Structural Analysis of Tullock Contests with an Application to U.S. House of Representatives Elections

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Structural Analysis of Tullock Contests with an Application to U.S. House of Representatives Elections"

Transcription

1 Structural Analysis of Tullock Contests with an Application to U.S. House of Representatives Elections Ming He Yangguang Huang March 22, 27 Abstract We study the econometrics of an asymmetric Tullock contest model with incomplete information and establish nonparametric identification of the distributions of players private cost signals. We propose estimators for the quantile functions, establish their consistency, and develop an asymptotic inference procedure. Monte Carlo experiments demonstrate the good finite sample performance of the estimators and confidence intervals. We employ this newly developed method to analyze data from U.S. House of Representatives elections. The structural estimation results provide insights into the technological advances of the past four decades and quantify the incumbency advantage and the partisan advantage. Keywords: Tullock contest, nonparametric identification, structural econometrics, U.S. House of Representatives elections JEL codes: C57, D72 We thank Yanqin Fan, Fahad Khalil, Yasutora Watanabe, Quan Wen, and seminar participants at University of Washington for valuable comments and suggestions. We are very grateful to Professor Gary Jacobson for sharing his data with us. Economics Discipline Group, University of Technology Sydney, Box 23, Ultimo, NSW, 27, AU. Department of Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, Hong Kong.

2 Introduction Contest games, including all-pay auctions as a special case, formalize strategic interactions among players and have wide applicability in studies of competitive environments. Beginning with the seminal works of Tullock (967, 98), contest theory has been developed in recent decades and has provided profound insights into a wide class of applications. For instance, in a rent-seeking process, lobbyists exert effort to compete for political resources (Tullock, 967, 98; Krueger, 974; Becker, 983; Baye et al., 993); in a lawsuit, both the plaintiff and the defendant hire attorneys in order to obtain a favorable judgment (Baye et al., 25; Skaperdas and Vaidya, 22); and in research, time and money are spent to file patents or compete for research award (Taylor, 995; Che and Gale, 23). Other examples include sports (Szymanski, 23), military conflicts (Hwang, 22), labor market promotions (Connelly et al., 24), college admissions (Bodoh-Creed and Hickman, 25), and Internet marketplaces (Wang and Xu, 26), among others. Congleton et al. (28) and Vojnović (26) provide comprehensive surveys of contest theory and its applications. In a standard contest model, each player exerts costly effort to compete for a prize that she may not be awarded. The efforts of all players are mapped onto winning probabilities by a contest success function (CSF), which is a probabilistic allocation rule reflecting the nature of the competitive environment. On the one hand, if the player who exerts the highest effort wins the prize for certain, the contest reduces to an all-pay auction and is referred to as perfectly discriminating (Hillman and Riley, 989). On the other hand, most contests are imperfectly discriminating: a player s effort positively influences her winning probability but does not guarantee a win, even she exerts the most effort (Skaperdas, 996). For example, the army that incurs most casualties may not win the battle; the company that spends the most resources might not win a patent race; and the candidate who spends the most money on a campaign may not win the election. Depending on whether a player knows her competitors private information, there are contest models with complete or incomplete information. For contests with complete information, there is a large body of theoretical literature, for example, Ellingsen (99), Che and Gale (998), and Siegel (29), among many others. There are also a few structural empirical studies that focus on the estimation of parametric CSFs. For example, Hwang (22) uses data on spending in military conflicts to estimate the CSF. Kang (26) studies lobbying activities in the U.S. energy sector and shows how spending affects voting outcomes. In this paper, we focus on contest models with incomplete information, in which the In addition, there are also some reduced-form empirical studies of contests. For example, Jia (28) and Malueg and Yates (2) study data from sports, and Jia and Skaperdas (22) study data from military conflicts. 2

3 Bayesian Nash equilibrium (BNE) quantifies how each player chooses spending (effort) based on her realized type and knowledge about other players. 2 According to Fearon (995), given the opportunity to negotiate and settle, incomplete information is the main reason why a conflict situation turns into a war. In the theoretical literature on incomplete-information contests, Hurley and Shogren (998b), Malueg and Yates (24), and Sui (29) consider contests in which players have discrete types. Harstad (995), Hurley and Shogren (998a), and Schoonbeek and Winkel (26) analyze contests with one-sided private information. Wärneryd (23) studies a two-player contest for a prize with common but uncertain value. Ewerhart (2) finds a closed-form equilibrium in a two-sided private information contest for a particular family of continuous type distributions. Fey (28) establishes the existence of equilibrium in a two-player contest with uniformly distributed types. Ryvkin (2) extends the result in Fey (28) to cases with multiple players and general distribution functions. Ewerhart (24) establishes the uniqueness of the equilibrium in both symmetric and asymmetric environments. We study the identification, estimation, and inference of model primitives in a Tullock contest with asymmetric and privately-informed players. To the best of our knowledge, there is no previous study on identification and structural estimation of incomplete-information contest models, despite their importance and wide applicability. Our modeling framework uses contest data to unveil the distributions of players types as the model primitives, 3 which might reflect the state of contest-relevant technologies and factors that affect players ex ante positions. 4 Learning the model primitives of a competitive environment by using structural econometric analysis is crucial for policy intervention and contest design. Our contributions to the literature are in threefold. First, we establish nonparametric identification of the quantile functions (or equivalently the distribution functions) of players private cost signals. Our identification analysis is related to that in the structural auction literature. For example, Guerre et al. (2) consider the first-price sealed-bid auction and identify the private value distribution by the distribution of bids. 5 2 Baik and Shogren (995) and Kovenock et al. (25) note that information acquisition and sharing have a significant impact on the equilibrium effort. 3 This private type can be treated as either a private cost signal or a private prize value. See additional discussion in Section 2. As a first step, we assume a known CSF and focus on the distributions of players types. More generally, considering an unknown CSF under the incomplete information framework is very interesting and challenging. We leave this for future research. 4 For example, in political campaigns, the distributions can reflect campaign-relevant technologies such as printing and advertisement. They can also reflect candidates ex ante positions such as incumbency and partisan advantages. 5 A Tullock contest game differs from a standard auction in the allocation rule and the payment rule. In a Tullock contest, the allocation rule is probabilistic, and the payment rule has the all-pay structure, while in 3

4 Second, we develop estimators for the quantile functions of private cost signals, establish their consistency, root-n asymptotic normality, and propose estimators for the asymptotic variances. Through Monte Carlo simulations, we find that our estimators and confidence intervals (CIs) perform reasonably well in finite sample. Third, we apply our method to study several questions using data from U.S. House of Representatives elections. All previous studies, such as Jacobson (978) and Levitt (994), focus on the reduced-form relationship of how campaign spending affects the election outcome. We analyze two sub-samples corresponding to incumbent-versus-challenger elections and open-seat elections. By taking into account the game theoretical structure explicitly and nonparametrically estimating the distributions of cost signals, our results shed light on the following issues. First, the estimates suggest that the distributions of private cost signals have evolved in a roughly decreasing manner in terms of first-order stochastic dominance over the past four decades, which may be attributed to advances in technologies related to campaign costs. Second, based on the estimated quantile functions, we quantify the incumbency advantage as the gap between candidates equilibrium winning probabilities given either their cost signals or spending. For example, in the 2s, a median-type incumbent wins with a probability of 6.8%, while a median-type challenger wins only with a probability of 22.5%. Third, we similarly quantify the partisan advantage. We find that a candidate from one party has an advantage over one from the other party within a decade, and this advantage switches across decades. This pattern is roughly in line with the political atmosphere in each period. For example, in the 97s, Republicans were at a serious disadvantage because of the Watergate scandal, the collapse of the Nixon administration, and the unpopular pardon of the former president by Ford. During this period, for two candidates who spent an average amount of money, the Democratic candidate s winning probability was 3.2% higher than that of the Republican candidate. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the asymmetric Tullock contest model with incomplete information. Section 3 provides the key identification result for the model primitives. In Section 4, we propose nonparametric estimators for the quantile functions and establish their asymptotic properties. In Section 5, we conduct simulations to evaluate the finite sample performance of the estimators and CIs. Empirical analysis of the U.S. House election campaign is conducted in Section 6. Concluding remarks are provided in Section 7 and all proofs are relegated to the Appendix. standard auctions, such as first-price or second-price sealed-bid auctions, the allocation rule is deterministic and the payment rule has a winner-pay structure. 4

5 2 The Model There are L risk-neutral players and their private cost signals, C = (C,, C L ), are independent but not identically distributed. C l has CDF F l ( ) and Lebesgue density function f l ( ) on the support C l = [c l, c l ]. 6 F l (or its quantile function Q l ), l =,, L, reflect the state of contest-relevant technologies and factors affecting players ex ante positions. Denote the spending vector for all players as b = (b,, b L ). Given that player l s realized private cost is C l = c and the spending vector is b, her ex post expected payoff is π l (c, b) = p l (b) cφ(b l ), (2.) where p l (b) = b l / L j= b j is the well-known Tullock CSF. The prize is normalized to be one, and φ is a known baseline cost function with φ >, φ and can take different forms such as linear or quadratic. Note that, in the above formulation, we adopt a private cost signal framework instead of a private prize value one due to the equivalence of the two setups. Therefore, the prize of the contest game is normalized to be one without loss of generality, and the spending should be interpreted as spending per unit of prize. 7 Given φ and p = (p,, p L ), the model primitives are F = (F,, F L ), the private cost signal distributions. Let the BNE spending functions be β( ) = (β ( ),, β L ( )). Given that C l = c and other players follow their BNE strategies, player l s interim expected payoff is [ b l πl (b l, c; β) = E b l + j l β j(c j ) cφ(b l) C l = c [ ] = E b l + j l β b l cφ(b l ). (2.2) j(c j ) 6 c l is allowed to be, in which case C l = [c l, ). 7 To see this, we can divide the ex post expected payoff function by c and define v = /c. We obtain vp l (b) φ(b l ). Moreover, by a monotone transformation of the spending: e l = φ(b l ), the payoff function is strategically equivalent to vφ (e l )/ L j= φ (e j ) e l. See Cornes and Hartley (25), Ryvkin (2), and Wasser (23) for details. Skaperdas (996) shows that, the relevant CSF, φ (e l )/ L j= φ (e j ), is equivalent to assuming five basic axioms of a contest, for example, p l (b) = e r l / L j= er j, r >. ] 5

6 By the definition of BNE, β must satisfy [ ] πl (β l (c), c; β) = E b l [β l (c) + j l β β j(c j )] 2 l (c) [ ] + E β l (c) + j l β cφ (β l (c)) = (c), (2.3) j(c j ) where ( ) is the zero function. The existence and uniqueness of β are established in Ryvkin (2) and Ewerhart (24). Example. Let L = 2, φ(x) = x, and the CDFs of private costs be F l (c), l =, 2, with quantile functions Q (τ) = a log + a τ τ + a τ, Q a( τ) + 2(τ) = log, τ (, ), a( τ) a( τ) + where a > is a parameter. In this case, (2.3) becomes [ˆ c2 (β (c) + β 2 (c 2 )) 2 df 2(c 2 ) c 2 [ˆ c c (β (c ) + β 2 (c)) df (c 2 ) ] ] β (c) + β 2 (c) + ˆ c2 β (c) + β 2 (c 2 ) df 2(c 2 ) c = (c), c 2 ˆ c c β (c ) + β 2 (c) df (c ) c = (c), where c = log(a+) a +a, c 2 = log a+ a a+, and c = c 2 =. It can be shown that the unique solution is β (c) = F (c), c [c, ), β 2 (c) = a( F 2 (c)), c [c 2, ). Figure illustrates the quantile functions and equilibrium spending functions for two players when a = 2. Note that β l ( ) < because a higher type corresponds to a weaker player.8 The equilibrium spending functions are determined by the quantile functions of cost signals, so are the distributions of equilibrium spending. In the next section, we establish nonparametric identification of the primitive distributions using the observed distributions. 8 Alternatively, if we adopt a private prize value framework, the equilibrium spending function will be increasing in a player s valuation. 6

7 Figure : Illustration of Example 3 Identification Given n independent and identical plays of the contest game, we obtain a random sample {B i,, B il } n i= of equilibrium spending, where B i,, B il are independent but not identically distributed, with B il = β l (C il ), l =,, L. Then the CDFs G l (b) and PDFs g l (b) of B il are directly identified from the data. For τ (, ), t l (, ) L, let q l (τ) = G l (τ), Q l (τ) = F l (τ), ω l (τ, t l ) = q l (τ) + k l q k (t k ), and δ lj (τ) = ˆ ω j l (τ, t l) dt l, for j =, 2, 3, where dt l = dt dt l dt l+ dt L. Assumption. For l =,, L, F l (c) is continuous and strictly increasing on C l = [c l, c l ]. In the equilibrium, one player s spending is monotonically decreasing in her cost signal. The probability of observing a spending higher than b is G l (b) = P(B l b) = P(β l (B l ) β l (b)) = F l (β l (b)). A change of variables gives q l ( F l (c)) = β l (c). (3.) Equation (3.) is the key to identifying F l from the observed bid distributions. Theorem. For l =,, L, under Assumption, the quantile functions of private costs 7

8 are nonparametrically identified as Q l (τ) = Proof. See the Appendix. [ ] δ φ l ( τ) q l ( τ)δ l2 ( τ), τ (, ). (3.2) (q l ( τ)) Learning the cost signal distributions is very meaningful for policy reference. For example, the contest designer of a patent race can induce the desired distribution of equilibrium spending by adjusting the prize; likewise, an international organization can discourage military conflict between two countries by imposing the proper amount of economic sanctions. Example (Continued). By (3.) and the fact that β (c) = F (c) and β 2 (c) = a( F 2 (c)), we obtain q (τ) = τ, q 2 (τ) = aτ for τ (, ). Then ω (τ, t ) = τ + at 2 for (τ, t 2 ) (, ) 2, ω 2 (τ, t 2 ) = aτ + t for (τ, t ) (, ) 2, and δ (τ) = a log τ + a, δ 2 (τ) = τ Therefore, by (3.2), we obtain τ(τ + a), δ 2(τ) = log aτ +, δ 22 (τ) = aτ Q (τ) = δ ( τ) q ( τ)δ 2 ( τ) = a log + a τ τ a( τ) + Q 2 (τ) = δ 2 ( τ) q 2 ( τ)δ 22 ( τ) = log a( τ) + a τ, aτ(aτ + ). a( τ) +. 4 Estimation and Inference In this section, we propose estimators for the quantile functions of private cost signals, study their asymptotic properties, namely, consistency and asymptotic normality, and propose estimators for the asymptotic variances. Let B (k:n) l denote the k-th lowest order statistic out of the n i.i.d. spending from player l and denote the ceiling function. Let q l (τ) be the empirical quantile estimator of q l (τ) using {B il } n i=, that is, q l (τ) = B ( nτ :n) l. Assumption 2. For l =,, L, (a) G l ( ) is strictly increasing and twice differentiable with compact support [b L l, bu l ], where bl l and sup g l (q l(τ)) <. τ (,) ; (b) inf τ (,) g l(q l (τ)) >, sup g l (q l(τ)) <, τ (,) Assumption 3. For l =,, L and τ (, ), the diagonal elements of Σ l (τ) are finite, with Σ l (τ) defined in (A.2). 8

9 Assumption 4. For l =,, L, (a) g l has an r-th continuous bounded derivative on [b L l, bu l ], r =, 2; (b) K is a second-order symmetric kernel function with support [, ] and a twice continuous and bounded derivative; (c) the bandwidth h l satisfies < h l < (b U l bl l )/2, h l, nh l / log n as n ; (d) h l = O(h l ), / nh 3 l = O(h l), h l = O(h l ), α l > /3, where h l, h l, h l, and α l are defined in Lemma A.2. Assumption 2 imposes standard conditions from the statistical literature to ensure uniform convergence of the empirical quantile function on (, ). Assumption 3 is the standard regularity assumption to invoke the multivariate central limit theorem for the i.i.d. sequence. Assumption 4 is adapted from Li and Liu (25) to make use of their boundary-corrected kernel estimator for the density functions of equilibrium spending, so that we obtain uniform convergence for the associated quantile density estimators. Let ω l (τ, t l ) = q l (τ) + k l q k (t k ), δ lj (τ) = ˆ ω j l (τ, t l) dt l, j =, 2, 3, and Q l (τ) = [ δl ( τ) q φ l ( τ) δ l2 ( τ)]. (4.) ( q l ( τ)) Theorem 2. For l =,, L and τ (, ), under Assumption 2, Q l (τ) Q l (τ) = o P (). Proof. See the Appendix. Next, we establish the asymptotic distribution related to Q l (τ). Theorem 3. Under Assumptions 2 and 3, for l =,, L and τ (, ), ( ) ) d n Ql (τ) Q l (τ) N(, Ω l ( τ) where Ω l (τ) = A T l (τ)σ l(τ)a l (τ), and A l (τ), Σ l (τ) are defined in (A.) and (A.2). Proof. See the Appendix. Next, we show that the asymptotic covariance function can be consistently estimated. 9

10 Theorem 4. Under Assumptions 2 and 4, for l =,, L and τ (, ), Ω l (τ) Ω l (τ) = o P (), where Ω l (τ) = ÂT l (τ) Σ l (τ)âl(τ), and Âl(τ), Σ l (τ) are defined in (A.3) and (A.4). Proof. See the Appendix. 5 Simulation In this section, we conduct Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate the finite sample performance of the estimators and the CIs. We use the same setup as in Example. We set L = 2, φ(x) = x. The private costs are independent and with distribution functions F ( ) and F 2 ( ) associated with quantile functions Q (τ) = a log + a τ τ + a τ and Q a( τ) + 2(τ) = log a( τ) a( τ) +. Note that Q () = log(a+) a +a, Q 2() = log a+ a a+, and Q () = Q 2 () =. Let a {, 2, 4}, n {, 5, }, and the number of repetitions be 2 for each design. By (4.), we have Q l (τ) = δ l ( τ) q l ( τ) δ l2 ( τ), l =, 2, where δ lj ( τ) = [ q l ( τ)+ k l q k(t k dt )] j l for j =, 2, 3. In estimating the asymptotic covariance matrix, we use kernel function K(u) = 2 ( u ), and set h l = ( log(n) n ) 5, h l = n 5, h l = 3.87h l, and α l = In Tables, 2, and 3, for the quantile functions evaluated at levels τ =.,.3,,.9, we report the estimated bias and root mean squared error (RMSE) of the estimators, and the empirical coverage probability (ECP) and the empirical interval length (EIL) of the 95% point-wise confidence intervals (CIs). The results are similar, and we focus on Table in the discussion. For the estimators, first, the bias and RMSE at a given quantile level decrease as the sample size increases. For example, when τ =.5, the biases and RMSEs of Q (τ) are.46,.3,.4 and.344,.53,.6 when n =, 5,, while those of Q 2 (τ) are 9 It is easy to see that in this case, c K = 3.87, where c K is defined in (A.5).

11 .54,.7,.2 and.277,.9,.79 when n =, 5,. Second, in our design, the estimation is more precise for the lower quantile level than for the upper quantile level. For example, when n = 5, the RMSEs of Q (τ) are.45,.89,.53,.27,.67 for quantile levels τ =.,.3,,.9, and those of Q 2 (τ) have a similar pattern. For the CIs, first, the ECPs are very close to the nominal levels in most cases, except for a few under coverage when n =. We attribute this to finite sample approximation error. In fact, the ECPs improve as the sample size increases. Second, the EILs increase with the quantile level due to a larger estimation error at the higher quantile level. In Figure 2, we graph the estimated quantile functions and the 95% point-wise CIs for τ {.,.2,,.99}, each curve is averaged across all the repetitions. First, the estimated curves are very close to the true quantile function in all cases. Second, the confidence bands tend to be wide at upper quantiles when n =, but they become increasingly tight as the sample size increases. In sum, our estimators and CIs perform reasonably well. Table : Performance of Estimators and CIs (a = ) ˆQ (τ) ˆQ2 (τ) n τ Bias RMSE ECP EIL Bias RMSE ECP EIL This is because, for our design, it can be shown analytically that Ω l ( τ) increases as τ increases.

12 Table 2: Performance of Estimators and CIs (a = 2) ˆQ (τ) ˆQ2 (τ) n τ Bias RMSE ECP EIL Bias RMSE ECP EIL Table 3: Performance of Estimators and CIs (a = 4) ˆQ (τ) ˆQ2 (τ) n τ Bias RMSE ECP EIL Bias RMSE ECP EIL

13 Figure 2: Mean Estimates and Point-wise CIs for Quantile Functions 6 Empirical Analysis of U.S. House Elections Every two years, elections are held to elect representatives from 435 congressional districts across all states in the U.S. The outcomes are determined by popular vote and are highly influenced by candidates campaign spending. Political campaigns have been modeled as contests since the beginning of contest theory (Baron, 994; Skaperdas and Grofman, 995). In this section, we use the structural estimation method to study election campaigns for the 3

14 U.S. House of Representatives. Our data set covers twenty House election cycles from the 93rd Congress (972 election) to the 2th Congress (2 election). The following questions are of great interest: First, for a generic candidate, the distribution function of her private cost signal reflects the state of technologies related to political campaigns: therefore, how has these technologies changed in the past decades? Second, while it has been argued that competition is desired in political campaigns, the incumbent usually has an advantage over the challenger in terms of fundraising ability and reputation. This incumbency advantage can be learned by comparing the distribution functions of candidates cost signals. How great is the incumbency advantage? Does the amount of spending affect the equilibrium vote shares or winning probabilities differently for an incumbent and a challenger? Third, the political atmosphere may change across election cycles. Is there any partisan advantage for a candidate, say a Democrat, during a certain period? Does the amount of spending affect the equilibrium vote shares or winning probabilities differently for Democratic and Republican candidates? In the following, we analyze the data and uncover the primitives of the election contests, which allows us to quantify technological changes and to assess the incumbency and partisan advantages. To answer the above questions, we focus on two sub-samples. To quantify the incumbency advantage, we use an incumbent-challenger sub-sample of 5776 elections. To quantify the partisan advantage, we use an open-seat sub-sample of 853 elections. To quantify the potential changes in the model primitives, we further divide each sub-sample by decades in accordance with the timing of electoral redistricting Incumbent-versus-Challenger Elections For the incumbent-challenger sub-sample, descriptive statistics are provided in Table 4 and Figure 3. All spending data are in thousands of 29 dollars for rest of this paper. Figure 3(A) depicts the trend in spending, averaged across all the contests in a given election cycle. It shows that levels of campaign spending increase over time. Given that spending is a decreasing function of the private cost signal, this pattern indicates that the private cost has tended to decrease in recent decades. Figure 3(B) depicts the proportion of incumbents spending and their winning probability. On average, incumbents spend more than twice what challengers do. Incumbents receive, on average, 64.3% of votes, and more than 9% of incumbents are reelected. It is clear that an incumbent has certain advantage over a U.S. House election data have been well documented by the Federal Election Commission since 972 ( 2 Electoral district boundaries are redrawn at the beginning of each decade. The 97s sub-sample contains five election cycles: 972, 974, 976, 978, and 98. The same occurs for other decades. For details, see redistricting.lls.edu. 4

15 challenger. We expect that this advantage will be reflected in the difference between the distributions of their private cost signals. In Table 5, we report two sets of reduced-form regression results. In Panel A, we report the results of linear regressions of the incumbent s vote share on her spending and the challenger s spending. In Panel B, we use election outcomes as the binary dependent variable and report the results of logistic regressions. On the one hand, the reduced-form results suggest a negative and statistically significant effect of the challenger s spending on the incumbent s vote share or winning probability, which is consistent with economic intuition. On the other hand, these results suggest either a small but statistically insignificant positive effect or a moderate and significant negative effect of the incumbent s own spending on her vote share or winning probability. Table 4: Summary Statistics (Incumbent-challenger) Obs Mean SD Min Max Incumbent spending Challenger spending Incumbent vote share (%)* Incumbent wins dummy * There are 5 missing values for the incumbent vote share. Figure 3: Descriptive Statistics (Incumbent-challenger) 5

16 Table 5: Reduced-form Results (Incumbent-challenger) All 97s 98s 99s 2s Panel A: OLS Dependent variable: vote share of Incumbent Incumbent spending -.8** ** -.64** -.779** (.2) (.) (.547) (.365) (.227) Challenger spending -.72** -.26** ** ** -.443** (.2) (.) (.688) (.474) (.256) R Obs Panel B: Logit Dependent variable: = Incumbent wins Incumbent spending..* ** (.) (.) (.342) (.96) (.3) Challenger spending -.3** -.4** ** -.65** -.69** (.) (.) (.339) (.22) (.) McFadden pseudo R Obs Note: * p <.5, ** p <.. Figure 4: Money-vote Relation (Incumbent-challenger) This counter-intuitive result is in line with Jacobson (978, 99), Abramowitz (988), and Figure 4. One explanation is that the candidates campaign spending varies with the competitiveness of an election. On the one hand, a weak challenger does not spend much and would not provide a strong incentive for an incumbent to spend. On the other hand, a 6

17 strong challenger would push an incumbent to fight for her incumbency and still convert a fair proportion of the incumbent s vote. Reduced-form regressions do not take into account the endogeneity issue caused by the strategic interactions, as argued in Erikson and Palfrey (2). We emphasize that levels of spending are simultaneously determined by the equilibrium of a contest game, which further determines the equilibrium winning probabilities. Next, we structurally estimate the quantile functions of cost signals and use the results to quantify how a candidate s realized cost signal or campaign spending determines her equilibrium winning probability. Figure 6 reports the estimated quantile functions and CIs. First, from the two upper panels, the incumbent and the challenger s estimated quantile functions have both shifted outwards in the past four decades. There is a first-order stochastic dominance relationship: the private cost signals become more and more concentrated at lower values. Advances in technologies related to political campaigns are a possible explanation. For example, laser printers have been introduced to replace the mimeograph machines, and e- mail serves as a substitute for paper mail in campaign advertisements. Second, from the four lower panels, there is a large gap between the two estimated quantile functions, which clearly reflects the incumbency advantage: the incumbent s cost signal is first-order stochastically dominated by the challenger s cost signal. This summarizes the overall advantage of the incumbent in terms of fundraising ability and the effect of reputation, etc. Next, define the equilibrium [ winning probabilities ] [ given the cost ] signal or spending β to be P(l wins c) = E l (C l ) β l (C l )+ C q j l β j(c j ) l = c = E l ( F l (c)) q l ( F l (c))+ or P(l wins b) = j l B j [ ] [ ] E = E, respectively. These two quantities are different from the b b+ j l β j(c j ) b b+ j l B j CSF. Instead of ex post winning probability, they take into account the strategic interactions and the equilibrium concept, and provide players with expected winning probabilities given their private signals or spending levels. We estimate them by P(l wins c) = n P(l wins b) = n n q l ( F l (c)) q l ( F l (c)) + j l B, ij (6.) n b b + j l B. ij (6.2) i= i= The estimation results are summarized in Figures 5 and 7. Figure 5 shows that the equilibrium winning probability is decreasing and convex in a candidate s own cost signal, which suggests increasing return to a lower cost signal. 3 It also 3 Given the state of contest-relevant technologies and other factors that affect players ex ante positions, a candidate s realized cost signal can be interpreted as her ability. 7

18 quantifies the incumbency advantage. If the incumbent and the challenger have the same cost signal, their chances of winning can be very different. For example, in the 2s, for an incumbent and a challenger with the median type (c =.54), the incumbent wins with a probability of 6.8% and the challenger wins with a probability of only 22.5%. Figure 7 shows that equilibrium winning probability is increasing and concave in a candidate s own spending, and also quantifies the incumbency advantage. For example, in the 2s, by spending the average amount of money (b = 962), an incumbent wins with a probability of 77.6% and a challenger wins with a probability of only 45.9%. Therefore, even if the challenger has no disadvantage in campaign funding, her winning probability is 3.7% lower than that of the incumbent. This might be attributed to the effect of reputation. Figure 5: Equilibrium Winning Probability Given Cost Signal (Incumbent-challenger) 8

19 Figure 6: Quantile Estimates and CIs by Period (Incumbent-challenger) 9

20 Figure 7: Equilibrium Winning Probability Given Spending (Incumbent-challenger) 6.2 Open-seat Elections For the open-seat sub-sample, descriptive statistics are provided in Table 6 and Figure 8. Figure 8(A) depicts the trends in spending, averaged across all the contests in a given election cycle. It shows that the levels of campaign spending increase over time, which again suggests that the private cost tended to decrease in recent decades. It also shows that the candidates from the two parties spend similar amounts of money on average. Figure 8(B) depicts the proportion of spending by Democratic candidates and that of elections they win: these two proportions are similar. This observation supports the ratio-form CSF of 2

21 Tullock (98), 4 which implies that a contestant s proportion of total spending determines her winning probability. Table 6: Summary Statistics (Open-seat) Obs Mean SD Min Max Democrat spending Republican spending Democrat vote share (%) Democrat wins dummy * There is missing value for the Democrat vote share. Figure 8: Descriptive Statistics (Open-seat) In Table 7, we report two sets of reduced-form regression results. In Panel A, we regress the vote share received by the Democrat candidate on her spending and the Republican candidate s spending. In Panel B, we use the election outcomes as the dependent variable and perform logistic regressions. The results from the two panels lead to similar conclusions: First, as suggested by the signs of the estimates, a candidate s own spending has a positive effect on her campaign outcome and a negative effect on the opponent s outcome. Therefore, the counter-intuitive phenomenon in Table 5 disappears after putting aside the incumbency advantage. Second, across decades, the magnitude of marginal effect of one extra unit of spending decreases. This is also consistent with the ratio-form CSF of Tullock (98), which implies that the winning probability is determined by the spending ratio. In later decades, 4 Another popular CSF is the difference form, which means that the difference in spending determines the winning probability. See Jia et al. (23). 2

22 both parties spend more; hence, an extra unit of spending by one side has a smaller effect on the ratio. Table 7: Reduced-form Results (Open-seat) All 97s 98s 99s 2s Panel A: OLS Dependent variable: vote share of Incumbent Democrat spending.**.463**.38**.3775**.592** (.) (.224) (.4) (.8) (.73) Republic spending -.** ** ** -.639** -.44** (.) (.25) (.655) (.879) (.788) R Obs Panel B: Logit Dependent variable: = Democrat wins Democrat spending.7**.2998**.355**.223**.345** (.2) (.583) (.62) (.324) (.239) Republic spending -.23** -.535** -.392** -.87** -.4** (.2) (.796) (.679) (.332) (.282) McFadden pseudo R Obs Note: * p <.5, ** p <.. Figure 9 summarizes and compares the estimated quantile functions for all periods and for candidates from both parties. First, from the two upper panels, there is a rough first-order stochastic dominance relationship across decades for candidates from both parties, which again might be explained by technological advances. 5 Second, from the four lower panels, we see an insightful pattern that the partisan advantage switches every ten years. This pattern roughly corresponds to the political atmosphere and the president s partisanship during each period. For example, in the 97s, the Republicans were at a serious disadvantage because of the Watergate scandal, the collapse of the Nixon administration, and the unpopular pardon of the former president by Ford. In the 98s, the advantage switched back to the Republicans when Ronald Reagan was in office. The Democrats had the advantage when Bill Clinton was in office during the 99s, while the Republicans had it when George Bush was in office during most of the 2s. Next, similar to the incumbent-challenger sub-sample, we use the estimated quantile 5 However, it is both interesting and puzzling to see that this stochastic dominance relationship does not hold for Democrat candidates between the 99s and 2s, and Republican candidates between the 98s and 99s. 22

23 functions to compute the relationships between either the private cost signal or spending and the equilibrium winning probability by (6.) and (6.2), respectively. Figure shows that the equilibrium winning probability is decreasing and convex in a candidate s own cost signal, and it quantifies the partisan advantage. Moreover, the partisan advantage is higher among high-cost-signal candidates, which suggests that for candidates with lower ability, partisanship plays a more important role in determining the election outcome. In Figure, the equilibrium winning probability is increasing and concave in spending. 6 It also quantifies the partisan advantage. For example, in the 97s, if Democratic and Republican candidates spent the average amount of money (b = 425) on their campaigns, they would win with probabilities of 57.4% and 54.2%, respectively. The 3.2% difference in the winning probabilities reflects the political atmosphere during that era. 6 For the 99s, although the gap is small, the equilibrium winning probability curve for the Democrats is strictly above that of the Republicans at all spending levels. 23

24 Figure 9: Quantile Estimates and CIs by Period (Open-seat) 24

25 Figure : Equilibrium Winning Probability Given Cost Signal (Open-seat) 25

26 Figure : Equilibrium Winning Probability Given Spending (Open-seat) 7 Conclusion In this paper, we study the econometrics of an asymmetric Tullock contest model with incomplete information. We establish nonparametric identification of the distributions of players private cost signals. We propose estimators for the quantile functions, establish their consistency, and develop an asymptotic inference procedure. Monte Carlo experiments are conducted to show the good finite sample performance of our estimators and CIs. We apply our method to data from U.S. House of Representatives elections. While all previous studies focus on the reduced-form relationship between campaign spending and election outcomes, we treat candidates campaign spending as equilibrium outcomes of the 26

27 underlying contest game with incomplete information. Our empirical results offer the following insights: First, the structural estimates of quantile functions across periods suggest that the distributions of private cost signals have evolved roughly in a decreasing manner in terms of first-order stochastic dominance over the past four decades. This phenomenon may be attributed to advances in technologies related to campaign costs. Second, the estimated quantile functions shed light on the incumbency advantage, which might be attributed to incumbents fundraising ability and reputation. We further quantify this advantage by the gap between equilibrium winning probabilities for incumbents and challengers. Third, we find that candidates from one party tend to have an advantage over those from the other party within a decade, and this advantage switches across decades. This pattern is roughly in line with the political atmosphere of each period. This paper yields several avenues for future research. First, we focused on the case with independent private cost signals, but in reality, private values or costs could be correlated, which highlights the need to study a contest model with correlated private types. The existence and uniqueness of equilibrium, identification, estimation, and inference in this situation is of great interest to study. Second, from an empirical perspective, it would be useful to employ our method to answer questions in other contest games, such as how research investments affect patent race outcomes, and how litigation spending affects the results of lawsuits. 27

28 References Abramowitz, Alan I, Explaining Senate Election Outcomes, American Political Science Review, 988, 82 (2), Bahadur, R Raj, A Note on Quantiles in Large Samples, The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 966, 37 (3), Baik, Kyung Hwan and Jason F Shogren, Contests with Spying, European Journal of Political Economy, 995, (3), Baron, David P, Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters, American Political Science Review, 994, 88 (), Baye, Michael R, Dan Kovenock, and Casper G De Vries, Rigging the Lobbying Process: an Application of the All-Pay Auction, American Economic Review, 993, 83 (), ,, and, Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach, Economic Journal, 25, 5 (55), Becker, Gary S, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 983, 98 (3), Bodoh-Creed, Aaron and Brent R Hickman, College Assignment as a Large Contest, Working Paper, 25. Che, Yeon-Koo and Ian L Gale, Caps on Political Lobbying, American Economic Review, 998, 88 (3), and, Optimal Design of Research Contests, American Economic Review, 23, 93 (3), Congleton, Roger D, Arye L Hillman, and Kai A Konrad, 4 Years of Research on Rent Seeking, Vol. & 2, Springer, 28. Connelly, Brian L, Laszlo Tihanyi, T Russell Crook, and K Ashley Gangloff, Tournament Theory Thirty Years of Contests and Competitions, Journal of Management, 24, 4 (), Cornes, Richard and Roger Hartley, Asymmetric Contests with General Technologies, Economic Theory, 25, 26 (4),

29 Csörgo, Miklós, Quantile processes with statistical applications. CBMS-NSF Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics, 42, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, 983. der Vaart, Aad W Van, Asymptotic Statistics, Vol. 3, Cambridge University Press, 2. Ellingsen, Tore, Strategic Buyers and the Social Cost of Monopoly, American Economic Review, 99, 8 (3), Erikson, Robert S and Thomas R Palfrey, Equilibria in Campaign Spending Games: Theory and Data, American Political Science Review, 2, 94 (3), Ewerhart, Christian, Rent-Seeking Contests with Independent Private Values, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper, 2, (49)., Unique Equilibrium in Rent-Seeking Contests with a Continuum of Types, Economics Letters, 24, 25 (), 5 8. Fearon, James D, Rationalist Explanations for War, International Organization, 995, 49 (3), Fey, Mark, Rent-Seeking Contests with Incomplete Information, Public Choice, 28, 35 (3-4), Guerre, Emmanuel, Isabelle Perrigne, and Quang Vuong, Optimal Nonparametric Estimation of First-Price Auctions, Econometrica, 2, 68 (3), Harstad, Ronald M, Privately Informed Seekers of an Uncertain Rent, Public Choice, 995, 83 (-2), Hillman, Arye L and John G Riley, Politically Contestable Rents and Transfers, Economics & Politics, 989, (), Hurley, Terrance M and Jason F Shogren, Asymmetric Information Contests, European Journal of Political Economy, 998, 4 (4), and, Effort Levels in a Cournot Nash Contest with Asymmetric Information, Journal of Public Economics, 998, 69 (2), Hwang, Sung-Ha, Technology of Military Conflict, Military Spending, and War, Journal of Public Economics, 22, 96 (),

30 Jacobson, Gary C, The Effects of Campaign Spending in Congressional Elections, American Political Science Review, 978, pp , The Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections: New Evidence for Old Arguments, American Journal of Political Science, 99, pp Jia, Hao, An Empirical Study of Contest Success Functions: Evidence From the NBA, Working Paper, 28. and Stergios Skaperdas, Technologies of Conflict, Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Peace and Conflict, 22, p. 449.,, and Samarth Vaidya, Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23, 3 (3), Kang, Karam, Policy Influence and Private Returns from Lobbying in the Energy Sector, Review of Economic Studies, 26, 83 (), Kiefer, J, On Bahadur s Representation of Sample Quantiles, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 967, 38 (5), , Deviations Between the Sample Quantile Process and the Sample Df, Nonparametric Techniques in Statistical Inference, 97, pp Kovenock, Dan, Florian Morath, and Johannes Münster, Information Sharing in Contests, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 25, 24 (3), Krueger, Anne O, The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, American Economic Review, 974, 64 (3), Levitt, Steven D, Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending On Election Outcomes in the U.S. House, Journal of Political Economy, 994, pp Li, Huihui and Nianqing Liu, Nonparametric Identification and Estimation of Double Auctions with Bargaining, Working Paper, 25. Malueg, David A and Andrew J Yates, Rent Seeking with Private Values, Public Choice, 24, 9 (-2), and, Testing Contest Theory: Evidence From Best-of-Three Tennis Matches, Review of Economics and Statistics, 2, 92 (3),

31 Ryvkin, Dmitry, Contests with Private Costs: Beyond Two Players, European Journal of Political Economy, 2, 26 (4), Schoonbeek, Lambert and Barbara M Winkel, Activity and Inactivity in a Rent- Seeking Contest with Private Information, Public Choice, 26, 27 (-2), Shorack, Galen R and Jon A Wellner, Empirical Processes with Applications to Statistics, Vol. 59, SIAM, 29. Siegel, Ron, All-Pay Contests, Econometrica, 29, 77 (), Skaperdas, Stergios, Contest Success Functions, Economic theory, 996, 7 (2), and Bernard Grofman, Modeling Negative Campaigning, American Political Science Review, 995, 89 (), and Samarth Vaidya, Persuasion as a Contest, Economic Theory, 22, 5 (2), Sui, Yong, Rent-Seeking Contests with Private Values and Resale, Public Choice, 29, 38 (3-4), Szymanski, Stefan, The Economic Design of Sporting Contests, Journal of Economic Literature, 23, 4 (4), Taylor, CR, Digging for Golden Carrots: an Analysis of Research Tournaments, American Economic Review, 995, 85 (4). Tullock, G, Efficient Rent Seeking. In J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison and G. Tullock (Eds.), Towards a Theory of the Rent-seeking Society, Texas A&M University Press, 98. Tullock, Gordon, The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft, Economic Inquiry, 967, 5 (3), 224. Vojnović, Milan, Contest Theory: Incentive Mechanisms and Ranking Methods, Cambridge University Press, 26. Wang, Zhongmin and Minbo Xu, Empirical Evidence on Competition and Revenue in an All-Pay Contest, Review of Industrial Organization, 26, pp. 2. Wärneryd, Karl, Information in Conflicts, Journal of Economic Theory, 23, (),

32 Wasser, Cédric, Incomplete Information in Rent-Seeking Contests, Economic Theory, 23, 53 (), Zhang, S, RJ Karunamuni, and MC Jones, An Improved Estimator of the Density Function at the Boundary, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 999, 94 (448),

33 A Appendix Proof. (Theorem ) For l =,, L, let the operator T l be [ˆ ] c T l (c, β ; F, φ) = c [β l (c) + j l β j (c j)] df l(c l ) β 2 l (c) ˆ [ ] c + β l (c) + j l β j (c j) df l(c l ) cφ (β l (c)), c where β = (β,, β L ), with β l : C l R + to be the candidate functions, and c df c l(c l ) = c c l cl+ c L df c c l c l+ c (c ) df l (c l )df l+ (c l+ ) df L (c L ). The vector of equilibrium spending functions β = (β,, β L ) satisfies T l (c, β; F, φ) = (c), l =,, L L. Due to the facts that B il = β l (C il ) and β l ( ) is strictly decreasing, it is easy to show that G l (t) = F l (β l (t)), which implies that β l (s) = q l ( F l (s)). Plugging this equation into (2.3), we obtain [ˆ ] c c [q l ( F l (c)) + j l q j( F j (c j ))] df l(c 2 l ) q l ( F l (c)) ˆ [ ] c + q l ( F l (c)) + j l q j( F j (c j )) df l(c l ) cφ (q l ( F l (c))) = (c). c Under Assumption, we apply changes of variables F l (c) = τ (and thus c = Q l ( τ)), and F j (c j ) = t j, j l. Solving for Q l ( τ) yields Q l ( τ) = φ (q l (τ)) φ (q l (τ)) ˆ [ q l (τ) + j l q j(t j ) dt l [ δ l (τ) q l (τ)δ l2 (τ) ] ], τ (, ), where dt = dt dt l dt l+ dt L. [ˆ ] q l(τ) φ (q l (τ)) [q l (τ) + j l q j(t j )] dt 2 l Proof. (Theorem 2) Given any l =,, L and τ (, ), by the continuous mapping theorem, it suffices to show that (i) q l (τ) q l (τ) = o P (); (ii) δ lj (τ) δ lj (τ) = o P (), j =, 2, 3. Step (i): Under Assumption 2, sup τ (,) q l (τ) q l (τ) = o P () by Corollary.4. in Csörgo (983), which implies the point-wise convergence result. 33

34 Step (ii): for τ (, ), δ lj (τ) δ lj (τ) ˆ ω j l (τ, t l) ω j l (τ, t l) dt l ˆ () j ω j+ l (τ, t l ) ω l(τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) dt l (2) [ j q l (τ) q l (τ) + ] ˆ sup q k (t k ) q k (t k ) k l t k (,) [ j q l (τ) q l (τ) + ][ sup q k (t k ) q k (t k ) k l t k (,) (3) = o P ()O P () = o P (), j =, 2, 3, ω j+ l (τ, t l ) dt l inf ω l (τ, t l ) t l (,) L where () is by Taylor expansion with ω l (τ, t l ) between ω l (τ, t l ) and ω l (τ, t l ), (2) is by the Triangle inequality, and (3) is by Corollary.4. in Csörgo (983) and the fact that /X nl = O P () under Assumption 2 (a), where X nl inf t l (,) L ω l(τ, t l ). To show that /X nl = O P (), by the Triangle inequality and the fact that ω l (τ, t l ) is between ω l (τ, t l ) and ω l (τ, t l ), we obtain ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) X nl inf ω l (τ, t l ) sup ω l (τ, t l ) ω l (τ, t l ) t l (,) L t l (,) L q l (τ) + j l b L j q l (τ) q l (τ) j l p sup q j (t j ) q j (t j ) Y nl yl, t j (,) ] j+ where y l q l (τ) + j l bl j that y l ɛ >, > by Assumption 2 (a) and that τ (, ). For ɛ > such P(X nl > ɛ) P(Y nl > ɛ) P( y l + ɛ < Y nl y l < y l ɛ) = P( Y nl y l < y l ɛ), implying that P ( X nl ɛ ) since Xnl >, which in turn implies that /X nl = O P (). Proof. (Theorem 3) Given any l =,, L and τ (, ), let θ l (τ) = (q l (τ), δ l (τ), δ l2 (τ)) T, θ l (τ) = ( q l (τ), δ l (τ), δ l2 (τ)) T. Define m : R 3 R as m(θ l (τ)) = φ (q l (τ)) [δ l(τ) q l (τ)δ l2 (τ)]. For notational simplicity, we equivalently study Q l ( τ) Q l ( τ) instead of Q l (τ) Q l (τ). 34

Multi-Player Contests with Asymmetric Information Karl Wärneryd

Multi-Player Contests with Asymmetric Information Karl Wärneryd Multi-Player Contests with Asymmetric Information Karl Wärneryd Multi-Player Contests with Asymmetric Information Karl Wärneryd March 25, 2008 Abstract We consider imperfectly discriminating, common-value,

More information

Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest

Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest Zenan Wu Jie Zheng May 4, 207 Abstract We investigate players incentives to disclose information on their private valuations of the prize ahead of a

More information

Volume 35, Issue 4. Group contests and technologies. Dongryul Lee Department of Economics, Sungshin University

Volume 35, Issue 4. Group contests and technologies. Dongryul Lee Department of Economics, Sungshin University Volume 35, Issue 4 Group contests and technologies Dongryul Lee Department of Economics, Sungshin University Abstract We study the role of returns of scale of the technology on the characterization of

More information

A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams

A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams Kfir Eliaz and Qinggong Wu April 27, 216 Abstract We model a competition between two teams as an all-pay auction with incomplete information. The teams may differ

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams

A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams A Simple Model of Competition Between Teams Kfir Eliaz and Qinggong Wu March 2, 217 Abstract We model a competition between two teams that may differ in size as an all-pay auction with incomplete information.

More information

Linking Individual and Collective Contests through Noise Level and Sharing Rules

Linking Individual and Collective Contests through Noise Level and Sharing Rules Linking Individual and Collective Contests through Noise Level and Sharing Rules Pau Balart Subhasish M. Chowdhury Orestis Troumpounis November 6, 2015 Abstract We provide a theoretical link between the

More information

Multiple Equilibria in Tullock Contests

Multiple Equilibria in Tullock Contests MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Multiple Equilibria in Tullock Contests Subhasish Chowdhury and Roman Sheremeta 20 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5204/ MPRA Paper No. 5204, posted 0. December

More information

Contests with Bilateral Delegation: Unobservable Contracts

Contests with Bilateral Delegation: Unobservable Contracts Contests with Bilateral Delegation: Unobservable Contracts by Kyung Hwan Baik and Jihyun Kim Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, September 014, 170(3): 387-405. DOI: 10.168/09345614X13946975834836

More information

Academic Editor: Ulrich Berger Received: 12 August 2016 ; Accepted: 5 September 2016 ; Published: 9 September 2016

Academic Editor: Ulrich Berger Received: 12 August 2016 ; Accepted: 5 September 2016 ; Published: 9 September 2016 games Article Payoff Shares in Two-Player Contests Samuel Häfner and Georg Nöldeke * Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Basel, Peter Merian-Weg 6, Basel 400, Switzerland; samuel.haefner@unibas.ch

More information

On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y

On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y E. Einy z, O. Haimanko z, D. Moreno x, A. Sela z, and B. Shitovitz { December 2014 Abstract We show that

More information

Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information

Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information E. Einy y, O. Haimanko y, D. Moreno z, A. Sela y, and B. Shitovitz x December 2014 Abstract We show that under general assumptions

More information

A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter

A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter Forthcoming in Public Choice A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter J. Atsu Amegashie Department of Economics University of Guelph Guelph, Ontario Canada NG W E-mail: jamegash@uoguelph.ca

More information

Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information

Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach, Aner Sela July 14, 014 Abstract We study two-player common-value all-pay auctions in which the players have

More information

Unique Equilibrium in Contests with Incomplete Information

Unique Equilibrium in Contests with Incomplete Information 1 2 Unique Equilibrium in Contests with Incomplete Information 3 4 Christian Ewerhart y Federico Quartieri z 5 July 2013 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Abstract. For a large class of contests with incomplete

More information

A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter

A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter Public Choice (2006) 126: 135 144 DOI: 10.1007/s11127-006-2461-z C Springer 2006 A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter J. ATSU AMEGASHIE Department of Economics, University of Guelph,

More information

Hybrid All-Pay and Winner-Pay Contests

Hybrid All-Pay and Winner-Pay Contests Hybrid All-Pay and Winner-Pay Contests Seminar at DICE in Düsseldorf, June 5, 208 Johan N. M. Lagerlöf Dept. of Economics, U. of Copenhagen Email: johan.lagerlof@econ.ku.dk Website: www.johanlagerlof.com

More information

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply. Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply. Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale Discussion Paper No.: 0506-15 Department of Economics Columbia University New

More information

Information Advantage in Tullock Contests

Information Advantage in Tullock Contests Information Advantage in Tullock Contests A. Aiche, E. Einy y, O. Haimanko y, D. Moreno z, A. Sela y, and B. Shitovitz March 2017 Abstract We study the impact of an information advantage on the equilibrium

More information

Contests between groups of unknown size

Contests between groups of unknown size Contests between groups of unknown size Luke Boosey Philip Brookins Dmitry Ryvkin This version: September 1, 2017 Abstract We consider group contests where the number of competing groups is fixed but group

More information

Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation

Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation Hao Jia a,, Stergios Skaperdas b,, Samarth Vaidya c, a School of Accounting, Economics and Finance, Deakin University, Waurn Ponds, VIC

More information

The Strategic Equivalence of Rent-Seeking, Innovation, and Patent-Race Games

The Strategic Equivalence of Rent-Seeking, Innovation, and Patent-Race Games The Strategic Equivalence of Rent-Seeking, Innovation, and Patent-Race Games MichaelR.Baye Indiana University Heidrun C. Hoppe Universität Hamburg October 21 Abstract Conditions are identified which guarantee

More information

A Note on Multi-winner Contest Mechanisms

A Note on Multi-winner Contest Mechanisms A Note on Multi-winner Contest Mechanisms Subhasish M. Chowdhury and Sang-Hyun Kim February 11, 2014 Abstract In this note we consider a realistic multi-winner nested elimination contest in which losers

More information

1 Fixed E ects and Random E ects

1 Fixed E ects and Random E ects 1 Fixed E ects and Random E ects Estimation 1.1 Fixed E ects Introduction Fixed e ects model: y it = + x it + f i + it E ( it jx it ; f i ) = 0 Suppose we just run: y it = + x it + it Then we get: ^ =

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

Multi prizes for multi tasks: externalities and the optimal design of tournaments

Multi prizes for multi tasks: externalities and the optimal design of tournaments Multi prizes for multi tasks: externalities and the optimal design of tournaments Xu Tang Department of Economics, Georgia State University Email: xtang4@gsu.edu Yongsheng Xu Department of Economics, Georgia

More information

Players with Fixed Resources in Elimination Tournaments Alexander Matros Department of Economics University of Pittsburgh.

Players with Fixed Resources in Elimination Tournaments Alexander Matros Department of Economics University of Pittsburgh. Players with Fixed Resources in Elimination Tournaments Alexander Matros Department of Economics University of Pittsburgh January 29, 2004 Abstract. We consider two-round elimination tournaments where

More information

A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions

A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions Yu Yvette Zhang Abstract This paper is concerned with economic analysis of first-price sealed-bid auctions with risk

More information

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer University of British Columbia Artyom Shneyerov CIRANO, CIREQ, and Concordia University August 30, 2010 Abstract

More information

Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information y

Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information y Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information y E. Einy z, O. Haimanko z, D. Moreno x, A. Sela z, and B. Shitovitz { July 2014 Abstract We show that under standard assumptions every member of a broad class

More information

Games and Economic Behavior

Games and Economic Behavior Games and Economic Behavior 9 015) 138 149 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Games and Economic Behavior wwwelseviercom/locate/geb Tie-breaks and bid-caps in all-pay auctions Nora Szech Institute

More information

Crowdsourcing contests

Crowdsourcing contests December 8, 2012 Table of contents 1 Introduction 2 Related Work 3 Model: Basics 4 Model: Participants 5 Homogeneous Effort 6 Extensions Table of Contents 1 Introduction 2 Related Work 3 Model: Basics

More information

COMMON-VALUE ALL-PAY AUCTIONS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND BID CAPS. Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach and Aner Sela. Discussion Paper No.

COMMON-VALUE ALL-PAY AUCTIONS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND BID CAPS. Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach and Aner Sela. Discussion Paper No. COMMON-VALUE ALL-PAY AUCTIONS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND BID CAPS Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach and Aner Sela Discussion Paper No. 4-0 September 04 Monaster Center for Economic Research Ben-Gurion

More information

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012 September 24, 2012 Finding Nash equilibrium Best-response or best-reply functions. We introduced Nash-equilibrium as a profile of actions (an action for each player) such that no player has an incentive

More information

Ability Grouping in All-Pay Contests

Ability Grouping in All-Pay Contests Ability Grouping in All-Pay Contests Jun Xiao October 11, 2017 Abstract This paper considers a situation in which participants with heterogeneous ability types are grouped into different competitions for

More information

Best-shot Versus Weakest-link in Political Lobbying: An Application of Group All-pay Auction *

Best-shot Versus Weakest-link in Political Lobbying: An Application of Group All-pay Auction * Best-shot Versus Weakest-link in Political Lobbying: An Application of Group All-pay Auction * Subhasish M. Chowdhury a and Iryna Topolyan b a School of Economics, Centre for Behavioural and Experimental

More information

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2)

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2) Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2) Haifeng Huang University of California, Merced Best response functions: example In simple games we can examine

More information

All-pay auctions with interdependent valuations: The highly competitive case 1

All-pay auctions with interdependent valuations: The highly competitive case 1 All-pay auctions with interdependent valuations: The highly competitive case 1 Lucas Rentschler Centro Vernon Smith de Economía Experimental Universidad Francisco Marroquin Guatemala, Guatemala lrentschler@ufm.edu

More information

Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information

Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information Tullock Contests with Asymmetric Information E. Einy y, O. Haimanko y, D. Moreno z, A. Sela y, and B. Shitovitz x September 203 Abstract We show that under standard assumptions a Tullock contest with asymmetric

More information

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 John Nachbar Washington University May 2, 2017 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 1 Introduction. The Revenue Equivalence Theorem gives conditions under which some very different auctions generate the same

More information

A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle

A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle Daniel Quint University of Wisconsin April 06 Abstract. I present a numerical example illustrating the revenue-superiority of an open over a closed

More information

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1 Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder Jinwoo Kim We study the efficiency of standard auctions with interdependent values in which one of two bidders is perfectly informed of his value while

More information

Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in. First-Price Auctions

Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in. First-Price Auctions Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in First-Price Auctions Isabelle Perrigne Pennsylvania State University Department of Economics University Park, PA 16802 Phone: (814) 863-2157, Fax:

More information

Incentives versus Competitive Balance

Incentives versus Competitive Balance Incentives versus Competitive Balance Marc Möller Department of Economics Universität Bern Abstract When players compete repeatedly, prizes won in earlier contests may improve the players abilities in

More information

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems CSCI699: Topics in Learning and Game Theory Lecture 4 Lecturer: Shaddin Dughmi Scribes: Haifeng Xu,Reem Alfayez 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems Example 1: Single Item Auctions. There is a single

More information

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126 UC3M Working papers Departamento de Economía Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid 13-14 Calle Madrid, 126 July, 2013 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 916249875 TULLOCK CONTESTS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION

More information

A nested contest: Tullock meets the All-Pay Auction*

A nested contest: Tullock meets the All-Pay Auction* A nested contest: Tullock meets the All-Pay Auction J. Atsu Amegashie Department of Economics and Finance University of Guelph Guelph, Ontario Canada NG W Email: jamegash@uoguelph.ca Phone: 59-84-40 Ext.

More information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information joint with Stephen Morris (Princeton University) November 2010 Payoff Environment in games with incomplete information, the agents are uncertain

More information

Optimal Favoritism in All-Pay Auctions and Lottery Contests

Optimal Favoritism in All-Pay Auctions and Lottery Contests Optimal Favoritism in All-Pay Auctions and Lottery Contests Jörg Franke 1, Wolfgang Leininger 1, and Cédric Wasser 2 1 University of Dortmund (TU) Department of Economics Vogelpothsweg 87 44227 Dortmund

More information

Estimating Dynamic Games of Electoral Competition to Evaluate Term Limits in U.S. Gubernatorial Elections: Online Appendix

Estimating Dynamic Games of Electoral Competition to Evaluate Term Limits in U.S. Gubernatorial Elections: Online Appendix Estimating Dynamic Games of Electoral Competition to Evaluate Term Limits in U.S. Gubernatorial Elections: Online ppendix Holger Sieg University of Pennsylvania and NBER Chamna Yoon Baruch College I. States

More information

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Monika Köppl-Turyna Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Winter 2017/2018 Static Games of Incomplete Information Introduction So far we assumed that payoff functions

More information

Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS. Heng Liu

Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS. Heng Liu Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS Heng Liu This note considers equilibrium selection in common-value secondprice auctions with two bidders. We show that for each

More information

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi Political Cycles and Stock Returns Ľuboš Pástor and Pietro Veronesi University of Chicago, National Bank of Slovakia, NBER, CEPR University of Chicago, NBER, CEPR Average Excess Stock Market Returns 30

More information

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008 Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information November 14, 2008 Bayesian Games : Osborne, ch 9 Battle of the sexes with incomplete information Player 1 would like to match player 2's action Player 1 is unsure

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 37

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 37 1 / 37 Political Economics Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich Summer term 2010 4 / 37 Table of contents 1 Introduction(MG) 2 Preferences and voting (MG) 3 Voter turnout (MG) 4 Electoral competition (SÜ)

More information

The Lottery Contest is a Best-Response Potential Game

The Lottery Contest is a Best-Response Potential Game University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-7041 (print) ISSN 1664-705X (online) Working Paper No. 242 The Lottery Contest is a Best-Response Potential Game Christian Ewerhart

More information

The incidence of overdissipation in rent-seeking contests

The incidence of overdissipation in rent-seeking contests Public Choice 99: 439 454, 1999. 1999 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 439 The incidence of overdissipation in rent-seeking contests MICHAEL R. BAYE 1,, DAN KOVENOCK 2 & CASPER G.

More information

Working Paper Series. Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes. Jun Xiao. June Research Paper Number 1151

Working Paper Series. Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes. Jun Xiao. June Research Paper Number 1151 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Jun iao June 212 Research Paper Number 1151 ISSN: 819 2642 ISBN: 978 734 451 Department of Economics The

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Problem Set 0. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann 4/5/4 This problem set is due on Tuesday, 4//4..

More information

UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND Department of Economics Economics 754 Topics in Political Economy Fall 2005 Allan Drazen. Exercise Set I

UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND Department of Economics Economics 754 Topics in Political Economy Fall 2005 Allan Drazen. Exercise Set I UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND Department of Economics Economics 754 Topics in Political Economy Fall 005 Allan Drazen Exercise Set I The first four exercises are review of what we did in class on 8/31. The next

More information

APPLIED MECHANISM DESIGN FOR SOCIAL GOOD

APPLIED MECHANISM DESIGN FOR SOCIAL GOOD APPLIED MECHANISM DESIGN FOR SOCIAL GOOD JOHN P DICKERSON Lecture #3 09/06/2016 CMSC828M Tuesdays & Thursdays 12:30pm 1:45pm REMINDER: SEND ME TOP 3 PRESENTATION PREFERENCES! I LL POST THE SCHEDULE TODAY

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 24: Decisions in Groups

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 24: Decisions in Groups 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 24: Decisions in Groups Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT December 9, 2009 1 Introduction Outline Group and collective choices Arrow s Impossibility Theorem Gibbard-Satterthwaite

More information

Lottery versus All-Pay Auction Contests

Lottery versus All-Pay Auction Contests RUHR ECONOMIC PAPERS Jörg Franke Christian Kanzow Wolfgang Leininger Alexandra Schwartz Lottery versus All-Pay Auction Contests A Revenue Dominance Theorem #35 Imprint Ruhr Economic Papers Published by

More information

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Matthew Osborne University of Toronto November 25, 2013 Abstract

More information

Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes

Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Jun iao y May 212 Abstract This paper studies complete-information, all-pay contests with asymmetric players competing for multiple heterogeneous prizes.

More information

Supplemental Online Appendix for Trading Across Borders in On-line Auctions

Supplemental Online Appendix for Trading Across Borders in On-line Auctions Supplemental Online Appendix for Trading Across Borders in On-line Auctions Elena Krasnokutskaya Christian Terwiesch Johns Hopkins University Wharton School of Business Lucia Tiererova Johns Hopkins University

More information

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006 Economics 301 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 0, 006 Lecture 11 Topics Problem Set 9 Extensive Games of Imperfect Information An Example General Description Strategies and Nash Equilibrium Beliefs

More information

BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS

BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Lobbying, Campaign Contributions and Political Competition Javier Rivas No. 55 /16 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Department of Economics Lobbying, Campaign Contributions and Political Competition Javier

More information

EFFORT INCENTIVES, ACHIEVEMENT GAPS AND AFFIRMA. AND AFFIRMATIVE ACTION POLICIES (very preliminary)

EFFORT INCENTIVES, ACHIEVEMENT GAPS AND AFFIRMA. AND AFFIRMATIVE ACTION POLICIES (very preliminary) EFFORT INCENTIVES, ACHIEVEMENT GAPS AND AFFIRMATIVE ACTION POLICIES (very preliminary) Brent Hickman Department of Economics, University of Iowa December 22, 2008 Brief Model Outline In this paper, I use

More information

Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation

Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation Contest Functions: Theoretical Foundations and Issues in Estimation Hao Jia, Stergios Skaperdas, and Samarth Vaidya May 14, 2011 Abstract Contest functions (alternatively, contest success functions) determine

More information

Rent-Seeking Group Contests with Private Information

Rent-Seeking Group Contests with Private Information Rent-Seeking Group Contests with Private Information Jean-François Mercier April 7, 2015 Abstract A model of rent-seeking group contest is developed. The contested good is a local public good. Individuals

More information

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Tymofiy Mylovanov Thomas Tröger University of Bonn June 21, 2008 1/28 Motivation 2/28 Motivation In most applications of mechanism design, the proposer

More information

Asymmetric Rent-seeking Contests with Multiple Agents of Two Types

Asymmetric Rent-seeking Contests with Multiple Agents of Two Types Asymmetric Rent-seeking Contests with Multiple Agents of Two Types Tao Cai Qian Jiao Jie Zheng February, 207 Abstract We consider a complete-information rent-seeking contest with multiple agents of two

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics 7. Special-interest politics Motivation Why do some groups in society receive more generous support than other (e.g. farmers)? Homogeneity in interests which allows more efficient organization of lobby

More information

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games Chapter 2 Equilibrium Equilibrium attempts to capture what happens in a game when players behave strategically. This is a central concept to these notes as in mechanism design we are optimizing over games

More information

A simple microfoundation for the utilization of fragmentation indexes to measure the performance of a team

A simple microfoundation for the utilization of fragmentation indexes to measure the performance of a team A simple microfoundation for the utilization of fragmentation indexes to measure the performance of a team Benoît LE MAUX University of Rennes 1 and CREM-CNRS Yvon ROCABOY University of Rennes 1 and CREM-CNRS

More information

Electoral Competition with Privately Informed Candidates. (Preliminary)

Electoral Competition with Privately Informed Candidates. (Preliminary) Electoral Competition with Privately Informed Candidates (Preliminary) Dan Bernhardt Department of Economics University of Illinois 1206 S. Sixth Street Champaign, IL 61820 John Duggan Department of Political

More information

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics Benoit S Y Crutzen and Nicolas Sahuguet y September 20 Abstract This paper studies an electoral competition game between two candidates,

More information

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Games and Economic Behavior 38, 19 27 22 doi:116 game21879, available online at http: wwwidealibrarycom on Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Sushil Bihchandani 2 Anderson Graduate School

More information

Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs

Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs Xiaoyong Cao Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, TX 77843 Guoqiang Tian Department of Economics Texas A&M University

More information

THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS. A Dissertation XIAOYONG CAO

THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS. A Dissertation XIAOYONG CAO THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS A Dissertation by XIAOYONG CAO Submitted to the Office of Graduate Studies of Texas A&M University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

Mixed equilibria in Tullock contests

Mixed equilibria in Tullock contests University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-7041 (print) ISSN 1664-705X (online) Working Paper No. 143 Mixed equilibria in Tullock contests Christian Ewerhart March 2014

More information

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games Chapter 2 Equilibrium The theory of equilibrium attempts to predict what happens in a game when players behave strategically. This is a central concept to this text as, in mechanism design, we are optimizing

More information

Auctions with Rent Seeking

Auctions with Rent Seeking Auctions with Rent Seeking Marco Haan and Lambert Schoonbeek Department of Economics University of Groningen The Netherlands Abstract We present a model which combines elements of an auction and a rent-seeking

More information

SIRE DISCUSSION PAPER

SIRE DISCUSSION PAPER scottish institute for research in economics SIRE DISCUSSION PAPER SIRE-DP-00-83 Affirmative Action Policy and Effort Levels. Sequential-Move Contest Game Argument Andrzej Kwiatkowski University of Dundee

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Gagan Ghosh Bingchao Huangfu Heng Liu October 19, 2017 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: COMMENTS WELCOME) Abstract We study wars of attrition between two bidders who

More information

Supplemental Appendix to "Alternative Assumptions to Identify LATE in Fuzzy Regression Discontinuity Designs"

Supplemental Appendix to Alternative Assumptions to Identify LATE in Fuzzy Regression Discontinuity Designs Supplemental Appendix to "Alternative Assumptions to Identify LATE in Fuzzy Regression Discontinuity Designs" Yingying Dong University of California Irvine February 2018 Abstract This document provides

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information. Games of incomplete information. Cournot Competition under Asymmetric Information (cont )

Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information. Games of incomplete information. Cournot Competition under Asymmetric Information (cont ) Lecture Note II- Static Games of Incomplete Information Static Bayesian Game Bayesian Nash Equilibrium Applications: Auctions The Revelation Principle Games of incomplete information Also called Bayesian

More information

First Price Auctions with General Information Structures: Implications for Bidding and Revenue

First Price Auctions with General Information Structures: Implications for Bidding and Revenue First Price Auctions with General Information Structures: Implications for Bidding and Revenue Dirk Bergemann Benjamin Brooks Stephen Morris August 10, 2015 Abstract This paper explores the consequences

More information

The Importance of the Median Voter

The Importance of the Median Voter The Importance of the Median Voter According to Duncan Black and Anthony Downs V53.0500 NYU 1 Committee Decisions utility 0 100 x 1 x 2 x 3 x 4 x 5 V53.0500 NYU 2 Single-Peakedness Condition The preferences

More information

Information and Incentives in A Model of Contest Between Large Groups

Information and Incentives in A Model of Contest Between Large Groups Information and Incentives in A Model of Contest Between Large Groups Eduardo Perez perezedu@stanford.edu Abstract This paper studies a model of social contest between two large groups, in which individual

More information

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar ABSTRACT We study a model of social learning with partial observations from

More information

Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen No. 7-20 Hybrid All-Pay and Winner-Pay Contests Johan N. M. Lagerlöf Øster Farimagsgade 5, Building 26, DK-353 Copenhagen K., Denmark

More information

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101 3 Tournaments 3.1 Motivation General idea Firms can use competition between agents for 1 incentive and 2 selection purposes We mainly focus on incentives 3 / 101 Main characteristics Agents fulll similar

More information

Information Acquisition in Interdependent Value Auctions

Information Acquisition in Interdependent Value Auctions Information Acquisition in Interdependent Value Auctions Dirk Bergemann Xianwen Shi Juuso Välimäki July 16, 2008 Abstract We consider an auction environment with interdependent values. Each bidder can

More information

Contests between groups of unknown size

Contests between groups of unknown size Contests between groups of unknown size Luke Boosey Philip Brookins Dmitry Ryvkin This version: June 30, 2018 Abstract We study group contests where the number of competing groups is fixed but group sizes

More information

public-good prizes Katsuya Kobayashi December 28, 2017 Abstract

public-good prizes Katsuya Kobayashi December 28, 2017 Abstract Step-by-step group contests with group-specific public-good prizes Katsuya Kobayashi December 28, 2017 Abstract This study analyzes group contests with group-specific public-good prizes in which the step-by-step

More information

Populism, Partisanship, and the Funding of Political Campaigns

Populism, Partisanship, and the Funding of Political Campaigns Populism, Partisanship, and the Funding of Political Campaigns Tilman Klumpp University of Alberta October 2015 Abstract We define populism as a politician s effort to appeal to a large group of voters

More information