modeling firms locational choice Modeling firms locational choice Giulio Bottazzi DIMETIC School Pécs, 05 July 2010 Agglomeration derive from some form of externality. Drivers of agglomeration can be of two types: pecuniary and non-pecuniary.

More information

Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs

Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs Samuel G Hanson David S Scharfstein Adi Sunderam Harvard University June 018 Contents A Programs that impact the

More information

What s wrong with sprawl? The urgent need for cost benefit analyses of modern urban growth patterns. Jacy Gaige

What s wrong with sprawl? The urgent need for cost benefit analyses of modern urban growth patterns. Jacy Gaige What s wrong with sprawl? The urgent need for cost benefit analyses of modern urban growth patterns. Jacy Gaige Urban Econ 245 Professor Charles Becker Literature Review 1 Urban is hip. Bikes, messenger

More information

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1 Ralph s Strategic Disclosure Ralph manages a firm that operates in a duopoly Both Ralph s (privatevalue) production cost and (common-value) inverse demand are uncertain Ralph s (constant marginal) production

More information

The Monocentric City Model

The Monocentric City Model 1 / 58 The Monocentric City Model Nathan Schiff Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Graduate Urban Economics, Lecture 2 March 7, 2019 2 / 58 Introduction One of the biggest questions in urban

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Volume Author/Editor: Gregory K. Ingram, John F. Kain, and J. Royce Ginn. Volume URL:

Volume Author/Editor: Gregory K. Ingram, John F. Kain, and J. Royce Ginn. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Detroit Prototype of the NBER Urban Simulation Model Volume Author/Editor: Gregory K.

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Matteo Paradisi November 1, 2016 In this Section we develop a theoretical analysis of optimal minimum

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Modeling Recreational Amenities in an Urban Setting: Location, Congestion, and Substitution Effects

Modeling Recreational Amenities in an Urban Setting: Location, Congestion, and Substitution Effects Modeling Recreational Amenities in an Urban Setting: Location, Congestion, and Substitution Effects Frances R. Homans and Elizabeth P. Marshall In this article, we introduce a recreational amenity a greenbelt

More information

Environmental Amenities and Community Characteristics: An Empirical Study of Portland, Oregon. Seong-Hoon Cho and JunJie Wu

Environmental Amenities and Community Characteristics: An Empirical Study of Portland, Oregon. Seong-Hoon Cho and JunJie Wu Environmental Amenities and Community Characteristics: An Empirical Study of Portland, Oregon by Seong-Hoon Cho and JunJie Wu Corresponding author: Seong-Hoon Cho Warnell School of Forest Resources University

More information

Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth

Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth Andreas Schäfer University of Leipzig Maik T. Schneider ETH Zurich Preliminary version 8. May 2008 Abstract Why are intellectual property rights in some countries higher

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V31.0013 Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm Question 1. Welfare Theorems (a) There are two households that maximize max i,g 1 + g 2 ) {c i,l i} (1) st : c i w(1

More information

Should Robots Be Taxed?

Should Robots Be Taxed? Should Robots Be Taxed? Joao Guerreiro, Sergio Rebelo, and Pedro Teles August 2017 (revised September 2017) Abstract We use a model of automation to show that with the current U.S. tax system, a fall in

More information

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Gustav Engström The Beijer Institute of Environmental Economics Stockholm, December 2012 G. Engström (Beijer) Stockholm, December

More information

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated Chapter 4 The Consumer Exercise 4.1 You observe a consumer in two situations: with an income of $100 he buys 5 units of good 1 at a price of $10 per unit and 10 units of good 2 at a price of $5 per unit.

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation Daron Acemoglu MIT September 19, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition and Innovation September 19, 2011. 1 / 51 Competition and Innovation

More information

INTELLIGENT CITIES AND A NEW ECONOMIC STORY CASES FOR HOUSING DUNCAN MACLENNAN UNIVERSITIES OF GLASGOW AND ST ANDREWS

INTELLIGENT CITIES AND A NEW ECONOMIC STORY CASES FOR HOUSING DUNCAN MACLENNAN UNIVERSITIES OF GLASGOW AND ST ANDREWS INTELLIGENT CITIES AND A NEW ECONOMIC STORY CASES FOR HOUSING DUNCAN MACLENNAN UNIVERSITIES OF GLASGOW AND ST ANDREWS THREE POLICY PARADOXES 16-11-08 1. GROWING FISCAL IMBALANCE 1. All orders of government

More information

The Definition of Market Equilibrium The concept of market equilibrium, like the notion of equilibrium in just about every other context, is supposed to capture the idea of a state of the system in which

More information

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Luc Christiaensen and Ravi Kanbur World Bank Cornell Conference Washington, DC 18 19May, 2016 losure Authorized Public Disclosure

More information