Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica. Economies

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica. Economies"

Transcription

1 Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 eplica Economies Maxwell Pak Queen s University This version: April 2009 Abstract This paper presents a model of price adjustment in replica economies with two consumer types and two goods. The model provides a trading rule that allows out-of-equilibrium trading and a decentralized price adjustment rule that features learning through noisy imitation. It is shown that for all sufficiently large economies, the process of experimentation and imitation favors adjustment of prices in the direction of the excess demand. When the experimentation probability is small, the price adjustment process mostly follows a tâtonnementlike dynamics, and the limiting distribution is concentrated around the Walrasian equilibrium. Price adjustment, tâtonnement, exchange economy, stochastic stabil- Keywords: ity. JEL Classification: C7, D51, D83. This paper has benefitted greatly from numerous discussions with Chris Shannon. I am also deeply indebted to Steve Evans for his guidance on the continuous state space Markov chain literature. Department of Economics, Queen s University. Kingston, Ontario K7L 3N6, Canada. Phone: Fax: pakm@qed.econ.queensu.ca. 1

2 1 Introduction Walrasian equilibrium defines equilibrium price vector in an exchange economy as the prices at which all markets clear when all consumers are maximizing their preferences given these prices. The intuitive appeal of this definition makes Walrasian equilibrium the natural equilibrium concept not only for an exchange economy but also for many other economic models. Not surprisingly, then, there have been many attempts at modeling the dynamic process through which a Walrasian equilibrium may arise. A well-known example is tâtonnement dynamics, first proposed in 1874 by Walras [9], which assumes that the price of a good adjusts in the direction of its excess demand. 1 Tâtonnement dynamics captures the seemingly correct intuition that for an economy to reach its equilibrium, the price of a good should rise when its demand exceeds its supply, and fall when its supply exceeds its demand. Also well known about tâtonnement dynamics, however, are its many shortcomings as a model of price adjustment. First, its stability is not guaranteed in economies with more than two goods. Second, it leaves the motivation of the price-setting agent unmodeled. Tâtonnement models typically assume the existence of an exogenous agent, commonly called the Walrasian auctioneer, who learns the demand of all the market agents at given prices and adjusts the price of each good according to the sign of its excess demand. However, assuming that the auctioneer is exogenous and not modeling why she would want to adjust prices in this particular manner is a significant omission in models in which all agents are assumed to maximize their own preferences. Third, it does not specify how trading occurs when the economy is not in equilibrium. Typically, the models assume that prices first adjust toward their limit, and that there is no actual trading until the equilibrium prices have been reached. Without out-of-equilibrium trades, however, there is no incentive for agents to reveal their 1 For general discussion of tâtonnement dynamics, see Hahn [3]. 2

3 demand. Thus, tâtonnement dynamics fails to be a satisfactory model of price adjustment even in settings where its stability can be assured. This paper addresses this issue by modeling a decentralized, endogenous price adjustment process that is tâtonnementlike. In particular, it provides a trading rule and a price adjustment rule in replica economies with two consumer types and two goods. The trading rule is constructed to allow trades to occur out of equilibrium. The price adjustment rule assumes that the two consumer types set prices in different periods and adjust prices through a learning through noisy imitation rule, in which the prices that were most successful in the previous period are adopted with high probability but random experiments are also taken with low but strictly positive probability. 2 It is shown that for all sufficiently large economies, the noisy imitation rule favors adjustment of prices in the direction of the excess demand. As a result, when the experimentation probability is small, the price adjustment process mostly follows a tâtonnement-like dynamics and leads eventually to a Walrasian equilibrium. More precisely, this paper shows that for any fixed experimentation probability, the distribution of the prices converges to some limiting distribution. Following the standard approach in evolutionary game theory, the limit of the limiting distributions, as the experimentation probability decreases to zero, is then considered. The main result shows that for any small neighborhood of the equilibrium price vector, the limit of the limiting distributions is concentrated inside the neighborhood for all sufficiently large economies. These results, however, are derived in the restrictive setting of a two-consumers, two-goods, replica economy with a unique equilibrium. The two-consumers, twogoods economy with a unique equilibrium provides the simplest setting where tâtonnement dynamics is globally stable. Because the price adjustment dynamics incorporates learning through imitation, the existence of other agents from whom a given agent 2 See Foster and Young [2], Kandori, Mailath, and ob [4], and Young [10] for pioneering examples of evolutionary models that feature persistent random experimentation. 3

4 can learn is required. Thus, a replica economy in which there are many identical agents of each consumer type provides a natural setting for the model. Ultimately, like other attempts at providing a foundation for tâtonnement dynamics, this paper addresses some issues while leaving others unresolved. For example, Keisler [5] models a price adjustment process that approximates tâtonnement dynamics and also features out-of-equilibrium trading and decentralized price setting. Keisler assumes that a large, finite set of agents takes turns trading with a market maker and shows that if at each period the market maker adjusts the price vector in the direction opposite to the changes in her inventory, the price vector approaches a Walrasian equilibrium under suitable conditions. While Keisler s model resolves many deficiencies of tâtonnement dynamics without resorting to the restrictive setting of this paper, it leaves unmodeled the motivation of the market maker to adjust the prices in the specified manner. In contrast, the focus in this paper is on providing a model, albeit in a simple setting, in which price setters adjust prices because it is in their interest to do so. 3 Studying a price adjustment process through an evolutionary game theory approach is not new. In a partial equilibrium context, Vega-edondo [8] shows that learning through noisy imitation leads to the competitive equilibrium price in Cournot competition with identical firms. In addition, Temzelides [7] applies noisy imitation to the market game of Shapley and Shubik in 2 2 replica economies and shows that it leads to the Walrasian equilibrium. While this paper shares the same replica economy setting of Temzelides [7], the papers differ in that the market game requires the existence of an auctioneer who collects the bids and use them to determine the market clearing prices. Methodologically, this paper also departs from the existing literature on learning 3 More recently, Crockett, Spear, and Sunder [1] provides a decentralized process that leads to a competitive equilibrium in a general setting. Agents in their model use a random search to first get near a Pareto optimal allocation and then use modified random searches to move towards a competitive equilibrium. However, the modified random searches require some agents to accept allocations that make them strictly worse off, and the motivation for accepting such allocation is left unmodeled. 4

5 through noisy imitation. The existing literature is limited to finite state space models since it relies on the use of the tree-surgery technique to characterize a limiting distribution. However, as prices get closer to the equilibrium price vector, the excess demand approaches zero, and the set of prices that can be successfully adopted through experimentation and imitation becomes arbitrarily small. As a result, considering only a finite set of prices, however large, leads to unnecessary complications. Consequently, this paper foregoes the tree-surgery technique and applies a method that is applicable to general state space models. The remaining pages are organized as follows. Section 2 presents the trading rule and the price adjustment rule considered in this paper. Section 3 provides the main result, and Section 4 gives a brief conclusion. The lemmas and their proofs that support the main result are given in the Appendix. 2 The Price Adjustment Process Since a replica economy is an economy in which there are many copies of the consumers of some underlying economy, the description of the model begins with the specification of the underlying economy. The underlying economy is a pure exchange economy consisting of two consumers and two goods. The set of consumers is denoted by I = {1, 2}. For each i I, let ω i 2 ++ denote consumer i s initial endowment, and let i denote consumer i s preference, which is assumed to be continuous, strongly monotone, and strictly convex. Let u i ) denote the continuous utility function representing i. Consumer i s demand function is denoted by x i : , where = {p 1, p 2 ) 2 ++ : p 1 + p 2 = 1}. 4 Let z i : p, ω i ) x i p, ω i ) ω i denote consumer i s excess demand function, and let z : p, ω 1, ω 2 ) z 1 p, ω 1 ) + z 2 p, ω 2 ) denote the market excess demand function. A Walrasian equilibrium price vector of the 4 The assumptions on the preferences imply that x i, ) is a continuous function. 5

6 underlying economy is a price vector p that satisfies zp, ω 1, ω 2 ) = 0. It is assumed that the Walrasian equilibrium is unique and satisfies x i p, ω i ) ω i for all i I. The -replica economy is the economy with 2 consumers in which consumers are exact copies of consumer 1 of the underlying economy and the remaining consumers are exact copies of consumer 2. That is, the consumers in the underlying economy are interpreted as consumer types so that I now denotes the set of consumer types. For each type i I, there are consumers with the identical preference i and the identical initial endowment ω i. These consumers are called type i replicas, and r-th replica of type i is denoted ir. A replica economy is related to the underlying economy in that price vector p together with each replica ir consuming x i p, ω i ) is also a Walrasian equilibrium in the replica economy. The following two subsections present the price adjustment model considered here. In the model, each replica ir starts with the same endowment ω i in every period. In the beginning of each period, a consumer type is chosen randomly as the price setter. After the prices have been set, trades occur according to the trading rule specified in Subsection 2.1. After all the trades have been completed, consumptions occur and the new period begins. In the next period, each replica again receives her endowment, a new price-setter type is chosen randomly, and the prices are set according to the learning rule specified in Subsection 2.2. As seen below, these two rules together imply that the evolution of prices can be modeled as a Markov chain on the state space Ξ = I, where a state i, p 1,..., p ) Ξ has the interpretation that type i consumer is the price setter and that replica ir has set price vector p r. 5 5 In the discrete time model developed here, only one consumer type is chosen as the price setter in each period. This assumption may seem more plausible if the discrete time model is thought of as being embedded in a continuous time model in which price adjustments occur at random times. Suppose each consumer type sets prices independently of each other and that the waiting time between the price adjustments has exponential distribution. Assume further that each type reacts first to the other type s price changes before attempting to set its own prices. Then since the probability of two adjustments occurring at any given time is zero, watching this continuous time process only at random times in which a price adjustment occurs is effectively equivalent to the original discrete time setup. 6

7 2.1 The Trading ule The trading rule assumes that replicas of the price-taker type trade with replicas of the price-setter type in sequential stages, starting with the price setters with the most favorable prices and ending with the price setters with the least favorable prices. The price takers are active traders in that they choose the order of their trading partners and set the desired net trade vector. The price setters are passive in that they only trade when asked to trade by a price taker and are required to trade in an amount proportional to the net trade vector desired by the price takers. More precisely, suppose a state i, p 1,..., p ) Ξ has been realized at the beginning of the current period. In particular, let j i denote the price-taker type. In the following, Ψ s denotes the set of price setters that the price takers have not yet traded with as of the beginning of stage s, and Φ s denotes the price takers most favorable trading partners among those in Ψ s. Each price setter trades only once, and the result of her trade is denoted ˆω ir. Since all price takers have the same preference and endowment and face the same set of prices, they are assumed to behave identically. The commodity vector each type j replica has at the beginning of stage s is denoted by ωj s, and the final result of her trading in the current period is denoted by ˆω j, without using subscripts to distinguish among replicas. Finally, in this paper any reference to j I will always mean j i, and will denote the set {1,..., }. Trading within the current period can now be described in the following inductive manner. Let Ψ 0 =, Φ 0 =, and ω 1 j = ω j. At stage s, let Ψ s = Ψ s 1 \ Φ s 1. Assume Ψ s. Let p {p r : r Ψ s } be such that x j p, ω s j ) j x j p r, ω s j ) for all r Ψs, and let Φ s = {r Ψ s : p r = p}. The total net trade desired by each type j replica from the type i replicas in Φ s is given by z j p, ωj s ). Since type j replicas are indifferent among their 7

8 trading partners in Φ s, each type j replica is assumed to desire 1 Φ s z jp, ω s j ) from each replica in Φ s. Thus, each type i replica in Φ s receives a total order of Φ s z jp, ωj s ) as the desired net trade from type j replicas. After an order is received, each type i replica in Φ s gives α s z j p, ωj s ) to each type j replica, where α s = arg max u i ω i α ) Φ s z jp, ωj s ). In particular, it is assumed that price setters are allowed to partially fill the orders they receive as long as they trade in the amount proportional to the trade vector desired by the price takers. The result of the trading in s-th stage is given by: ω s+1 j = ω s j + α s z j p, ω s j ), and r Φ s, ˆω ir = ω i α s Φ s z jp, ωj s ). The trading proceeds to stage s + 1 if Ψ s+1 = Ψ s \ Φ s. Otherwise, all trades have been completed and ˆω j = ω s+1 j. 2.2 The Price Adjustment ule Define a best price correspondence B from Ξ into as follows. For any ξ = i, p 1,..., p ) Ξ, let trades occur according to the trading rule described above. Then B is defined by Bξ) = { p r {p 1,..., p } : ˆω ir i ˆω ir r }. Thus, Bξ) is the set of prices that were most successful for type i. Let ˆδ > 0 and for all p = p 1, p 2 ), let N p, ˆδ) = {q 1, q 2 ) : q 1 p 1 < ˆδ} be the ˆδ-neighborhood of p. The price adjustment process is governed by the following learning through noisy 8

9 imitation rule: At t = 0: A state in Ξ is chosen according to some arbitrary initial distribution. At t = 1, 2, 3,...: Suppose ξ = i, p 1,..., p ) is the state chosen at period t 1. Then a new state is chosen at period t in the following way. 1. First, k I is chosen with uniform probability. 2. If k = i, then each replica ir independently chooses a price vector in either of two ways. With probability 1 ε > 0, replica ir imitates. That is, replica ir chooses an element of Bξ) with uniform probability. With probability ε > 0, replica ir experiments. That is, replica ir chooses an element of N p r, ˆδ) with uniform probability. 3. If k = j, then each replica jr adopts the previous period s prices by setting p r. 6 Formally, for any Z ++ and ε 0, 1), the price adjustment rule, together with the trading rule, defines a Markov chain ξ ε on Ξ. Let λ L be the Lebesgue measure on. Define measure µ L on subsets of by µ L C) = λ L {p 1 : p 1, 1 p 1 ) C}). For any Borel subset A of Ξ, let A k = r=1 A kr = {p 1,..., p ) : k, p 1,..., p ) A}. Let 1 denote the indicator function. For any ξ = i, p 1,..., p ) Ξ, the transition probability from ξ to A is given by Prob ξ ε t A ξ ε t 1 = ξ ) = ε) Bξ) Air r= {p 1,...,p ) A j }. Bξ) ) + εµ L N p r, ˆδ) A ir ) 6 This specification implicitly assumes that consumers only remember the immediate past. If the price setters in the current period had not been the price setters in the previous period, they would have no information about which prices had been successful. It is assumed that under this scenario they simply adopt the previous period s prices. 9

10 3 Limiting Distribution This section characterizes the long-run behavior of the price adjustment dynamics. As a starting point, Subsection 3.1 shows that, for any fixed experimentation probability, the price adjustment dynamics is stochastically stable. That is, starting from any arbitrary initial distribution, the dynamics eventually settles down to the same limiting distribution given by the unique invariant distribution. However, instead of deriving the limiting distribution explicitly, this paper derives the limit of the limiting distributions as the experimentation probability goes to zero. This limit is viewed as an approximation of the limiting distribution when the experimentation probability is small. Subsection 3.2 shows that as the experimentation probability goes to zero, the limiting distribution becomes concentrated around the states corresponding to the Walrasian equilibrium price vector. 3.1 Existence of the Limiting Distribution Theorem 3.2 below shows that for each ε > 0, the Markov chain ξ ε corresponding to the price adjustment dynamics has a limiting distribution and gives an upper bound on the rate of convergence. Although establishing the existence of a limiting distribution in general state space models is often delicate, the existence can be readily shown in models with persistent randomness by appealing to a special case of Doeblin s Theorem. 7 In the following, let X n and BX) be the Borel σ-field of X. Let ζ be a Markov chain on state space X. For any A BX) and x X, P m x A) denotes the m-step transition probability Probζ t+m A ζ t = x) and P x A) denotes P 1 x A). Theorem 3.1 Doeblin). Let ζ be a Markov chain on state space X. Suppose there exist m > 0 and a non-trivial measure ν m on BX) such that P m x A) ν m A) for all 7 For further discussion of Doeblin s condition and the uniform ergodicity of general state space chains, see Theorems and , and the related discussion in Meyn and Tweedie [6]. 10

11 x X and A BX). Then the unique invariant measure λ for ζ exists. Moreover, sup x P t x ) λ ) 1 ν m X)) t m. Theorem 3.2. Fix any Z ++ and ε 0, 1). Then the unique invariant measure π ε for the chain ξ ε on Ξ exists. Moreover, there exists a constant ρ ε < 1 such that sup ξ P t ξ ) πε ) ρ t ε. Proof. Let m > 1 + 2ˆδ. Let µ be the produce measure r=1 µ L on, and let µ 0 be the measure on {, {1}, {2}, {1, 2}} such that µ 0 {1}) = µ 0 {2}) = ) ) 1 m m ˆδε. 2 2 Let µ be the product measure µ 0 µ on BΞ ). Consider any A BΞ ). Let A 1 = {p 1,..., p ) : 1, p 1,..., p ) A} and A 2 = {p 1,..., p ) : 2, p 1,..., p ) A} so that {1} A 1 ) {2} A 2 ) = A and {1} A 1 ) {2} A 2 ) =. For all ξ Ξ, Pξ m A) = P ξ m {1} A 1) + Pξ m {2} A 2) ) ) 1 m m ) ) ˆδε 1 m m ˆδε µ A 1 ) + µ A 2 ) = µa). Since µ is non-trivial by construction, the conclusion follows from Theorem 3.1 with ρ ε = 1 µξ )) 1 m. As the above argument makes clear, the existence of a limiting distribution for the chain ξ ε is not a deep result. As in finite state space evolutionary models with persistent randomness, it is essentially the consequence of the irreducibility generated by allowing random experimentation. The more interesting result is the characterization of the limiting distribution, which is given next. 11

12 3.2 Characterization of the Limiting Distribution Since finding the exact expression for the limiting distribution π ε is difficult, this paper characterizes π ε by deriving the limit of π ε as ε 0. Meyn and Tweedie [6] gives a useful characterization of an invariant measure that simplifies this derivation. A simple version of their theorem is stated below as Theorem In the theorem and elsewhere, given chain ζ on X and A BX), let τ A = inf {t 1 : ζ t A} denote the hitting time of the set A. Theorem 3.3 Meyn and Tweedie). Under the assumptions of Theorem 3.1, the unique invariant measure λ for ζ satisfies the following. For any B BX) such that λb) > 0 and A BX), λa) = B λdx)e x [ τb t=1 1 {ζt A} ]. Meyn and Tweedie s theorem states that for any fixed set B of positive measure, the measure λ places on A is determined by how often the chain visits A before returning to B. Lemma 3.4 and Theorem 3.5 below exploit this return time characterization. Following Vega-edondo [8], let the states in which all the replicas set the same prices be called monomorphic states. Consider the expected number of times the price adjustment dynamics, starting from a monomorphic state, will visit non-monomorphic states before returning to the set of monomorphic states. Consider also the expected number of times the dynamics, starting now from a nonmonomorphic state, will visit monomorphic states before returning to the set of non-monomorphic states. When the experimentation probability is small, the probability of replicas taking an imitation step is greater than the probability of replicas 8 For the statement of this theorem in its full generality, see Theorem of Meyn and Tweedie [6]. In particular, Theorem only requires ζ to be recurrent, which is weaker than the hypothesis stated in Theorem 3.3. Furthermore, Theorem requires B to satisfy ψb) > 0, where ψ is the maximal irreducibility measure for ζ. However, since ψ and λ are equivalent measures, this simpler statement of the theorem is used. 12

13 taking a random experimentation step. Since imitation steps lead to a monomorphic state, the expected number of visits to monomorphic states is greater than the expected number of visits to non-monomorphic states. Therefore, according to the return time characterization, the limiting distribution π ε puts greater measure on the set of monomorphic states. In the limit, as the experimentation probability goes to zero, full measure is placed on the set of monomorphic states. This is formally stated and shown as Lemma 3.4 below. In the remainder of the paper, superscripts denoting are suppressed to reduce clutter in the notation whenever their suppression does not affect the clarity of the meaning. Lemma 3.4. Fix any Z ++. Let ˆΞ = {i, p,..., p) : i I and p }. Then for all ε 0, 1), π ε ˆΞ) > 0. Moreover, π ε ˆΞ) 1 as ε 0. Proof. Fix any ε 0, 1). Since π ε Ξ) > 0 and τ Ξ = 1 P ξ -a.s. for all ξ Ξ, π ε ˆΞ) = Ξ P ξ ˆΞ)π ε dξ) = P ξ ˆΞ)π ε dξ) + P ξ ˆΞ)π ε dξ) ˆΞ Ξ\ˆΞ by Theorem 3.3. Since for all ξ ˆΞ, P ξ ˆΞ) 1 ε) and for all ξ Ξ\ˆΞ, P ξ ˆΞ) ε), π ε ˆΞ) 1 ε) π ε 1 dξ) + ˆΞ Ξ\ˆΞ 2 1 ε) π ε dξ) = 1 ε) π ε ˆΞ) ε) π ε Ξ\ˆΞ) > 0. Moreover, the above inequality yields π ε ˆΞ) 1 ε) π ε ˆΞ) ε) π ε Ξ\ˆΞ). Since π ε ˆΞ) 1 as ε 0. π ε ˆΞ) 1 π ε ˆΞ) = πε 1 ˆΞ) π ε Ξ\ˆΞ) 2 1 ε) as ε 0, 1 1 ε) The two lemmas in the Appendix, Lemma A.6 and Lemma A.10, show that the 13

14 price adjustment dynamics favors adjustment in the direction of the excess demand for all economies with sufficiently large number of replicas. As a result, for any small neighborhood of the equilibrium price vector, the maximum number of experimentation steps needed to transition from the states outside the neighborhood into the neighborhood is smaller than the minimum number of experimentation steps needed to transition from the states inside the neighborhood to the outside. Therefore, the return time characterization yields that, as the experimentation probability goes to zero, the limiting distribution becomes concentrated around the monomorphic states corresponding to the equilibrium price vector. This is formally stated and shown below as Theorem 3.5. In the following, let N δ) = N p, δ) denote the δ-neighborhood of p. Theorem 3.5. Fix N δ) and assume ˆδ < δ. There exists such that for all > the following holds. Let π ε be the limiting distribution of ξ ε on Ξ and let A = {i, p,..., p) : i I and p N δ)}. Then π ε A) 1 as ε 0, Proof. Let B = ˆΞ\A. If B =, then the theorem follows from Lemma 3.4. So, assume B. Take N and 1 from Lemma A.9 and 2 from Lemma A.10. Let = max { 1, 2 } and fix >. Take any ε 0, 1 2). Since π ε ˆΞ) > 0, Theorem 3.3 yields π ε A) = = P ξ ξ ε A)π ε dξ) τˆξ ˆΞ P ξ ξ ε A)π ε dξ) + τˆξ A B P ξ ξ ε τˆξ A)π ε dξ). By Lemma A.9, for all ξ B, P ξ ξ ε τˆξ A) Kε N, where K > 0 is a constant. 14

15 For all ξ A, P ξ ˆΞ \ A) = 0. Then by Lemma A.10, for all ξ A, P ξ ξ ε A) P τˆξ ξ A) + Prob ξt+2 ε A, ξt+1 ε ˆΞ ) ξt ε = ξ εn+1 ) 1 ε N+1. Therefore, π ε A) 1 ε N+1 ) π ε dξ) + Kε N π ε dξ) A B = 1 ε N+1) π ε A) + Kε N π ε B). Since π ε A) 1 π ε A) = πε A) π ε B) KεN as ε 0, εn+1 π ε A) 1 as ε 0. 4 Concluding emarks The decentralized price adjustment model presented in this paper resolves some of the difficulties in interpreting tâtonnement dynamics. First, the model specifies outof-equilibrium trading so that a fictional time scale in which prices adjust without trade is not needed. Second, the price adjustment rule is decentralized and endogenous so that the model does not require an exogenous agent whose motivation for adjusting prices is unmodeled. These results, however, are derived in the restrictive setting of 2 2 replica economy, and to what extent the results can be generalized is an open question. 15

16 A Appendix By supporting price for i at ω i, we mean a price vector at which type i will demand exactly ω i when her endowment is ω i. Let p i denote the supporting price for i at her initial endowment ω i so that x i p i, ω i ) = ω i. Let T = {λ p i + 1 λ) p j : λ [0, 1]} be the set of prices that are convex combinations of p i and p j. For any set A, let A denote the relative interior of A. Since x i p j, ω i ) i ω i = x i p i, ω i ), type i prefers p j over p i when her endowment is ω i. The following lemma shows that more generally, given any two prices in T, type i prefers the price that is closer to p j. Lemma A.1. Take any p = λ p j + 1 λ ) p i and p = λ p j + 1 λ) p i, where 1 > λ > λ > 0. Then x i p, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ). Proof. Since x i p, ω i ) i ω i = x i p i, ω i ), p i z i p, ω i ) > 0 by the weak axiom of revealed preference. This implies p j z i p, ω i ) = 1 λ p 1 λ) p i) z i p, ω i ) ) 1 λ = p i z i p, ω i ) λ < 0. Letting η = λ λ > 0, we have p z i p, ω i ) = λ p j + 1 λ ) ) p i zi p, ω i ) = λ + η) p j + 1 λ η) p i ) z i p, ω i ) = [η p j η p i ) + λ p j + 1 λ) p i )] z i p, ω i ) = η p j z i p, ω i ) η p i z i p, ω i ) + p z i p, ω i ) < 0. Therefore, x i p, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ). Let T i = {λ p j + 1 λ)p : λ [0, 1]} be the set of prices that are convex com- 16

17 bination of the equilibrium price and the supporting price for j at her initial endowment. Since p z i p, ω i ) = 0 = p z j p, ω j ) by Walras Law, z i p, ω i ) and z j p, ω j ) are always colinear. Lemma A.2 below shows that, in addition, if p T i, then the excess demand vectors of the two types are in the opposite direction, with the magnitude of i s excess demand exceeding that that of j s. However, if p T then the excess demand vectors are in the same direction. Since p T, T = T i T j. Therefore, an immediate consequence of this lemma is that a trade will occur at the initial endowment allocation and price p if and only p T. Lemma A.2. For all p \{ p i }, there exists β such that z j p, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ). Furthermore, if p T i then β 1, 0), and if p T then β > 0. Proof. If p = p j, z j p, ω j ) = 0 = βz i p, ω i ) with β = 0. If p \ { p j, p i }, then z j p, ω j ) 0 z i p, ω i ). Moreover, p z j p, ω j ) = 0 = p z i p, ω i ) by Walras Law. Therefore, z 1 j p, ω j) z 2 j p, ω j) = p 2 p 1 = z1 i p, ω j) z 2 j p, ω j). So, for any p \ { p i }, there exists β such that z j p, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ). Suppose p T i. Then there exists λ 0, 1) such that p = λ p j + 1 λ)p. p j z i p, ω i ) = 1 λ p 1 λ)p ) z i p, ω i ) ) 1 λ = p z i p, ω i ) λ < 0 since x i p, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ) by Lemma A.1. But, β [ p j z i p, ω i )] = p j z j p, ω j ) > 0 since x j p, ω j ) j ω j = x j p j, ω j ). Therefore, β < 0. Next, z i p j, ω i ) > 0 = z j p j, ω j ) while z i p, ω i ) = z j p, ω j ). Since the excess demand functions are continuous functions of prices and the equilibrium is unique, z i p, ω i ) > z j p, ω j ) for all p = λ p j + 1 λ)p. Therefore, β < 1 as claimed. Now, suppose p T. Then either p i = λp + 1 λ) p j for some λ 0, 1), or 17

18 p j = λp + 1 λ) p i for some λ 0, 1). Assume p i = λp + 1 λ) p j for some λ 0, 1). Then p i z j p, ω j ) = λp + 1 λ) p j ) z j p, ω j ) = 1 λ) p j z j p, ω j ) > 0 since x j p, ω j ) j ω j = x j p j, ω j ). Also, p i z i p, ω i ) > 0 since x i p, ω i ) i ω i = x i p i, ω i ). Therefore, β > 0. Lastly, the case where p j = λp + 1 λ) p i for some λ 0, 1) is similar. Using the above two lemmas, we can now show that it takes only one experimentation to successfully transition away from a monomorphic state if the replicas are setting a price p in \ T. In particular, consider a monomorphic state i, p,..., p). Lemma A.3 below shows that if p T, then for some appropriate k I, p Bk, p, p,..., p). This implies that it takes only a single experimentation step to transition from i, p,..., p) to k, p,..., p ) via k, p, p,...p). Lemma A.3. Fix any replica population size Z ++. For all p \ T and p, there exists ξ = k, p, p,...p) Ξ such that p Bξ). Proof. Since p T, either p i = λp + 1 λ) p j for some λ 0, 1], or p j = λp + 1 λ) p i for some λ 0, 1]. Without loss of generality, assume p i = λp + 1 λ) p j for some λ 0, 1]. First, suppose p T so that p = λ p i + 1 λ ) p j for some λ 0, 1). Then p = λ λp + 1 λ) p j ) + 1 λ ) p j = λ λp + 1 λ λ) p j. So, p z j p, ω j ) = 1 λ λ p 1 λ λ) p j ) z j p, ω j ) 1 λ ) λ = λ p j z j p, ω j ) λ < 0 since x j p, ω j ) j ω j = x j p j, ω j ). 18

19 Therefore, x j p, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ). Let ξ = i, p, p,..., p) Ξ. Since x j p, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ), j-replicas will want to trade first with i-replicas setting price p. That is, Φ 1 = {2, 3, 4..., }, with each replica ir, r Φ 1, receiving a total trade order of 1 z jp, ω j ). However, since the desired trades of the two types are in the opposite direction, no actual trade will occur in the first stage. To see this, note that since x i p, ω i ) i ω i = x i p i, ω i ), p i z i p, ω i ) 0. Using Lemma A.2, we obtain p i ω i α ) 1 z jp, ω j ) = p i ω i αβ ) 1 z ip, ω i ) p i ω i for all α [0, 1]. for some β 0 Meaning, ω i i ω i α 1 z jp, ω j ) for all α [0, 1]. Therefore, α 1 = arg max u i ω i α ) 1 z jp, ω j ) = 0 so that ω ir = ω i for all r Φ 1 and ω 2 jr = ω j for all r. In the second stage, we have j-replicas wanting to trade with replica i1. Since p is assumed to be in T, some trade will actually occur, leaving i1 better off than replicas ir, r Φ 1. To see this, note that Lemma A.2 yields α 2 = arg max u i ωi αz j p, ω j ) ) = arg max u i ωi + αβz i p, ω j ) ) for some β > 0 { } = min 1 β, 1 by continuity of u i ). Since a 2 > 0, we have ω i1 = ω i + α 2 βz i p, ω j ) i ω i = ω ir r 1. Therefore, Bi, p, p,..., p) = {p }. Second, suppose p T. Then similar argument to above yields that no actual trade will occur under p or p. Therefore, ω ir = ω i for all r, and Bi, p, p,..., p) = {p, p}. 19

20 For each p T i and the size of the replica population,, let f i p, ) be the supporting price for i at ω i 1 z jp, ω j ). That is, define f i : T i Z ++ by x i f i p, ), ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = ω i 1 z jp, ω j ). To see the relevance of f i p, ), consider a state ξ in which 1 many j-replicas have set price p while a single j-replica has set price p, where x i p, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ). If p Ti, then trade will occur since the excess demands of the two types are in the opposite direction. In fact, as shown below in the proof of Lemma A.6, the result of the first round trade for type i will be ωi 1 = ω i 1 z jp, ω j ). Thus, f i p, ) is the price that supports i s endowment after the first round of trading. Now, let T i p, ) be the set of convex combination of p and 1 2 p f ip, ) that are also in T i. That is, define T i : T i Z ++ 2 by { 1 T i p, ) = T i λp + 1 λ) 2 p + 1 ) } 2 f ip, ) : λ [0, 1] = T i { λp + 1 λ) f i p, ) : λ [ 1 2, 1]}. The proof of Lemma A.6 also shows that if p T then f i p, ) p so that the relative interior of { λp + 1 λ) 1 2 p f ip, ) ) : λ [0, 1] } is not empty, which then implies that Ti p, ). Moreover, since T ip, ) T i, if p Ti p, ), trade will occur at p when each type s endowment is its initial endowment. Lemma A.4 below goes one step further and shows the excess demands of the two types are in the opposite direction even when type i has endowment ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) and type j has endowment ω j. Therefore, trade will also occur in the second round in state ξ if p Ti p, ). Lemma A.4. For all p Ti, Z ++, and p Ti p, ), there exists β > 0 such that z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = βz j p, ω j ). Proof. Since p z i p, ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) ) = 0 = p z j p, ω j ), there exists β 20

21 such that z i p, ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) ) = βz j p, ω j ). In the following, we show that β > 0. First, x i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) i ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) = x i f i p, ), ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) Since p = λp + 1 λ)f i p, ) for some λ 1 2, 1), p z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = 1 p 1 λ)f i p, ) ) z i p, ω i 1 ) λ z jp, ω j ) ) 1 λ = f i p, ) z i p, ω i 1 ) λ z jp, ω j ) < 0 by the weak axiom. Second, p Ti ; so, by Lemma A.2, there exists γ 0, 1) such that ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) = ω i + 1 γz ip, ω i ) = 1 1 ) ) 1 γ ω i + γ x i p, ω i ). Since p ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) ) = p ω i, x i p, ω i ) i ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) = x i f i p, ), ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ). Appealing to the weak axiom again, we obtain 0 < f i p, ) x i p, ω i ) = f i p, ) x i p, ω i ) = 1 1 γ ω i 1 )) z jp, ω j ) 1 1 ) 1 γ ω i ) f i p, ) z i p, ω i ). ) ) γ x i p, ω i ) 21

22 By Lemma A.2, there is β 0, 1) such that p z j p, ω j ) = p β )z i p, ω i ) = 1 p 1 λ)f i p, ) ) β )z i p, ω i ) λ ) 1 λ = λ β f i p, ) z i p, ω i ) > 0. Since p z i p, ω i 1 z jp, ω j ) ) < 0 while p z j p, ω j ) > 0, we have β > 0 as desired. Lemma A.5. Fix any N δ). Then there exists 1 such that for all > 1, the following holds. For any p T i \ N δ) and p T i p, ) \ {p}, let α = arg max u j ω j αz i p, ω i 1 )) z jp, ω j ). Then ω j α z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = x j p, ω j ). Proof. Suppose p T i \ N δ) and p T i p, ) \ {p}. By Lemma A.4, there exists β > 0 such that z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = βz j p, ω j ). Then ω j αz i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) = ω j + αβz j p, ω j ). Therefore, arg max u j ω j αz i p, ω i 1 )) { } 1 z jp, ω j ) = min β, 1. It remains to show that β 1 for all sufficiently large. 22

23 Price vector f i p, ) was defined earlier as the supporting price for i at ω i 1 z jp, ω j ). Similarly, let f i p) be the supporting price for i at ω i z j p, ω j ). That is, let f i : T i be defined by x i fi p), ω i z j p, ω j ) ) = ω i z j p, ω j ). Also, analogously to T i p, ), define T i : T i 2 by T i p) = T i { λp + 1 λ) 1 2 p f i p) ) : λ [0, 1] } = T i { λp + 1 λ) f i p) : λ [ 1 2, 1]}. Since f i p) = p if and only if p = p, T i p) for all p T i \ {p }. For each p T i \ N δ), let h i p) = min p T i p) zi p, ω i z j p, ω j ) ). Since p p and f i p) T i p) by construction, z i p, ω i z j p, ω j )) > 0 for all p T i p). Since z i, ω i z j p, ω j )) is continuous and T i p) is compact, h i p) > 0. Moreover, h i ) is itself continuous by the theorem of the maximum; therefore, we have h i min p T i \N δ) h i p) > 0. Next, for each p T i \ N δ) and Z ++, let h i p, ) = min p T i p,) z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ). Since h i, ) is continuous and strictly positive on T i \ N δ), we have h i ) min h ip, ) > 0. p T i \N δ) Moreover, h i ) h i > 0 as. So, there exists i and η i > 0 such that for 23

24 all > i, h i ) > η i. Let ζ j = max p T z j p, ω j ). Then ζ j 0, ). Now, let 1 > max and fix any > 1. Since { } 1, 2, ζ 1 η 2, ζ 2 η 1 βζ j βz j p, ω j ) = z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ) η i, ) ) β η i ζj ζ j. Therefore, β ηi η i ζ j = 1, and α = arg max u j ω j αz i p, ω i 1 )) z jp, ω j ) = 1 β as desired. Lemma A.6. Fix any N δ). Then there exists 1 such that for all > 1, the following holds. Suppose ξ = j, p, p,..., p) Ξ is such that p T i \ N δ) and p T i p, ). Then p Bξ). Proof. Let 1 be as in Lemma A.5 and fix > 1. Consider any ξ = j, p, p,..., p) satisfying the hypothesis. If p = p j or p = p, then there is nothing to prove. So, assume p p j and p T i p, ) \ {p}. Then there exists λ 0, 1) such that p = λp + 1 λ) p j. In addition, since p T i \ { p j }, there exists β > 0 such that z i p, ω i ) = β z j p, ω j ) by Lemma A.2. Thus, p z i p, ω i ) = β λp + 1 λ) p j ) z j p, ω j ) = β 1 λ) p j z j p, ω j ) < 0. Therefore, x i p, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ), and Φ 1 = {2, 3, 4,..., }. 24

25 Since p T i, there exists β 0, 1) such that z jp, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ). Thus, arg max u j ω j α ) 1 z ip, ω i ) = arg max = β 1). ) u j ω j + α β 1) z jp, ω j ) Therefore, ω jr = x j p, ω j ) for all r Φ 1, and ω 2 i = ω i + β 1) z i p, ω i ) = ω i 1 z jp, ω j ). Since Φ 2 = {1}, ω j1 = ω j α 2 z i p, ω i 1 ) z jp, ω j ), where α 2 = arg max u j ω j αz i p, ω i 1 )) z jp, ω j ). Thus, ω j1 = x j p, ω j ) by Lemma A.5. Since x j p, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ) by Lemma A.1, p Bξ). The next two lemmas relate our price adjustment dynamics to the tâtonement dynamics. The first lemma, Lemma A.7 shows that if p T i and q p is in T i p, ), then q can be obtained from p by moving in the direction of the excess demand function, zp, ω i, ω j ). The second lemma, Lemma A.8 shows that, given two price vectors that are obtained from some p by moving in the direction opposite to type i s excess demand, z i p, ω i ), type i would prefer the price vector that is further away from p. Lemma A.7. For all p = p 1, p 2 ) Ti, Z ++, and q = q 1, q 2 ) Ti p, ), there exists γ > 0 such that q 1 q 2 = p1 p 2 + γz1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ). Proof. Since p Ti, Lemma A.2 implies that there exists β 0, 1) such that 25

26 z j p, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ). Therefore, q 1 z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) + q 2 z 2 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) = q zp, ω 1, ω 2 ) = λp + 1 λ)f i p, )) z i p, ω i ) + z j p, ω j )) = 1 λ)1 β)f i p, ) z i p, ω i ) > 0 as shown in the proof of Lemma A.4 while p 1 z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) + p 2 z 2 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) = p zp, ω 1, ω 2 ) = 0. Therefore, q 1 q 2 z1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) > p1 p 2 z1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ). So, whether z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) > 0 or z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) < 0, there exists γ > 0 such that q 1 q 2 = p1 p 2 + γz1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ). Lemma A.8. Fix any p = p 1, p 2 ) and ω i ++. Suppose p 1 = p 1 1, p2 1 ), p 2 = p 1 2, p2 2 ) are such that p 1 1 p 2 1 = p1 p 2 γ 1z 1 i p, ω i ) and p 1 2 p 2 2 = p1 p 2 γ 2z 1 i p, ω i ) for some γ 2 > γ 1 > 0. Then x i p 2, ω i ) i x i p 1, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ). Proof. Using p z i p, ω i ) = 0, we obtain p 1 1 p 2 1 z 1 i p, ω i ) + z 2 i p, ω i ) = ) p 1 p 2 γ 1zi 1 p, ω i ) zi 1 p, ω i ) + zi 2 p, ω i ) = γ 1 zi 1 p, ω i )zi 1 p, ω i ) < 0. 26

27 Thus, p 1 z i p, ω i ) < 0, which implies x i p 1, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ). Next, p 1 z i p, ω i ) < 0 also implies p z i p 1, ω i ) > 0 by the weak axiom. So, p 1 p 2 z1 i p 1, ω i ) + zi 2 p 1, ω i ) > 0 = p1 1 zi 1 p 1, ω i ) + zi 2 p 1, ω i ). p 2 1 Subtracting yields 0 < ) p 1 p 2 p1 1 p 2 zi 1 p 1, ω i ) = γ 1 zi 1 p, ω i )zi 1 p 1, ω i ). 1 Since γ 1 > 0, this means that z 1 i p, ω i)z 1 i p 1, ω i ) > 0. p 1 2 p 2 2 z 1 i p 1, ω i ) + z 2 i p 1, ω i ) = = = ) p 1 p 2 γ 2zi 1 p, ω i ) zi 1 p 1, ω i ) + zi 2 p 1, ω i ) ) p 1 p 2 γ 1 + γ 2 γ 1 ))zi 1 p, ω i ) zi 1 p 1, ω i ) + zi 2 p 1, ω i ) ) p 1 1 γ 2 γ 1 )zi 1 p, ω i ) zi 1 p 1, ω i ) + zi 2 p 1, ω i ) p 2 1 = γ 2 γ 1 )zi 1 p, ω i )zi 1 p 1, ω i ) < 0 by above. Therefore, p 2 z i p 1, ω i ) < 0, which implies x i p 2, ω i ) i x i p 1, ω i ). Lemma A.9. Fix any N δ). Assume ε 0, 1 2) and δ < δ. Then there exist N and 1 Z ++ such that for all > 1 the following holds. Let A = { k, p,..., p ) Ξ : k I and p N δ) }. For any ξ Ξ \ A, P ξ ξ ε τ Ξ A) KεN, where K > 0 is a constant that does not depend on ξ. Proof. Fix any N δ), where δ > δ, and let 1 satisfy Lemma A.6. For each i I, p T i, and Z ++, define ḡ i p, ) and ḡ i p) by T i p, ) N p, δ) = {λp + 1 λ)ḡ i p, ) : λ 0, 1)}, and T i p) N p, δ) = {λp + 1 λ)ḡ i p) : λ 0, 1)}. 27

28 Let d i ) = min p T i \N δ) 1 p 2 p + 1 )) 2ḡip, > 0, and choose d i such that 0 < d i < min p T i \N δ) 1 p 2 p ḡip)) Then there exists 2 such that for all > 2, d i ) > d i. Let 1 > max { 1, 2 } and fix > { 1. Let N > max p1 p, d p 2 p }. For all i I, let 2 d 1 S i p, ) = { 1 λḡ i p, ) + 1 λ) 2 p + 1 ) } 2ḡip, ) : λ [0, 1], and µ = min p T i \N δ) µ L S i p, )) > 0. Now, take any ξ = k, p,..., p) Ξ, where k I and p T i \ N δ). Consider any sequence of prices p 1, p 2,..., p N with p 1 = p and p n+1 S i p n, ) for all n. Since S i p n, ) T i p n, ) for all n, there exists γ n > 0 such that p 1 n+1 p 2 n+1 = p1 n p 2 + γ n z 1 p n, ω 1, ω 2 ) n by Lemma A.7. Since tâtonnement dynamics is globally stable in the underlying economy, p n+1 p < p n p for all n. Moreover, p n+1 p n > d i for all p n N δ). Therefore, there exists m N such that p m N δ) and p n N δ) for all n < m. For any n < m, p n+1 Bi, p n+1, p n,..., p n )) by Lemma A.6. Consequently, Prob ξ ε t+1 { i, p, p n+1,..., p n+1 ) : p S i p n+1, ) } ξ ε t = i, p n+1, p n,..., p n ) ) 1 2 µε1 ε) 1 ) 1 µε. 2 28

29 Therefore, there exists a constant K > 0 that does not depend on ξ such that P ξ τ Ξ A ξ t = ξ ) Kε N. Lastly, suppose ξ = k, p,..., p) Ξ, where k I and p T. Then the result follows readily from the above argument and Lemma A.3. Lemma A.10. Fix any N δ) T and N Z ++. Assume δ < δ. There exists 2 such that for all > 2, the following holds. Suppose ξ = i, p 1, p 2,..., p N, p,..., p) Ξ is such that p N δ) and p r N p, δ) \ {p} for each r = 1,..., N. Then p r Bξ) for any p r such that p r N δ). Proof. Let p i T j For each j I, let and p j T i be such that N δ) = {λ p i + 1 λ) p j : λ 0, 1)}. β j = inf p T i N δ) z j p, ω i ) z i p, ω j ) and β j = sup p T j N p i, δ) z i p, ω i ) z j p, ω j ). Then β j 0, 1) and β j 0, 1). Let β j 1, 1 β j ). Since x j p j, ω j ) j ω j for all j, there exists δ > 0 such that, for each j I, W j = {ω j : ω j ω j < δ and p j ω j p j ω j } has the following property. For any ω j, ω j W j and p, p {λ p i + 1 λ) p j : λ [0, 1]}, if x j p, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ), then x j p, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ). Moreover, by choosing δ small enough, W j can be made such that for all p T and ω j W j, z j p, ω j ) = ηz j p, ω j ) for some η β j, β i ). For each j I, let ζ j = max { 1, sup p T, ω j W j z j p, ω j ) } <. Let and fix >. > max { ζ1 N 2 δ β 1, β 1, ζ 2 N 2 δ β 2, β 2, N 1 β 1 β 1, N 1 β 2 β 2 } 29

30 Since there is nothing to prove if p N p i, δ) N p j, δ)), assume p N p i, δ) N p j, δ)) and p 1,..., p N N p, δ) \ {p}. Let s = {p r {p 1,..., p } : x j p r, ω j ) j x j p, ω j )}. Let Ψ 0 = and Φ 0 =. For each s = 1,..., s, define Ψ s and Φ s inductively as follows. Let Ψ s = Ψ s 1 \ Φ s 1. Let p {p r : r Ψ s } be such that x j p, ω j ) j x j p r, ω j ) for all r Ψ s, and let Φ s = {r Ψ s : p r = p }. In particular, Φ s+1 = {N + 1,..., }. Case 1: Suppose p N p i, δ). By Lemma A.2, z j p, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ) for some β > 1. Consider any p r such that p1 r p 2 r Since p 1 r p 2 r = p1 p 2 γ rβ 1)z 1 i p, ω i ), = p1 p 2 + γ r z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) for some γ r > 0. x i p r, ω i ) i x i p, ω i ) by Lemma A.8. Then p z j p r, ω j ) = βp z i p r, ω i ) < 0, and, therefore, x j p, ω j ) j x j p r, ω j ). Next, consider any p r such that p1 r p 2 r γ r z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) for some γ r > 0. Since = p1 p 2 p 1 r p 2 r = p1 p 2 γ r 1 1 ) zj 1 p, ω j ), β x j p r, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ) by Lemma A.8. Therefore, x j p r, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ) if and only if p1 r p 2 r = p1 p 2 γ r z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) for some γ r > 0. In particular, since tâtonnement dynamics is globally stable in the underlying economy, x j p r, ω j ) j p r N δ). x j p, ω j ) if Now, note that Ψ 1 = Ψ 1 and ω 1 j = ω j W j. Suppose for each stage s s, Ψ s = Ψ s and ω s j W j. Then Φ s = Φ s, and Φ s N. Consider any r Φ s. If 30

31 p r T, then a s = 0. If p r T, then p r Tj since δ < δ. So, α s = arg max = arg max = arg max = Φs β η u i ω i α ) Φ s z jp r, ωj s ) u i ω i α η ) Φ s z jp r, ω j ) ) u i ω i + α β η Φ s z ip r, ω i ) for some η > β j for some β > 1 > β j since Φ s β η N β j β j β j β j N ) = ζ j N 2 δ β j, β j δ ζ j N < 1. Therefore, ω s+1 j ωj s δ ζ j N z jp r, ωj s ) δ N. So, in either case, ω s+1 j W j. In addition, since Ψ s = Ψ s and Φ s = Φ s, Ψ s+1 = Ψ s+1. Therefore, by induction, Ψ s = Ψ s, Φ s = Φ s, and ω s j W j for all s = 1,..., s+1. In particular, Φ s+1 = {N + 1,..., }. Take any r Φ s, where s s. Since x j p r, ω s j ) j x j p, ω s j ), p z jp r, ω s j ) > 0. Therefore, p ω i α s z j p r, ω s j ) ) p ω i. Thus, x i p, ω i ) i ω ir for all r Φ s. On the other hand, α s+1 = arg max = arg max = arg max = N βη u i ω i α ) N z jp, ω s+1 j ) u i ω i α η ) N z jp, ω j ) for some η > β j u i ω i + α βη ) N z ip, ω i ), where 1 β β j 31

32 since N βη β j N) β j N) η β j < 1. So, ω ir = x i p, ω i ) for all r Φ s+1. Therefore, for all p r such that p r N δ), p r Bξ). Case 2: Suppose p N p j, δ). By Lemma A.2, z j p, ω j ) = βz i p, ω i ) for some β < 1. By similar reasoning as in Case 1, x j p r, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ) if and only if p1 r p 2 r = p1 p 2 + γ r z 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) for some γ r > 0. In particular, by the stability of the tâtonnement dynamics, if x j p r, ω j ) j x j p, ω j ), then p r N δ), and, therefore, z j p r, ω j ) = β z i p r, ω i ) for some β > β j. Thus, by similar reasoning as in Case 1, Ψ s = Ψ s, Φ s = Φ s, and ω s j W j for all s = 1,..., s + 1. In particular, Φ s+1 = {N + 1,..., }. α s+1 = arg max = arg max = arg max = 1 u i ω i α ) N z jp, ω s+1 j ) u i ω i α η ) N z jp, ω j ) for some η < β i u i ω i + α βη ) N z ip, ω i ), where β < β i since > N 1 β i β i > N 1 βη. Therefore, ω s+2 j = x j p, ω s+1 j ) and ω ir i ω i for all r Φ s+1. Now, consider any r Φ s+2. p r z j p r, ω s+2 j ) = 0 = p r z i p r, ω i ). Since x j p r, ω s+2 j ) ω s+2 j j = x j p, ω s+2 j ), 32

33 p z j p r, ω s+2 j ) > 0. On the other hand, since p 1 r p 2 r = p1 p 2 γ rz 1 p, ω 1, ω 2 ) = p1 p 2 γ r1 β)z 1 i p, ω i ), p r z i p, ω i ) < 0 by Lemma A.8. Therefore, p z i p r, ω i ) > 0. Therefore, there exists β > 0 such that z j p r, ω s+2 j ) = β z i p r, ω i ). So, for any K > 0, arg max ) u i ω i αkz j p r, ω s+2 j ) = 0. An induction argument yields that for all r Φ s, where s s + 2, ω ir = ω i. Therefore, for all p r such that p r N δ), p r Bξ). 33

34 eferences [1] Crockett, S., S. Spear, and S. Sunder. 2004). A Simple Decentralized Institution for Learning Competitive Equilibrium. Discussion Paper. [2] Foster, D. and P. Young. 1990). Stochastic Evolutionary Game Dynamics. Theoretical Population Biology, 38: [3] Hahn, F. 1982). Stability. Chap. 16 in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. II, edited by K. Arrow and M. Intriligator. Amsterdam: North-Holland. [4] Kandori, M., G. Mailath, and. ob. 1993). Learning to Play Equilibria in Games with Stochastic Perturbations. Econometrica, 61: [5] Keisler, H. Jerome. 1996). Getting to a Competitive Equilibrium. Econometrica, 64: [6] Meyn, S. and. Tweedie. 1996). Markov Chains and Stochastic Stability. NY: Springer. [7] Temzelides, T. 2001). A Note on Learning to Bid Walrasian in 2 2 Market Games. Discussion Paper. [8] Vega-edondo, F. 1997). The Evolution of Walrasian Behavior. Econometrica, 65: [9] Walras, L. 1874). Elements d Economie Politique Pure. Lausanne: Corbaz. [Translated as: Elements of Pure Economics. Homewood, IL: Irwin, 1954.] [10] Young, P. 1993). The Evolution of Conventions. Econometrica, 61:

Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica Economies

Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica Economies Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica Economies Maxwell Pak Queen s University August 2005 This version: March 2006 Abstract This paper presents a model of price adjustment in replica economies

More information

Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica. Economies

Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 Replica. Economies Decentralized Price Adjustment in 2 2 eplica Economies Maxwell Pak Queen s University December 2009 Abstract This paper presents a model of price adjustment in replica economies with two consumer types

More information

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Abstract: This paper gives a non-fixed point theoretic proof of equilibrium existence when the excess demand function of an exchange

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 21, November 14 Outline 1 Uniquenness (in pictures) 2 Stability 3 Gross Substitute Property Uniqueness and Stability We have dealt

More information

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata General Equilibrium Equilibrium in Consumption GE begins (1/3) 2-Individual/ 2-good Exchange economy (No production, no transaction costs, full information..) Endowment (Nature): e Private property/ NO

More information

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of Economics 201B Second Half Lecture 12-4/22/10 Justifying (or Undermining) the Price-Taking Assumption Many formulations: Core, Ostroy s No Surplus Condition, Bargaining Set, Shapley-Shubik Market Games

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 19, November 7 Outline 1 Welfare Theorems in the differentiable case. 2 Aggregate excess

More information

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions Chapter 1 Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions 1.1 Arrow-Debreu model of an economy via Walras equilibrium problem. Let us consider first the so-called Arrow-Debreu model. The presentation

More information

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Emir Kamenica and Matthew Gentzkow University of Chicago June 2010 1 Persuasion mechanisms In this paper we study a particular game where Sender chooses a signal π whose

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo January 29, 2012 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ). University of California, Davis Date: August 24, 2017 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer any three

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium. Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis

Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium. Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis June 1, 2012 1 Introduction The stability of Walrasian general equilibrium was widely studied in the years immediately following

More information

Lecture 6: Communication Complexity of Auctions

Lecture 6: Communication Complexity of Auctions Algorithmic Game Theory October 13, 2008 Lecture 6: Communication Complexity of Auctions Lecturer: Sébastien Lahaie Scribe: Rajat Dixit, Sébastien Lahaie In this lecture we examine the amount of communication

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy Andrew McLennan October 28, 2014 Economics 7250 Advanced Mathematical Techniques for Economics Second Semester 2014 Lecture 15 The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy I. Introduction A. The material discussed

More information

The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete. Resources

The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete. Resources The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete Resources Murat Yılmaz and Özgür Yılmaz November 17, 2016 Abstract A central notion for allocation problems when there are private endowments is

More information

MISTAKES IN COOPERATION: the Stochastic Stability of Edgeworth s Recontracting. Roberto Serrano Oscar Volij. January 2003

MISTAKES IN COOPERATION: the Stochastic Stability of Edgeworth s Recontracting. Roberto Serrano Oscar Volij. January 2003 MISTAKES IN COOPERATION: the Stochastic Stability of Edgeworth s Recontracting Roberto Serrano Oscar Volij January 2003 Abstract. In an exchange economy with a finite number of indivisible goods, we analyze

More information

1 Second Welfare Theorem

1 Second Welfare Theorem Econ 701B Fall 018 University of Pennsylvania Recitation : Second Welfare Theorem Xincheng Qiu (qiux@sas.upenn.edu) 1 Second Welfare Theorem Theorem 1. (Second Welfare Theorem) An economy E satisfies (A1)-(A4).

More information

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics Topics Volume 9, Issue 1 2009 Article 43 Simple Economies with Multiple Equilibria Theodore C. Bergstrom Ken-Ichi Shimomura Takehiko Yamato University of California,

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 41, No. 2, May 2000 SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel In this article we consider

More information

Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium Competitive Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 16, October 26 Outline 1 Pareto Effi ciency 2 The Core 3 Planner s Problem(s) 4 Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium Decentralized vs. Centralized Economic

More information

Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative

Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative Tâtonnement Mitri Kitti Helsinki University of Technology, Systems Analysis Laboratory, P.O. Box 1100, FIN-02015 HUT, Finland Abstract Global convergence conditions

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities Elena del Mercato Vincenzo Platino Paris School of Economics - Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne QED-Jamboree Copenhagen,

More information

Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem

Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem Communications to SIMAI Congress, ISSN 1827-9015, Vol. 2 2007 DOI: 10.1685/CSC06159 Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem M. B. DONATO 1 and M. MILASI 2 Department

More information

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 David Pérez-Castrillo 2 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona David Wettstein 3 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev April 2005 1 We gratefully

More information

First Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem First Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 17, October 31 Outline 1 First Welfare Theorem 2 Preliminaries to Second Welfare Theorem Past Definitions A feasible allocation (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium Introduction to General Equilibrium Juan Manuel Puerta November 6, 2009 Introduction So far we discussed markets in isolation. We studied the quantities and welfare that results under different assumptions

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics

Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Papers in Economics No. 10/11 A General Equilibrium Corporate Finance Theorem for Incomplete Markets: A Special Case By Pascal Stiefenhofer, University of York Department of Economics and Related

More information

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Working Papers Institute of Mathematical Economics 430 April 2010 Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Tomoki Inoue IMW Bielefeld University Postfach 100131 33501 Bielefeld Germany

More information

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Existence, ncentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Yeneng Sun, Lei Wu and Nicholas C. Yannelis Abstract The rational expectations equilibrium (REE), as introduced

More information

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Market Equilibrium and the Core Market Equilibrium and the Core Ram Singh Lecture 3-4 September 22/25, 2017 Ram Singh (DSE) Market Equilibrium September 22/25, 2017 1 / 19 Market Exchange: Basics Let us introduce price in our pure exchange

More information

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency Sjur Didrik Flåm University of Bergen, Norway Background Customary Nash equilibrium has no coupling constraints. Here: coupling constraints

More information

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem MS&E 336 Lecture 8: Supermodular games Ramesh Johari April 30, 2007 In this lecture, we develop the theory of supermodular games; key references are the papers of Topkis [7], Vives [8], and Milgrom and

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 20, 2015 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Sept. 20, 2015 1 / 48 Pure Exchange Economy H consumers with: preferences described

More information

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015 ANSWER KEY University of California, Davis Date: June, 05 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomic Theory Reading Time: 0 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer four

More information

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER SCARLETT LI Abstract. The focus of this paper is proving Brouwer s fixed point theorem, which primarily relies on the fixed point property of the

More information

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability Chapter 7 Nathan Smooha Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability 7.1 Introduction Brouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Let X be a non-empty, compact, and convex subset of R m. If

More information

PhD Qualifier Examination

PhD Qualifier Examination PhD Qualifier Examination Department of Agricultural Economics July 26, 2013 Instructions The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Tymofiy Mylovanov Thomas Tröger University of Bonn June 21, 2008 1/28 Motivation 2/28 Motivation In most applications of mechanism design, the proposer

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions Guoqiang Tian Abstract This paper provides a price equilibrium existence theorem in economies where commodities may be indivisible

More information

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION Jan Werner European University Institute May 2010 1 I. Price Bubbles: An Example Example I.1 Time is infinite; so dates are t = 0,1,2,...,.

More information

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Michael Florig Jorge Rivera Cayupi First version November 2001, this version May 2005 Abstract We study an economy where all goods entering

More information

The Last Word on Giffen Goods?

The Last Word on Giffen Goods? The Last Word on Giffen Goods? John H. Nachbar February, 1996 Abstract Giffen goods have long been a minor embarrassment to courses in microeconomic theory. The standard approach has been to dismiss Giffen

More information

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III The Existence of Equilibrium in Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples John H. Boyd III April 1989; Updated June 1995 Abstract. This paper presents some examples that clarify certain topological and

More information

Can everyone benefit from innovation?

Can everyone benefit from innovation? Can everyone benefit from innovation? Christopher P. Chambers and Takashi Hayashi June 16, 2017 Abstract We study a resource allocation problem with variable technologies, and ask if there is an allocation

More information

Fixed Point Theorems

Fixed Point Theorems Fixed Point Theorems Definition: Let X be a set and let f : X X be a function that maps X into itself. (Such a function is often called an operator, a transformation, or a transform on X, and the notation

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

18 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences

18 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences 18 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences 18.1 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences In intermediate microeconomic theory, a firm s cost function is often described as U-shaped.

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo September 6, 2011 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions Songzi Du Haoxiang Zhu March, 014 Preliminary and Incomplete. Comments Welcome Abstract We study bilateral trading between two bidders in a divisible double

More information

A finite population ESS and a long run equilibrium in an n players coordination game

A finite population ESS and a long run equilibrium in an n players coordination game Mathematical Social Sciences 39 (000) 95 06 www.elsevier.nl/ locate/ econbase A finite population ESS and a long run equilibrium in an n players coordination game Yasuhito Tanaka* Faculty of Law, Chuo

More information

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses. Microeconomic Theory Summer 206-7 Mid-semester Exam 2 There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.. Consider the following 2 2 economy. The utility functions are: u (.) = x x 2

More information

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY Essential Microeconomics -1-3. THE EXCHNGE ECONOMY Pareto efficient allocations 2 Edgewort box analysis 5 Market clearing prices 13 Walrasian Equilibrium 16 Equilibrium and Efficiency 22 First welfare

More information

The Survival Assumption in Intertemporal Economy J.M. Bonnisseau and A. Jamin 1 November Abstract

The Survival Assumption in Intertemporal Economy J.M. Bonnisseau and A. Jamin 1 November Abstract The Survival Assumption in Intertemporal Economy J.M. Bonnisseau and A. Jamin 1 November 2009 Abstract In an economy with a non-convex production sector, we provide an assumption for general pricing rules

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Econ Theory Bull (2014) 2:65 76 DOI 10.1007/s40505-014-0029-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Donald J. Brown Caterina Calsamiglia Received: 29 November

More information

6 Classical dualities and reflexivity

6 Classical dualities and reflexivity 6 Classical dualities and reflexivity 1. Classical dualities. Let (Ω, A, µ) be a measure space. We will describe the duals for the Banach spaces L p (Ω). First, notice that any f L p, 1 p, generates the

More information

1 General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium 1 General Equilibrium 1.1 Pure Exchange Economy goods, consumers agent : preferences < or utility : R + R initial endowments, R + consumption bundle, =( 1 ) R + Definition 1 An allocation, =( 1 ) is feasible

More information

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium 1.1 There are only two goods in the economy and there is no way to produce either good. There are n individuals, indexed by i = 1,..., n. Individual i owns

More information

Implementability, Walrasian Equilibria, and Efficient Matchings

Implementability, Walrasian Equilibria, and Efficient Matchings Implementability, Walrasian Equilibria, and Efficient Matchings Piotr Dworczak and Anthony Lee Zhang Abstract In general screening problems, implementable allocation rules correspond exactly to Walrasian

More information

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes *

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * Hugo F. Sonnenschein a and Marcus M. Opp b a Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 6 E. 59 th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 h-sonnenschein@uchicago.edu

More information

PERIODICITY AND CHAOS ON A MODIFIED SAMUELSON MODEL

PERIODICITY AND CHAOS ON A MODIFIED SAMUELSON MODEL PERIODICITY AND CHAOS ON A MODIFIED SAMUELSON MODEL Jose S. Cánovas Departamento de Matemática Aplicada y Estadística. Universidad Politécnica de Cartagena e-mail:jose.canovas@upct.es Manuel Ruiz Marín

More information

Implementation in Economies with Non-Convex Production Technologies Unknown to the Designer

Implementation in Economies with Non-Convex Production Technologies Unknown to the Designer Implementation in Economies with Non-Convex Production Technologies Unknown to the Designer Guoqiang TIAN Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, Texas 77843 and Institute for Advanced

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University March 26, 2012 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg () Stochastic Dynamic Programming March 26, 2012 1 / 31 References

More information

The Definition of Market Equilibrium The concept of market equilibrium, like the notion of equilibrium in just about every other context, is supposed to capture the idea of a state of the system in which

More information

Learning, Memory, and Inertia *

Learning, Memory, and Inertia * Learning, Memory, and Inertia * Carlos Alós Ferrer E mail: Carlos.Alos Ferrer@univie.ac.at Department of Economics, University of Vienna, Hohenstaufengasse 9, A 1010 Vienna, Austria This paper explores

More information

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad Unlinked llocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One ad Chiaki Hara Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University pril 16,

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA WORKING PAPERS Carlos Alós-Ferrer Cournot versus Walras in Dynamic Oligopolies with Memory August 2001 Working Paper No: 0110 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA All our working papers are available

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma. Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley**

Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma. Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley** Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley** Published as: Bhaskar Chakravorti and John P. Conley (2004) Bargaining Efficiency and the repeated Prisoners

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Implementation of Marginal Cost Pricing Equilibrium Allocations with Transfers in Economies with Increasing Returns to Scale

Implementation of Marginal Cost Pricing Equilibrium Allocations with Transfers in Economies with Increasing Returns to Scale Implementation of Marginal Cost Pricing Equilibrium Allocations with Transfers in Economies with Increasing Returns to Scale Guoqiang TIAN Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station,

More information

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions 1. For each of the following propositions, state whether the proposition is true or false. If true, provide a proof (or at least indicate how a proof could

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS This exam is take-home, open-book, open-notes. You may consult any published source (cite

More information

WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY

WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY H. JEROME KEISLER AND YENENG SUN Abstract. An atomless probability space (Ω, A, P ) is said to have the saturation property for a probability measure µ on

More information

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score. Economics 200A Part 2 UCSD Fall 2012 Prof. R. Starr, Mr. Troy Kravitz Final Exam 1 Your Name: Please answer all questions. Each of the six questions marked with a big number counts equally. Designate your

More information

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication)

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Nikolaus Robalino and Arthur Robson Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 2 This appendix contains the proof of Theorem

More information

Economics 201B. Nonconvex Preferences and Approximate Equilibria

Economics 201B. Nonconvex Preferences and Approximate Equilibria Economics 201B Nonconvex Preferences and Approximate Equilibria 1 The Shapley-Folkman Theorem The Shapley-Folkman Theores an elementary result in linear algebra, but it is apparently unknown outside the

More information

On the existence of price equilibrium in economies with excess demand functions

On the existence of price equilibrium in economies with excess demand functions Econ Theory Bull (2016) 4:5 16 DOI 10.1007/s40505-015-0091-7 RESEARCH ARTICLE On the existence of price equilibrium in economies with excess demand functions Guoqiang Tian 1 Received: 15 September 2015

More information

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden 1 Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning Jason R. Marden Abstract A learning rule is completely uncoupled if each player s behavior is conditioned only on his own realized

More information

Core. Ichiro Obara. December 3, 2008 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, / 22

Core. Ichiro Obara. December 3, 2008 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, / 22 Ichiro Obara UCLA December 3, 2008 Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, 2008 1 / 22 in Edgeworth Box Core in Edgeworth Box Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, 2008 2 / 22 in Edgeworth Box Motivation How should we interpret

More information

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory Lecture 1 History of general equilibrium theory Adam Smith: The Wealth of Nations, 1776 many heterogeneous individuals with diverging interests many voluntary but uncoordinated actions (trades) results

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

Product differences and prices

Product differences and prices Product differences and prices Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Abstract Under assumptions following Hotelling s 1929 paper Stability in Competition, the possibility

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information