Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order"

Transcription

1 Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order Hee Seok Nam a,, Qihe Tang a, Fan Yang b a Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Iowa, 241 Schaeffer Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA b Applied Mathematical and Computational Sciences, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA Abstract In this paper we show a characterization of upper comonotonicity via tail convex order. For any given marginal distributions, a maximal random vector with respect to tail convex order is proved to be upper comonotonic under suitable conditions. As an application, we consider the computation of the Haezendonck risk measure of the sum of upper comonotonic random variables with exponential marginal distributions. Keywords: comonotonicity, upper comonotonicity, tail convex order, Haezendonck risk measures JEL: D81; G32 Subject Category and Insurance Branch Category: IM30; IE43 1. Introduction In the study of the riskiness of an insurance portfolio, we are often interested in the total loss as a sum of risk variables. While traditional approaches have been based on the independence assumption between risks, recent trends allow dependent structures so that we can model the real situation more plausibly. Complications due to dependence between risks can be avoided by, or appropriately dealt with through, replacing the original sum by a less attractive one with a simpler dependence structure. Several Corresponding author addresses: kinsuever@gmail.com (Hee Seok Nam), qihe-tang@uiowa.edu (Qihe Tang), fan-yang-2@uiowa.edu (Fan Yang) Preprint submitted to Insurance: Mathematics and Economics January 5, 2011

2 concepts have been introduced to compare risks in the actuarial literature (see e.g. [8], [11]). One common way is to consider convex order which uses stop-loss premiums with the same mean. It is well known that if a random vector with given marginal distributions is comonotonic, then it has the largest sum with respect to convex order (see e.g. [9]). A proof based on geometric interpretation of the comonotonic support can be found in [15]. Conversely, it is also true that if a sum is maximal in the set of all random vectors with predetermined marginal distributions in convex order, then the underlying random variables must be comonotonic. Cheung proved the claim for the case of continuous marginal distributions in [3]. Later it was generalized to the case of integrable distributions in [5]. In [16] the authors showed that the problem boils down to a bivariate case and the joint distribution is indeed the minimum of the two marginal distributions. The well-known fact that a random vector is comonotonic if and only if it is pairwise comonotonic is used. It is, however, no longer valid for an upper comonotonic random vector and a counter-example is given in the appendix of this paper. The concept of upper comonotonicity was introduced and investigated in [4]. A characterization using joint distributions and the additivity of Valueat-Risk, Tail Value-at-Risk, and Expected Shortfall were given. In [12] the authors proved the additivity of α-mixed inverse distribution functions and stop-loss premiums for the sum of upper comonotonic random variables. In [5] it was shown that the additivity of Value-at-Risk for the confidence level being sufficiently large implies the upper comonotonicity. On the other hand, as in the comonotonic case, we can consider an ordering between the sum S of the components of a random vector X and the corresponding sum S uc of an upper comonotonic random vector X uc. Indeed, if X uc coincides with X in the lower tail in distribution and they have the same marginal distributions, then the sum S precedes S uc in convex order (for details, see [12]). If there is no coincidence in the lower tail, then the convex order is no longer valid in general and it should be relaxed to describe the upper tail only. The concept of tail convex order was introduced by [6], who proved that, upon suitable conditions, the sum of the components of an upper comonotonic random vector is the largest in tail convex order. This suggests that upper comonotonicity be related to tail convex order rather than convex order. Therefore, the following characterization question arises: if the sum of the components of a random vector is maximal in tail convex order, then is 2

3 this random vector upper comonotonic? In the present paper, we shall focus on this question and pursue an answer. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 prepares some necessary definitions and states our main result, Section 3 formulates the proof of the result, Section 4 shows an application to the computation of Haezendonck risk measures, and, finally, Appendix contains some examples to further clarify some fallacies. 2. Main Result The underlying probability space is denoted by (Ω, F, P ), where real valued random variables or risks X i and Y i are defined for i = 1,..., n. A subset C R n is said to be comonotonic if for any x and y in C, either x y or y x holds. We call a random vector X = (X 1,..., X n ) to be comonotonic if it has a comonotonic support. As a generalization of comonotonicity, we consider upper comonotonicity. For any given d = (d 1,..., d n ) (R { }) n, the upper quadrant (d 1, ) (d n, ) is denoted by U(d), the lower quadrant (, d 1 ] (, d n ] by L(d), and the remaining complement R n \ (U(d) L(d)) by R(d). Definition 2.1. ([4]) A random vector X = (X 1,..., X n ) is said to be upper comonotonic if there exist some d (R { }) n and some null set N such that (i) {X(ω) : ω Ω \ N} U(d) is comonotonic, (ii) P (X U(d)) > 0, (iii) {X(ω) : ω Ω \ N} R(d) is empty. The usual inverse distribution functions F 1 1+ X (p), FX (p) of a random variable X : Ω R are defined by F 1 X (p) = inf{x R : F X(x) p}, F 1+ X (p) = sup{x R : F X(x) p}, respectively, with the convention inf = and sup =. To pick up any point in the closed interval [F 1 1+ X (p), FX (p)], we introduce the so-called α-mixed inverse distribution functions of F X as F 1(α) X (p) = αf 1 1+ (p) + (1 α)f (p), p (0, 1). X X 3

4 See e.g. [9] for related discussions. From now on, the distribution function F Xi or F Yi will be denoted by F i as long as no confusion arises. A random variable X is said to precede another random variable Y in stop-loss order (written as X sl Y ) if X has less stop-loss premiums than Y, i.e. E[(X d) + ] E[(Y d) + ] for all d R. It is well known that stop-loss order preserves the ordering of TVaR p and vice versa, i.e. X sl Y if and only if TVaR p [X] TVaR p [Y ] for all p (0, 1) (see [11]). A random variable X is said to precede Y in convex order (written as X cx Y ) if E[X] = E[Y ] and X sl Y. For an overview of recent progresses on comonotonicity-based convex bounds, see [7], [10] and references therein. In particular, by limiting the range of d in stop-loss order, we are led to the following definition. Definition 2.2. ([6]) A random variable X is said to precede another random variable Y in tail convex order (written as X tcx Y ) if there exists some d such that (i) P (X d ) > 0, (ii) E[X] = E[Y ], (iii) E[(X d) + ] E[(Y d) + ] for all d d. For any given Y, the existence of an upper comonotonic random vector Y uc satisfying S tcx S uc is shown in Section 4 of [12], where (here and throughout) S and S uc are the sums of the components of Y and Y uc, respectively. For any given distribution functions F 1,..., F n, the Fréchet space R = R(F 1,..., F n ) is defined to be the set of all random vectors with marginal distributions F 1,..., F n. Note that if we restrict ourselves on R, then stoploss order is exactly the same as convex order. Now we are ready to state the main result. In what follows, for any given A R n, its closure, interior, and boundary are denoted by A, int(a), and bd(a), respectively. Theorem 2.3. For any given marginal distributions F 1,..., F n, if there exists Y = (Y 1,..., Y n ) R = R(F 1,..., F n ) such that X X n tcx Y Y n, (X 1,..., X n ) R, (1) then there exist some d R n and a null set N Ω such that 4

5 (i) P (Y U(d )) > 0, (ii) {Y : ω Ω \ N} U(d ) is comonotonic, (iii) {Y : ω Ω \ N} int(r(d )) =. Furthermore, if P (Y bd(u(d ))) = 0 then (Y 1,..., Y n ) is upper comonotonic with a threshold in L(d ). Note that (i) (iii) of the theorem are similar to, but not exactly same as, the three conditions in Definition 2.1. Example A.2 below shows the necessity of the condition P (Y bd(u(d ))) = 0 for Y to be upper comonotonic. 3. Proof of the Theorem The proof of Theorem 2.3 will be given by observing relations between Y and its comonotonic counterpart Y c in terms of stop-loss premiums Lemmas To begin with, we recall the following lemma: Lemma 3.1. ([9]) The stop-loss premiums of the sum S c of the components of the comonotonic random vector Y c = (Y1 c,..., Yn c ) are given by E[(S c d) + ] = n E[(Yi c d i ) + ] for F 1+ 1 S (0) < d < F c S (1), c i=1 where d i = F 1(α) i (F S c(d)) and α [0, 1] solves the equation F 1(α) S (F c S c(d)) = d. Note that a similar result also holds true for an upper comonotonic random vector (see e.g. [12]). In addition, we can see that d i = F 1(α) i (q) is defined only for values of the form q = F S c(d). Nevertheless, the applicability of Lemma 3.1 during the proof of Theorem 2.3 is guaranteed by the following lemma, which shows that the image of each F i is a subset of the image of F S c, namely, Im(F i ) Im(F S c). Lemma 3.2. For any random vector Y = (Y 1,..., Y n ) and its comonotonic counterpart Y c, we have Im(F i ) Im(F S c), i = 1,..., n. 5

6 Proof. We prove the contraposition. It is well known that the additivity of the α-mixed inverse function holds for a comonotonic random vector [9]: F 1(α) S c (q) = n i=1 F 1(α) i (q), 0 < q < 1, 0 α 1. (2) If q / Im(F S c), then there exists a sufficiently small ɛ > 0 such that F 1(α) S c is constant on the interval [q, q + ɛ). By (2) each F 1(α) i is also constant on the interval [q, q + ɛ) since it is non-decreasing,. Then q / Im(F i ) for each i {1,..., n} and this completes the proof Proof of Theorem 2.3 The argument of [16] motivates the following proof. Since the comonotonic counterpart Y c is also in the Fréchet space R, the condition (1) implies Y c Y c n tcx Y Y n. By definition there exists d such that P (S d ) > 0 and E[(Y Y n d) + ] = E[(Y c Y c n d) + ], d d. (3) For d d and α [0, 1] which solves the equation F 1(α) S (F c Sc(d)) = d, we define d = (d 1,..., d n ) with d i = F 1(α) i (F S c(d)). In the particular case of d = d, the notations d and d i are used. Then, by (3) and Lemma 3.1, [ n n ] E[(S d) + ] = E[(S c d) + ] = E[(Yi c d i ) + ] = E (Y i d i ) +. i=1 Since (S d) + n i=1 (Y i d i ) +, we have (S d) + = n i=1 (Y i d i ) + almost surely, or, equivalently, there exists a null set N Ω such that (Y i (ω) d i )(Y j (ω) d j ) 0, ω Ω \ N, i, j = 1,..., n. (4) Since P (S d ) > 0, (4) implies i=1 P (Y U(d )) > 0. (5) We formulate the remaining proof of Theorem 2.3 into the following three steps. 6

7 Step 1. For any (y i, y j ) U(d i, d j ), the closure of the upper quadrant U(d i, d j), we have P (Y i y i, Y j y j ) = min k=i,j P (Y k y k ). Proof. Note that a distribution function has no more than countably many discontinuities. If we can show that, for any (y i, y j ) U(d i, d j) with y i and y j being continuities of F i and F j, there exists a null set Ñ Ω such that {ω Ω \ N : Y i y i, Y j y j } = {ω Ω \ Ñ : Y k y k }, k = i or j, then the right continuity of distribution functions gives the desired result of Step 1. Without loss of generality, we may assume that i = 1, j = 2, that F 1, F 2 are continuous at y 1, y 2, and that q 1 = F 1 (y 1 ) q 2 = F 2 (y 2 ). It suffices to prove that P (Y 1 y 1, Y 2 y 2 ) = P (Y 1 y 1 ). (6) Lemma 3.2 guarantees that q 1, q 2 Im(F S c) and we can use (4) to obtain ( )( ) Y 1 (ω) F 1(α 1) 1 (q 1 ) Y 2 (ω) F 1(α 1) 2 (q 1 ) ( )( ) 0, ω Ω \ N, (7) Y 1 (ω) F 1(α 2) 1 (q 2 ) Y 2 (ω) F 1(α 2) 2 (q 2 ) 0, ω Ω \ N, (8) where α 1 and α 2 [0, 1] solve the equations y 1 = F 1(α 1) 1 (q 1 ) and y 2 = F 1(α 2) 2 (q 2 ), respectively. If q 1 = F 1 (y 1 ) < q 2 = F 2 (y 2 ), then, by the continuity of F 1 at y 1 and (7), {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1 } {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1, Y 2 y 2 } = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1, Y 2 F 1(α 2) 2 (q 2 )} = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 < y 1, Y 2 F 1(α 1) 2 (q 1 )} {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 = y 1, Y 2 F 1(α 1) 2 (q 1 )} {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1, F 1(α 1) 2 (q 1 ) < Y 2 F 1(α 2) 2 (q 2 )} = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 < y 1, Y 2 F 1(α 1) 2 (q 1 )} N 1 = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 < y 1 } N 1 = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1 } N 1 \ N 2, (9) 7

8 where P (N 1 ) = P (N 2 ) = 0. If q 1 = q 2 and α 1 < α 2, then the same argument also applies to get (9). Finally, if q 1 = q 2 and α 1 α 2, then, by the continuity of F 2 at y 2 and (8), {ω Ω \ N : Y 2 y 2 } {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1, Y 2 y 2 } = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 F 1(α 1) 1 (q 1 ), Y 2 y 2 } = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 F 1(α 2) 1 (q 2 ), Y 2 < y 2 } {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 F 1(α 2) 1 (q 2 ), Y 2 = y 2 } {ω Ω \ N : F 1(α 2) 1 (q 2 ) < Y 1 F 1(α 1) 1 (q 2 ), Y 2 y 2 } = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 F 1(α 2) 1 (q 2 ), Y 2 < y 2 } N 3 = {ω Ω \ N : Y 2 < y 2 } N 3 = {ω Ω \ N : Y 2 y 2 } N 3 \ N 4, (10) where P (N 3 ) = P (N 4 ) = 0. By (9) and (10) we conclude that the relation (6) holds, and this completes the proof of Step 1. Step 2. For any y = (y 1,..., y n ) U(d ), and Y is comonotonic in U(d ). P (Y 1 y 1,..., Y n y n ) = min i=1,...,n P (Y i y i ), Proof. By induction, we will prove the claim that {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1,..., Y n y n } = {ω Ω \ Ñ : Y i y i } (11) for some i {1,..., n} with null sets N and Ñ. For n = 2, the claim is true by Step 1. Now, suppose that the claim is true for n = k 2 and consider it for n = k + 1. Again by Step 1, we have {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1,..., Y k+1 y k+1 } = {ω Ω \ N : Y 1 y 1,..., Y k y k } {ω Ω \ N : Y k+1 y k+1 } = {ω Ω \ N i : Y i y i } {ω Ω \ N : Y k+1 y k+1 } for some i {1,..., k} = {ω Ω \ (N N i ) : Y i y i, Y k+1 y k+1 } = {ω Ω \ Ñ : Y j y j } for j = i or k + 1, where N, N i, and Ñ are null sets. This shows that (11) holds true. 8

9 To show the comonotonicity of Y on U(d ), we construct a new random vector Ỹ by restricting Y to the set Ω = {ω Ω \ N : Y(ω) U(d )}. Then by (4), P ( Ω) = 1 F Y (d ) + P (Y = d ). Note that P ( Ω) > 0 by (5). Now we consider the new probability space ( Ω, F, P ) where F = F Ω and P (A) = P (A)/P ( Ω) for A F. To obtain the comonotonicity of Ỹ = Y Ω, it suffices to check FỸ(y 1,..., y n ) = min 1 i n F Ỹ i (y i ), (y 1,..., y n ) R n. (12) Since the interior of R(d ) has no intersection with {Y(ω) : ω Ω \ N} by (4), if y i d i then FỸi (y i ) = P ({Y i y i } Ω)/P ( Ω) = ( F i (y i ) (1 P ( Ω)) ) /P ( Ω). Therefore the marginal distribution function of Ỹi is given by { 0, y i < d i, FỸi (y i ) = ( Fi (y i ) (1 P ( Ω)) ) /P ( Ω), y i d i. Similarly, for any y R n we have { 0, y / U(d FỸ(y) = ), ( FY (y) (1 P ( Ω)) ) /P ( Ω), y U(d ). Finally, by (11) we obtain that (12) holds true and, hence, Y is comonotonic on U(d ). Step 3. If P (Y bd(u(d ))) = 0 then (Y 1,..., Y n ) is upper comonotonic with a threshold in L(d ). Proof. The condition of this step is equivalent to P (Y 1 d 1,..., Y i 1 d i 1, Y i = d i, Y i+1 d i+1,..., Y n d n) = 0 for each i {1,..., n}. In other words, (4) with a strict inequality holds, i.e., ( )( ) Y i (ω) d i Y j (ω) d j > 0, ω Ω \ N, i, j = 1,..., n. This implies that R(d ) {Y(ω) : ω Ω \ N} =. Then it is straightforward to check the conditions (i)-(iii) in Definition 2.1 to get the upper comonotonicity of Y. 9

10 4. Application In this section, we consider an application to the computation of Haezendonck risk measures. The concept of Haezendonck risk measures was first raised by Haezendonck and Goovaerts [14]. As a premium calculation principle induced by an Orlicz norm, it is multiplicatively analogous to the zero utility principle. In [13], Haezendonck risk measures were derived as translationinvariant minimal Orlicz risk measures which preserve convex order. In [1], an alternative formulation of Haezendonck risk measures was introduced to guarantee coherence. For application to portfolio optimization, several estimators of Haezendonck risk measure were provided by numerical simulations in [2]. Definition 4.1. ([13]) For a risk variable X, 0 < q < 1 and a nonnegative, strictly increasing continuous function φ( ) satisfying φ(0) = 0, φ(1) = 1, φ(+ ) = +, the Haezendonck risk measure is defined as π q [X] = inf π q[x, x], (13) <x<max[x] where π q [X, x] is the unique solution of the equation [ ( )] (X x)+ E φ = 1 q. (14) π x As its definition indicates, the computation of the Haezendonck risk measure π q [X] is complicated in general except for some ideal choices of φ( ) and the distribution of X. Example 4.2. Suppose that φ(t) = t. For any given marginal distributions F 1,..., F n, if Y = (Y 1,..., Y n ) R(F 1,..., F n ) is maximal in tail convex order, then there exists some q (0, 1) such that π q [Y Y n ] = n TVaR q [Y i ], q (q, 1). (15) i=1 Proof. By definition there exists some d such that E[(S c x) + ] = E[(S x) + ] for all x d. Thus π q [S, x] = π q [S c, x] for all x d since π q [S, x] = E[(S x) +] 1 q 10 + x.

11 Moreover, if x d then F S (x) = F S c(x) by (ii) and (iii) of Theorem 2.3. Indeed, the support of Y coincides with that of Y c on U(d ) \ d and both of Y and Y c have no support on int(r(d )). The value of the Haezendonck risk measure π q [S] in (13) is attained at x at which the derivative d dx π q[s, x] = F S(x) q 1 q changes sign. A subtle analysis shows that x = F 1 S (q). Therefore, if q > q := F S (d ) then and x = F 1 S 1 (q) = F c (q) d π q [S] = π q [S, x ] = π q [S c, x ] = E[(Sc F 1 S (q)) +] c + F 1 S 1 q (q). c Hence, the desired relation (15) holds. In fact, the proof of Example 4.2 shows that π q [Y Y n ] = TVaR q [Y Y n ], q (0, 1) with φ(t) = t (see e.g. [13]). For a more general φ of the form φ(t) = t r with r > 1, it is unlikely that we can establish a transparent expression for the Haezendonck risk measure π q [X]. Nevertheless, for some special cases we can do so under the help of the following lemma. Lemma 4.3. If φ(t) = t r with r 1 and 0 < q < 1 then d dx π q[x, x] is non-decreasing in x and lim x Proof. For φ(t) = t, as shown in Example 4.2, S d dx π q[x, x] = 1. (16) d dx π q[x, x] = F X(x) q, 1 q 11

12 which is non-decreasing and (16) holds true. For φ(t) = t r with r > 1, we have ( ) 1 d 1 dx π r ( q[x, x] = 1 E[(X x) r 1 q + ] ) 1 r 1 E[(X x) r 1 + ]. (17) Since r > 1, an application of Hölder s inequality shows that ( d 2 1 dx π q[x, x] = 2 Indeed, E[(X x) r 1 + ] = E 0. [ ) 1 r (r 1) ( E[(X x) r + ] ) 1 r 2 1 q ( (E[(X x) r 1 + ] ) 2 E[(X x) r + ]E[(X x) r 2 + ] (X x) r 2 + (X x) r Thus d dx π q[x, x] is continuous and non-decreasing. Finally, by Hölder s inequality again we have ] ( E[(X x) r +] ) 1 2 ( E[(X x) r 2 + ] ) 1 2. E[(X x) r 1 + ] = E [ (X x) r (x<x< ) ] ( E[(X x) r + ] ) 1 1 r (1 F X (x)) 1 r, which, together with (17), implies (16) and the proof ends. An upper comonotonic random vector Y = (Y 1,..., Y n ) has a stochastic representation (Y 1,..., Y n ) = d (F1 1 (U 1 ),..., Fn 1 (U n )), where U i = U1 (U>β) + βv i 1 (U β) for some β [0, 1), U and V i s are uniform on (0, 1), and U is independent of (V 1,..., V n ) (see e.g. [4]). Example 4.4. Suppose that φ(t) = t r with r 1. If the marginal distributions are exponential with rates λ 1,..., λ n, respectively, then ) π q [S] = 1 λ ln rr (1 q) Γ(r + 1) + r λ (18) for q > 1 Γ(r+1) (1 β) and λ = ( n 1 r r i=1 λ i ) 1. 12

13 Proof. We have E[(S x) r +] = E [ (S x) r +(1 (U>β) + 1 (U β) ) ] [( ) r ] [( n ln(1 U) = E x 1 (U>β) + βe λ + If λx ln(1 β) then it reduces to 1 ( ln(1 u) E[(S x) r +] = λ β ) r x + i=1 ln(1 βv i ) λ i x du = e λx Γ(r + 1), λr so that d dx π q[s, x] = 1 1 ( ) 1 Γ(r + 1) r e λ x r. r 1 q d By Lemma 4.3, if π dx q[s, x] < 0, or, equivalently, ln(1 β) x= q > 1 λ Γ(r + 1) (1 β), r r then the equation d dx π q[s, x] = 0 has a solution x = 1 λ ln rr (1 q) Γ(r + 1) ln(1 β) >. λ Thus we obtain the desired Haezendonck risk measure (18) as π q [S] = π q [S, x ]. Note that if β = 0, then this example reduces to the case of completely comonotonic random vector. 5. Conclusion The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, we showed a characterization of upper comonotonicity via tail convex order. Second, as an application, we considered the computation of the Haezendonck risk measure of the sum of upper comonotonic random variables and we established a transparent expression for the case with exponential marginal distributions and a large confidence level. Note that upper comonotonicity corresponds to a special case of asymptotic dependence in the upper tail with coefficient 1. It is desirable to extend some applications of upper comonotonicity to the case of asymptotic dependence. We shall pursue such extensions in our future research. 13 ) r + ].

14 Acknowledgments The authors are thankful to Ka Chun Cheung and an anonymous referee for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. Appendix It is well known that a random vector Y = (Y 1,..., Y n ) is comonotonic if and only if it is pairwise comonotonic (see e.g. [9]). This is, however, no longer true for an upper comonotonic random vector. Example A.1. For n = 3 and Ω = {ω 1,..., ω 8 }, we define a random vector Y = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ) as follows: ω Y 1 Y 2 Y 3 P ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 ω /8 It is easy to check that each pair (Y i, Y j ) is upper comonotonic. Indeed, the thresholds of (Y 1, Y 2 ), (Y 2, Y 3 ), (Y 3, Y 1 ) are (0, 0), ( 1, 1), and (0, 1), respectively. Note, however, that the comonotonicity is broken down due to ω 3 and ω 4. Since Y(ω i ) and Y(ω i+1 ) always have at least one component with the same values for i = 1,..., 7 like a chain, there is no point d R 3 satisfying the three conditions in Definition 2.1. Therefore Y is not upper comonotonic. The following example illustrates the necessity of the condition P (Y bd(u(d ))) = 0 in Theorem 2.3 for Y to be upper comonotonic. Example A.2. For n = 2 and Ω = {ω 1,..., ω 10 }, we define a random vector Y = (Y 1, Y 2 ) with the corresponding comonotonic counterpart (Y1 c, Y2 c ) as follows: 14

15 ω Y 1 Y 2 Y 1 + Y 2 P ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω Y1 c Y2 c Y1 c + Y2 c P ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 ω /10 It is easy to check that the stop-loss premiums of Y 1 + Y 2 and Y c 1 + Y c 2 are equal for all d 0, i.e., E[(Y c 1 + Y c 2 d) + ] = E[(Y 1 + Y 2 d) + ], d 0. Although the support of (Y 1, Y 2 ) is comonotonic on U(0, 0), (Y 1, Y 2 ) is not upper comonotonic. The reason exists in that P ((Y 1, Y 2 ) bd(u(0, 0))) = 1 10 > 0. References [1] F. Bellini, E. Rosazza Gianin, On Haezendonck risk measures, Journal of Banking & Finance 32 (2008) [2] F. Bellini, E. Rosazza Gianin, Optimal portfolios with Haezendonck risk measures, Statist. Decisions 26 (2008) [3] K.C. Cheung, Characterization of comonotonicity using convex order, Insurance Math. Econom. 43 (2008) [4] K.C. Cheung, Upper comonotonicity, Insurance Math. Econom. 45 (2009) [5] K.C. Cheung, Characterizing a comonotonic random vector by the distribution of the sum of its components, Insurance Math. Econom. 47 (2010)

16 [6] K.C. Cheung, S. Vanduffel, Bounds for sums of random variables when the marginal distributions and the variance of the sum are given, Scand. Actuar. J. (Forthcoming) (2011). [7] G. Deelstra, J. Dhaene, M. Vanmaele, An overview of comonotonicity and its applications in finance and insurance, in: G. Di Nunno, B. Øksendal (Eds.), Advanced Mathematical Methods for Finance, Springer, [8] M. Denuit, J. Dhaene, M. Goovaerts, R. Kaas, Actuarial Theory for Dependent Risks: Measures, Orders and Models, Wiley, [9] J. Dhaene, M. Denuit, M.J. Goovaerts, R. Kaas, D. Vyncke, The concept of comonotonicity in actuarial science and finance: theory, Insurance Math. Econom. 31 (2002) [10] J. Dhaene, M. Denuit, M.J. Goovaerts, R. Kaas, D. Vyncke, The concept of comonotonicity in actuarial science and finance: applications, Insurance Math. Econom. 31 (2002) [11] J. Dhaene, S. Vanduffel, M.J. Goovaerts, R. Kaas, Q. Tang, D. Vyncke, Risk measures and comonotonicity: a review, Stoch. Models 22 (2006) [12] J. Dong, K.C. Cheung, H. Yang, Upper comonotonicity and convex upper bounds for sums of random variables, Insurance Math. Econom. 47 (2010) [13] M.J. Goovaerts, R. Kaas, J. Dhaene, Q. Tang, Some new classes of consistent risk measures, Insurance Math. Econom. 34 (2004) [14] J. Haezendonck, M.J. Goovaerts, A new premium calculation principle based on Orlicz norms, Insurance Math. Econom. 1 (1982) [15] R. Kaas, J. Dhaene, D. Vyncke, M.J. Goovaerts, M. Denuit, A simple geometric proof that comonotonic risks have the convex-largest sum, Astin Bull. 32 (2002) [16] T. Mao, T. Hu, A new proof of Cheung s characterization of comonotonicity, Insurance Math. Econom. 48 (2011)

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks Liang Hong, PhD, FSA Department of Mathematics Robert Morris University Presented at 2014 Actuarial Research Conference UC Santa Barbara July 16, 2014 Liang

More information

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Ka Chun Cheung, Michel Denuit, Jan Dhaene AFI_15100 TAIL MUTUAL EXCLUSIVITY AND TAIL-VAR LOWER BOUNDS KA CHUN CHEUNG Department of Statistics and Actuarial

More information

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Jan Dhaene Alexander Kukush y Daniël Linders z Qihe Tang x Version: October 7, 202 Abstract Distorted expectations can be expressed as weighted averages

More information

On the Haezendonck-Goovaerts Risk Measure for Extreme Risks

On the Haezendonck-Goovaerts Risk Measure for Extreme Risks On the Haezendonc-Goovaerts Ris Measure for Extreme Riss Qihe Tang [a],[b] and Fan Yang [b] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Iowa 241 Schaeffer Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242,

More information

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Jan Dhaene Shaun Wang Virginia Young Marc J. Goovaerts November 8, 1999 Abstract In this paper, we investigate the relationship between comonotonicity and

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Eur. Actuar. J. (2012) 2:319 328 DOI 10.1007/s13385-012-0058-0 ORIGINAL RESEARCH PAPER Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Jan Dhaene Alexander Kukush Daniël Linders Qihe Tang Received: 26

More information

Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks

Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks 1 Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks Alfred Kume 1 and Enkelejd Hashorva University of Kent & University of Lausanne February 1, 13 Abstract: In this paper we discuss the calculation

More information

Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks

Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks University of Iowa Iowa Research Online Theses and Dissertations Summer 23 Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks Fan Yang University of Iowa Copyright 23 Fan Yang This dissertation is available

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Introduction Extreme Scenarios Asymptotic Behavior Challenges Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Seminar at ETH Zurich

More information

A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables

A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables Journal of Mathematics and Statistics 8 (): -8, 0 ISSN 549-3644 0 Science Publications A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables Farida Kachapova and Ilias Kachapov School of Computing and Mathematical

More information

Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule

Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule Faculty of Economics and Applied Economics Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule Steven Vanduffel and Jan Dhaene DEPARTMENT OF ACCOUNTANCY, FINANCE AND INSURANCE (AFI) AFI 0601 Some Results

More information

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Walter Schneider July 26, 20 Abstract In this paper an analytic expression is given for the bounds

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures F. Bellini 1, B. Klar 2, A. Müller 3, E. Rosazza Gianin 1 1 Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca 2 Institut für Stochastik,

More information

Upper stop-loss bounds for sums of possibly dependent risks with given means and variances

Upper stop-loss bounds for sums of possibly dependent risks with given means and variances Statistics & Probability Letters 57 (00) 33 4 Upper stop-loss bounds for sums of possibly dependent risks with given means and variances Christian Genest a, Etienne Marceau b, Mhamed Mesoui c a Departement

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.rm] 11 Mar 2015

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.rm] 11 Mar 2015 Negative Dependence Concept in Copulas and the Marginal Free Herd Behavior Index Jae Youn Ahn a, a Department of Statistics, Ewha Womans University, 11-1 Daehyun-Dong, Seodaemun-Gu, Seoul 10-750, Korea.

More information

MATH 426, TOPOLOGY. p 1.

MATH 426, TOPOLOGY. p 1. MATH 426, TOPOLOGY THE p-norms In this document we assume an extended real line, where is an element greater than all real numbers; the interval notation [1, ] will be used to mean [1, ) { }. 1. THE p

More information

Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables

Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables Jaap Geluk 1 and Qihe Tang 2 1 Department of Mathematics The Petroleum Institute P.O. Box 2533, Abu Dhabi, United Arab

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Stoyan V. Stoyanov Svetlozar T. Rachev September 3, 7 Abstract In this paper, we prove a result for the asymptotic distribution of the sample

More information

COMPARING APPROXIMATIONS FOR RISK MEASURES RELATED TO SUMS OF CORRELATED LOGNORMAL RANDOM VARIABLES MASTERARBEIT

COMPARING APPROXIMATIONS FOR RISK MEASURES RELATED TO SUMS OF CORRELATED LOGNORMAL RANDOM VARIABLES MASTERARBEIT COMPARING APPROXIMATIONS FOR RISK MEASURES RELATED TO SUMS OF CORRELATED LOGNORMAL RANDOM VARIABLES MASTERARBEIT Technische Universität Chemnitz Fakultät für Mathematik Integrierter Internationaler Master-

More information

A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks

A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks Jan Dhaene 1 Daniël Linders 2 Wim Schoutens 3 David Vyncke 4 December 1, 2013 1 KU Leuven, Leuven, Belgium. Email: jan.dhaene@econ.kuleuven.be 2

More information

Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation

Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation Bin Wang and Ruodu Wang January, 015 Abstract We introduce the concept of an extremely negatively dependent (END) sequence of random variables with a given

More information

Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance

Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance Dr. Julia L. Wirch Dr. Mary R. Hardy Dept. of Actuarial Maths Dept. of Statistics and and Statistics Actuarial Science Heriot-Watt University

More information

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9 MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: FALL 204 Contents. Sets 2 2. Functions 5 3. Countability 7 4. Axiom of choice 8 5. Equivalence relations 9 6. Real numbers 9 7. Extended

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han Set, functions and Euclidean space Seungjin Han September, 2018 1 Some Basics LOGIC A is necessary for B : If B holds, then A holds. B A A B is the contraposition of B A. A is sufficient for B: If A holds,

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Carole Bernard, Xiao Jiang and Ruodu Wang November 213 Abstract Risk aggregation with dependence uncertainty refers to the sum of individual risks with known

More information

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University February 7, 2007 2 Contents 1 Metric Spaces 1 1.1 Basic definitions...........................

More information

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Remigijus Leipus (with Yang Yang, Yuebao Wang, Jonas Šiaulys) CIRM, Luminy, April 26-30, 2010 1. Preliminaries

More information

The main results about probability measures are the following two facts:

The main results about probability measures are the following two facts: Chapter 2 Probability measures The main results about probability measures are the following two facts: Theorem 2.1 (extension). If P is a (continuous) probability measure on a field F 0 then it has a

More information

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures Michael Kalkbrener Deutsche Bank AG Abstract An axiomatic definition of coherent capital allocations is given. It is shown

More information

X n D X lim n F n (x) = F (x) for all x C F. lim n F n(u) = F (u) for all u C F. (2)

X n D X lim n F n (x) = F (x) for all x C F. lim n F n(u) = F (u) for all u C F. (2) 14:17 11/16/2 TOPIC. Convergence in distribution and related notions. This section studies the notion of the so-called convergence in distribution of real random variables. This is the kind of convergence

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

L p Spaces and Convexity

L p Spaces and Convexity L p Spaces and Convexity These notes largely follow the treatments in Royden, Real Analysis, and Rudin, Real & Complex Analysis. 1. Convex functions Let I R be an interval. For I open, we say a function

More information

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION HALUK ERGIN AND TODD SARVER Abstract. Suppose (i) X is a separable Banach space, (ii) C is a convex subset of X that is a Baire space (when endowed

More information

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 Index Page 1 Topology 2 1.1 Definition of a topology 2 1.2 Basis (Base) of a topology 2 1.3 The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 1.4 Basic topology concepts: limit points, closed sets,

More information

Max-min (σ-)additive representation of monotone measures

Max-min (σ-)additive representation of monotone measures Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Max-min (σ-)additive representation of monotone measures Martin Brüning and Dieter Denneberg FB 3 Universität Bremen, D-28334 Bremen, Germany e-mail:

More information

STAT 7032 Probability Spring Wlodek Bryc

STAT 7032 Probability Spring Wlodek Bryc STAT 7032 Probability Spring 2018 Wlodek Bryc Created: Friday, Jan 2, 2014 Revised for Spring 2018 Printed: January 9, 2018 File: Grad-Prob-2018.TEX Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Cincinnati,

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Math 209B Homework 2

Math 209B Homework 2 Math 29B Homework 2 Edward Burkard Note: All vector spaces are over the field F = R or C 4.6. Two Compactness Theorems. 4. Point Set Topology Exercise 6 The product of countably many sequentally compact

More information

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks University of Wisconsin Milwaukee UWM Digital Commons Theses and Dissertations May 2014 Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks Evelyn Susanne Gaus University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee Follow

More information

The compound Poisson random variable s approximation to the individual risk model

The compound Poisson random variable s approximation to the individual risk model Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 36 (25) 57 77 The compound Poisson random variable s approximation to the individual risk model Jingping Yang, Shulin Zhou, Zhenyong Zhang LMAM, School of Mathematical

More information

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups L. Rüschendorf J. Witting February 23, 2017 Abstract We derive improved estimates for the model risk of risk portfolios when additional

More information

are Banach algebras. f(x)g(x) max Example 7.4. Similarly, A = L and A = l with the pointwise multiplication

are Banach algebras. f(x)g(x) max Example 7.4. Similarly, A = L and A = l with the pointwise multiplication 7. Banach algebras Definition 7.1. A is called a Banach algebra (with unit) if: (1) A is a Banach space; (2) There is a multiplication A A A that has the following properties: (xy)z = x(yz), (x + y)z =

More information

Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis

Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis Portland State University PDXScholar University Honors Theses University Honors College 2014 Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis Adam Robinson Portland State University Let us know

More information

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Risk Measures under Solvency II Dietmar Pfeifer (2004) Risk measures and premium principles a comparison VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Dependence and its implications for risk measures

More information

MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS

MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS EDWARD FURMAN Department of Mathematics and Statistics York University Toronto, Ontario M3J 1P3, Canada EMail: efurman@mathstat.yorku.ca

More information

Chapter 6 Expectation and Conditional Expectation. Lectures Definition 6.1. Two random variables defined on a probability space are said to be

Chapter 6 Expectation and Conditional Expectation. Lectures Definition 6.1. Two random variables defined on a probability space are said to be Chapter 6 Expectation and Conditional Expectation Lectures 24-30 In this chapter, we introduce expected value or the mean of a random variable. First we define expectation for discrete random variables

More information

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Proceedings of the World Congress on Engineering 29 Vol II WCE 29, July 1-3, 29, London, U.K. Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Tao Jiang Abstract

More information

2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits

2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits 2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits In this chapter, we introduce the fundamental notions of continuity and limit of a real-valued function of two variables. As in ACICARA, the definitions as well as proofs

More information

BIVARIATE P-BOXES AND MAXITIVE FUNCTIONS. Keywords: Uni- and bivariate p-boxes, maxitive functions, focal sets, comonotonicity,

BIVARIATE P-BOXES AND MAXITIVE FUNCTIONS. Keywords: Uni- and bivariate p-boxes, maxitive functions, focal sets, comonotonicity, BIVARIATE P-BOXES AND MAXITIVE FUNCTIONS IGNACIO MONTES AND ENRIQUE MIRANDA Abstract. We give necessary and sufficient conditions for a maxitive function to be the upper probability of a bivariate p-box,

More information

Indeed, if we want m to be compatible with taking limits, it should be countably additive, meaning that ( )

Indeed, if we want m to be compatible with taking limits, it should be countably additive, meaning that ( ) Lebesgue Measure The idea of the Lebesgue integral is to first define a measure on subsets of R. That is, we wish to assign a number m(s to each subset S of R, representing the total length that S takes

More information

Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension. n=1

Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension. n=1 Chapter 2 Probability measures 1. Existence Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension to the generated σ-field Proof of Theorem 2.1. Let F 0 be

More information

Scandinavian Actuarial Journal. Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks

Scandinavian Actuarial Journal. Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks For eer Review Only Journal: Manuscript ID: SACT-- Manuscript Type: Original Article Date Submitted

More information

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure Damir Filipović and Nicolas Vogelpoth Vienna Institute of Finance Nordbergstrasse 15 A-1090 Vienna, Austria first version: 16 August 2006, this version: 16

More information

WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA

WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA Adv. Appl. Prob. 37, 510 522 2005 Printed in Northern Ireland Applied Probability Trust 2005 WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA YIQING CHEN, Guangdong University of Technology

More information

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Sebastian Ferrando, Department of Mathematics, Ryerson University, Toronto, Canada Alfredo Gonzalez and Sebastian Ferrando Trajectorial

More information

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 3332. Abstract. In this

More information

Discrete Probability Refresher

Discrete Probability Refresher ECE 1502 Information Theory Discrete Probability Refresher F. R. Kschischang Dept. of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto January 13, 1999 revised January 11, 2006 Probability theory

More information

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989),

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989), Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 April 26, 2005 1 Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski 1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer

More information

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Jin Peng, Shengguo Li Institute of Uncertain Systems, Huanggang Normal University, Hubei 438, China Email: pengjin1@tsinghua.org.cn lisg@hgnu.edu.cn Abstract: A key

More information

Math General Topology Fall 2012 Homework 11 Solutions

Math General Topology Fall 2012 Homework 11 Solutions Math 535 - General Topology Fall 2012 Homework 11 Solutions Problem 1. Let X be a topological space. a. Show that the following properties of a subset A X are equivalent. 1. The closure of A in X has empty

More information

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays Bünyamin Kızıldemir Nicolas Privault Division of Mathematical Sciences School of Physical and Mathematical Sciences Nanyang Technological University 637371 Singapore

More information

Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence

Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence Int. J. Contemp. Math. Sciences, Vol. 4, 2009, no. 4, 191-200 Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence Marta Cardin Department of Applied Mathematics University of Venice, Italy mcardin@unive.it Abstract

More information

Herz (cf. [H], and also [BS]) proved that the reverse inequality is also true, that is,

Herz (cf. [H], and also [BS]) proved that the reverse inequality is also true, that is, REARRANGEMENT OF HARDY-LITTLEWOOD MAXIMAL FUNCTIONS IN LORENTZ SPACES. Jesús Bastero*, Mario Milman and Francisco J. Ruiz** Abstract. For the classical Hardy-Littlewood maximal function M f, a well known

More information

Technical Report No. 13/04, December 2004 INTRODUCING A DEPENDENCE STRUCTURE TO THE OCCURRENCES IN STUDYING PRECISE LARGE DEVIATIONS FOR THE TOTAL

Technical Report No. 13/04, December 2004 INTRODUCING A DEPENDENCE STRUCTURE TO THE OCCURRENCES IN STUDYING PRECISE LARGE DEVIATIONS FOR THE TOTAL Technical Report No. 13/04, December 2004 INTRODUCING A DEPENDENCE STRUCTURE TO THE OCCURRENCES IN STUDYING PRECISE LARGE DEVIATIONS FOR THE TOTAL CLAIM AMOUNT Rob Kaas and Qihe Tang Introducing a Dependence

More information

Tail Conditional Expectations for. Extended Exponential Dispersion Models

Tail Conditional Expectations for. Extended Exponential Dispersion Models Tail Conditional Expectations for Extended Exponential Dispersion Models A Thesis Presented to the Faculty of the Department of Mathematical Sciences Middle Tennessee State University In Partial Fulfillment

More information

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions vanrooijschikhof.tex April 25, 2018 van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions Notes from [vrs]. Introduction A monotone function is Riemann integrable. A continuous function is Riemann integrable.

More information

Bounds for Sums of Non-Independent Log-Elliptical Random Variables

Bounds for Sums of Non-Independent Log-Elliptical Random Variables Bounds for Sums of Non-Independent Log-Elliptical Random Variables Emiliano A. Valdez The University of New South Wales Jan Dhaene Katholieke Universiteit Leuven May 5, 003 ABSTRACT In this paper, we construct

More information

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

econstor Make Your Publications Visible. econstor Make Your Publications Visible. A Service of Wirtschaft Centre zbwleibniz-informationszentrum Economics Cheung, Ka Chun; Denuit, Michel; Dhaene, Jan Working Paper Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail-Var

More information

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Section 2.6 (cont.) Properties of Real Functions Here we first study properties of functions from R to R, making use of the additional structure

More information

Incremental Risk Vulnerability 1

Incremental Risk Vulnerability 1 Incremental Risk Vulnerability 1 Guenter Franke 2, Richard C. Stapleton 3 and Marti G Subrahmanyam 4 June 13, 2005 1 We are very much indebted to two unknown referees for their excellent comments. Section

More information

Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables

Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables Ruodu Wang November 26, 2013 Abstract Suppose X 1,, X n are random variables with the same known marginal distribution F

More information

F (x) = P [X x[. DF1 F is nondecreasing. DF2 F is right-continuous

F (x) = P [X x[. DF1 F is nondecreasing. DF2 F is right-continuous 7: /4/ TOPIC Distribution functions their inverses This section develops properties of probability distribution functions their inverses Two main topics are the so-called probability integral transformation

More information

Applications of axiomatic capital allocation and generalized weighted allocation

Applications of axiomatic capital allocation and generalized weighted allocation 6 2010 11 ( ) Journal of East China Normal University (Natural Science) No. 6 Nov. 2010 Article ID: 1000-5641(2010)06-0146-10 Applications of axiomatic capital allocation and generalized weighted allocation

More information

Introduction to Empirical Processes and Semiparametric Inference Lecture 08: Stochastic Convergence

Introduction to Empirical Processes and Semiparametric Inference Lecture 08: Stochastic Convergence Introduction to Empirical Processes and Semiparametric Inference Lecture 08: Stochastic Convergence Michael R. Kosorok, Ph.D. Professor and Chair of Biostatistics Professor of Statistics and Operations

More information

Convexity in R N Supplemental Notes 1

Convexity in R N Supplemental Notes 1 John Nachbar Washington University November 1, 2014 Convexity in R N Supplemental Notes 1 1 Introduction. These notes provide exact characterizations of support and separation in R N. The statement of

More information

From now on, we will represent a metric space with (X, d). Here are some examples: i=1 (x i y i ) p ) 1 p, p 1.

From now on, we will represent a metric space with (X, d). Here are some examples: i=1 (x i y i ) p ) 1 p, p 1. Chapter 1 Metric spaces 1.1 Metric and convergence We will begin with some basic concepts. Definition 1.1. (Metric space) Metric space is a set X, with a metric satisfying: 1. d(x, y) 0, d(x, y) = 0 x

More information

Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims

Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims Serguei Foss Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh Karlovasi, Samos 3 June, 2010 (Joint work with Tomasz Rolski and Stan Zachary

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting

Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting 1 Joint work with : Véronique Maume-Deschamps 1 and Didier Rullière 2 1 Institut Camille Jordan Université Lyon 1 2 Laboratoire des Sciences

More information

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Qihe Tang [a] and Zhongyi Yuan [b] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Iowa [b] Smeal College of Business Pennsylvania

More information

General approach to the optimal portfolio risk management

General approach to the optimal portfolio risk management General approach to the optimal portfolio risk management Zinoviy Landsman, University of Haifa Joint talk with Udi Makov and Tomer Shushi This presentation has been prepared for the Actuaries Institute

More information

Tail Conditional Expectations for Extended Exponential Dispersion Models

Tail Conditional Expectations for Extended Exponential Dispersion Models American Researc Journal of Matematics Original Article ISSN 378-704 Volume 1 Issue 4 015 Tail Conditional Expectations for Extended Exponential Dispersion Models Ye (Zoe) Ye Qiang Wu and Don Hong 1 Program

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk

A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/~wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Extreme Value Analysis Conference 2017 TU Delft

More information

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY 1. The Hopf-Rinow Theorem Recall that a Riemannian manifold (M, g) is called geodesically complete if the maximal defining interval of any geodesic is R. On the other

More information

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance Definitions and properties of Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance First Part: Convex Marco Frittelli Milano University The Fields Institute, Toronto, April 2010 Definitions and

More information

Reducing Risk in Convex Order

Reducing Risk in Convex Order Reducing Risk in Convex Order Junnan He a, Qihe Tang b and Huan Zhang b a Deartment of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Camus Box 208, St. Louis MO 6330-4899 b Deartment of Statistics and Actuarial

More information

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Chapter 4 GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Alberto Cambini Department of Statistics and Applied Mathematics University of Pisa, Via Cosmo Ridolfi 10 56124

More information

Lecture 1. Stochastic Optimization: Introduction. January 8, 2018

Lecture 1. Stochastic Optimization: Introduction. January 8, 2018 Lecture 1 Stochastic Optimization: Introduction January 8, 2018 Optimization Concerned with mininmization/maximization of mathematical functions Often subject to constraints Euler (1707-1783): Nothing

More information

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity 3 214 5 ( ) Journal of East China Normal University (Natural Science) No. 3 May 214 Article ID: 1-5641(214)3-23-7 Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity TIAN De-jian, JIANG Long, JI

More information

Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures

Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures Alfred Galichon (Ecole polytechnique) Brussels, May 25, 2012 Based on collaborations with: A. Charpentier (Rennes) G. Carlier (Dauphine)

More information

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis 1 Convex sets Both convex sets and functions have general importance in economic theory, not only in optimization. Given two points x; y 2 R n and 2 [0; 1]; the weighted

More information

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s.

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s. 20 6. CONDITIONAL EXPECTATION Having discussed at length the limit theory for sums of independent random variables we will now move on to deal with dependent random variables. An important tool in this

More information

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem Set 2: s Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem 1. (a) Prove that a closed subset of a complete metric space is complete. (b) Prove that a closed subset of a compact metric space is compact. (c) Prove that

More information

B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces

B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces B.1 B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces B.1. Fréchet spaces. In this appendix we go through the definition of Fréchet spaces and their inductive limits, such as they are used for definitions of function

More information

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due 9/5). Prove that every countable set A is measurable and µ(a) = 0. 2 (Bonus). Let A consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information