Solving Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models by Approximating the Stochastic Equilibrium System

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Solving Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models by Approximating the Stochastic Equilibrium System"

Transcription

1 Solving Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models by Approximating the Stochastic Equilibrium System Michael P. Evers September 20, 2012 Revised version coming soon! Abstract Dynamic stochastic rational expectations models are commonly solved by computing the linearized solution from the deterministic equilibrium system. Therefore, the linearized solution must be independent of the distribution of the exogenous shocks. This paper proposes to compute the linearized solution from an approximated equilibrium system. This approximated equilibrium system (denoted by AES) is obtained from a kth-order Taylor series expansion of the true stochastic equilibrium system about the deterministic equilibrium system by perturbing it in the exogenous disturbances. The AES is non-stochastic and preserves the nonlinearity in the endogenous variables, but it is linear in the first k moments of the exogenous disturbances. Hence, the linearized solution to the I thank Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, Martin Uribe, Christopher Sims, Harald Uhlig, Kenneth Judd, Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde, Matthias Paustian, Paul Pichler, Casper de Vries, Christian Matthes, and in particular Johannes Pfeifer for helpful discussions and valuable comments at different stages of this project. All errors are my responsibility. IIW, ZEI, and BGSE, Bonn University; Correspondence: Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftspolitik, Lennéstr. 37, D Bonn, Germany; mevers@uni-bonn.de. 1

2 AES fully captures the equilibrium implications of the stochastic environment up to the first k moments. The solution procedure thus allows to employ standard linear toolboxes both from mathematical economics and econometrics to study the ramifications of risk in DSGE models. Keywords: Solving dynamic general equilibrium models; Perturbation methods; Linear solution in second and higher moments of shock distribution; Accuracy JEL classification: E0, C63 1 Introduction Nonlinearities and stochastic environments are key features of modern dynamic macroeconomic modeling. The predominant solution method to solve nonlinear dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models is based on perturbation methods. Following Magill (1977), Kydland and Prescott (1982), and King et al. (1988), the conventional practice is to compute the linear solution to the deterministic version of the model, which is why the equilibrium interaction of the stochastic environment with nonlinearities must be neglected. This paper demonstrates how to obtain linear approximate solutions to dynamic stochastic rational expectations models which explicitly account for the stochastic environment in nonlinear models. The innovation of the approach is to compute the linear solution from an approximated equilibrium system that preserves the impact of risk on the complete solution process instead of computing the solution from the deterministic version of the equilibrium system. The approximated equilibrium system (denoted by AES henceforth) is the kth-order Taylor series approximation to the original stochastic equilibrium system which is expanded in the exogenous disturbances about the deterministic model with its deterministic solution. In these terms, the 2

3 conventional practice is to compute the linear solution from the 0th-order AES. The AES-approach has three key properties: First, the kth-order Taylor series approximation to the original stochastic equilibrium conditions is non-stochastic and preserves the nonlinearity in the endogenous variables. But it is linear in the first k moments of the distribution of exogenous shocks. The solution to the kth-order AES is parameterized by the first k moments of the exogenous disturbances. Notably, the steady state of the AES and the linear coefficients on the state vector capture the equilibrium implications of the stochastic environment in nonlinear models up to the first k moments. The practical implication for researchers is that the linear state-space representation of the solution process can be applied to study the equilibrium implications of nonlinearities in stochastic environments as for instance on the dynamic behavior and the equilibrium distribution. Most notably, the AES-approach captures the effect of risk on existence and uniqueness up to the first k moments. This is in stark contrast to the conventional perturbation approach where existence and uniqueness is generically assessed for the deterministic model (i.e. the 0th-order AES). Moreover, when taking the model to the data, the equilibrium solution process can be analyzed with standard linear econometric tools such as VARs and likelihood based approaches with linear filtering whereas nonlinear econometric tools are computationally expensive if not infeasible. Linear methods thus become applicable for a wide range of macroeconomic questions that were hitherto beyond their reach, like e.g. welfare comparisons across different policies, portfolio choice models, or the study of asset pricing in DSGE models. The same is true for studying Markov-switching models, models with recursive preferences, and the topical debate about the quantitative role of uncertainty and time-varying volatility on macroeconomic aggregates 1. 1 Compare on welfare evaluations e.g. Tesar (1995) and Kim and Kim (2003); on portfolio choice models, see e.g. Baxter and Jermann (1997) and Devereux and Sutherland (2011) in an open economy context; on asset pricing in DSGE model, see e.g. Uhlig (2007), Rudebusch and Swanson (2008), or Kliem and Uhlig (2011); on Markov-switching models in conventionally linearized setups see e.g. Farmer et al. (2009) and with a nonlinear solution method see e.g. Davig et al. (n.d.); on recursive 3

4 Second, the Euler error implied by the exact solution to the AES is simply the approximation error of the AES to the true stochastic equilibrium system. As a consequence, the accuracy of the linearized solution to the kth-order AES thus increases in the order k, too. This has important implications: i) The accuracy of the approximated key local properties of existence and uniqueness as well as the accuracy of the approximated equilibrium distribution and the dynamic behavior increases in the order k; ii) As Ackerberg et al. (2009) show, the effect of using approximated solutions on the parameter estimation based on maximum likelihood inference is limited by the approximation error to the solution. Consequently, the accuracy of parameter estimates based on the linear solution to the AES also increases in the order k; iii) Using the DSGE model for forecasting, the accuracy of forecasts based on the linear solution to the AES also increases in the order k. The third key property of the AES-approach is that the procedure requires the solution to be locally determined for the kth-order AES but not for the deterministic version of the model. This makes the perturbation method applicable to models where the solution is locally indeterminate in the deterministic version of the model. This is the case for instance in portfolio choice models. From a methodological perspective, the AES-approach regards the stochastic equilibrium system to be arising from the deterministic model by small random disturbances. This view has a long tradition in economics: Measures of risk aversion and precautionary motives following Arrow (1965) and Pratt (1964) are based on expansions in the random disturbances about some deterministic reference point. It is also the basic concept of Samuelson s fundamental approximation theorem to the mean-variance solution in portfolio choice problems (Samuelson (1970)). In this regard, the AES-approach generalizes Samuelson s approach to solving dynamic stochastic preferences in DSGE models, see e.g. Rudebusch and Swanson (2012); on the quantitative role of uncertainty and time-varying volatility in the DSGE framework, see for instance Justiniano and Primiceri (2008), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2007), Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2010), and Born and Pfeifer (2011). 4

5 rational expectations models. Related literature. In order to account for risk, several recent papers provide algorithms to compute higher-order Taylor series expansions to the solution of DSGE models. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), Kim et al. (2008), and Jin and Judd (2002) provide perturbation algorithms for calculating second-order approximations to the solution of DSGE models. 2 The AES-approach is closely related to conventional higher-order approximations because they are based on the same perturbation principles. The crucial difference between the two approaches boils down to the sequencing of perturbation with respect to exogenous disturbances/risk and the vector of state variables. Most conveniently from a practical perspective, by sorting and rearranging the Taylor coefficients appropriately, the AES-approach is easily implemented into existing computer programs that compute higher-order approximations to the solution of DSGE models based on Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), Sims (2000), or the popular DYNARE/DYNARE++ (Adjemian et al. (2011)). Simply sorting and rearranging the Taylor coefficients appropriately then dissolves two major difficulties of conventional higher-order approximations: First, pruning of higher-order perturbation approximations to avoid explosive simulated solution paths is no longer required. 3 Second, nonlinear statistical methods are avoided when estimating the rational expectations model. Instead, the linear state-space representation of the solution process allows to employ the standard linear tools like for instance the Kalman filter. The relation between the AES-approach and the conventional higher-order approximation is discussed in detail in Supplement A. This paper is also closely related to recent contributions that seek a linear approxi- 2 Other contributions include Collard and Juillard (2001), Anderson and Levin (2002), Anderson et al. (2006), Lombardo and Sutherland (2007), and Gomme and Klein (2011). 3 Kim et al. (2008) and den Haan and Wind (2012) describe the problem of explosive simulated time paths for higher-order perturbation approximations and potential remedies for this problem. 5

6 mation to the solution about a risky or stochastic steady state rather than about the deterministic steady state, as e.g. in Juillard (2012), Coeurdacier et al. (2011), and Kliem and Uhlig (2011). The basic idea and common to the AES-approach is to compute a (2nd-order) Taylor series expansion to the stochastic equilibrium conditions (Euler equations). Their approach is to compute the Taylor series expansion to the equilibrium system in the endogenous and exogenous variables with the consequence that the Euler equations are stated in terms of the moments of the equilibrium distribution of the endogenous and exogenous variables instead of the moments of the exogenous shocks. Assuming the linear structure of the solution, the risky steady state and the corresponding linear coefficients are then determined numerically by iteratively computing the implied equilibrium distribution and then updating the approximated Euler equations. The risky steady state approach is rather heuristic and lacks clear theoretical foundation. Crucially, the iterative procedure might be unstable as the fixed-point algorithm need not be convergent. In contrast, the AES-approach computes the Taylor series expansion to the equilibrium system directly in terms of the moments of the distribution of the exogenous shocks taking fully into account the impact of shocks on endogenous variables. The present paper thus provides a theoretical foundation to the risky steady state approach and discusses its properties. Specifically, the risky steady state simply refers to the steady state of the AES and the linear approximation about the risky steady state refers to the linearized solution to the AES. Importantly, the AES-approach is based on standard perturbation methods: Any computational instabilities and inefficiencies involved with the iterative fixed-point algorithms are avoided and the approximated solution process is easily taken to the data. Organization of the paper. The paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the simple portfolio choice problem as a motivating example. Section 3 6

7 describes the general framework and fixes notation. The Taylor series approximation to the stochastic equilibrium model is presented in Section 4. A discussion of the approximation error of the AES and its implications for the accuracy of the approximated solution follows in Section 5. Section 6 concludes with some final remarks. Supplemental Material. The Supplemental Material contains a detailed discussion of how the AES-approach relates to conventional higher-order perturbation algorithms as in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) (Supplement A). Supplement A also describes how the AES-approach can be implemented into existing routines. The Supplemental Material also contains two further applications of the AES-approach: Supplement B provides an algebraic application to the consumption-savings problem where it is highlighted how the AES-approach captures precautionary motives. Supplement C presents a comprehensive numerical application to an asset pricing model (Burnside (1998)) which permits an exact assessment of the accuracy of the AES-approach with respect to the Taylor coefficients of the linear solution, the implied equilibrium distribution, existence and uniqueness, and maximum likelihood estimates of the deep parameters. It also provides a comparison to the conventional 2nd-order approximation. 2 Motivating Example: The Portfolio Choice Problem Before starting with the general description of the problem and the solution procedure, it is useful to first illustrate the basic principle and the properties of the AES-approach. To this end, consider the simple portfolio choice example in Samuelson (1970). A risk averse investor with concave utility function U maximizes expected utility from investing a fraction (1 w) of initial unit wealth into cash and a fraction w into a risky asset with an excess return over cash of a. The overall return of the portfolio 7

8 investment is (1 w) + w(a + 1). The exogenous process for the excess return is simply a = σɛ where ɛ is a random shock and σ is the perturbation parameter. The solution to the portfolio investment problem is characterized by the first order condition EU (wσɛ + 1) σɛ = 0. (1) The first step to solve the portfolio choice model is to restate the stochastic equilibrium condition in terms of the moments of the exogenous excess return process. Step 1: Approximating the original stochastic equilibrium condition (computing the AES) The stochastic equilibrium condition (1) can be approximated by a Taylor series expansion in the perturbation parameter σ about σ = 0, which corresponds to the deterministic optimality condition. For instance, the second order Taylor series of (1) about σ = 0 yields EU (wσɛ + 1) σɛ = U (1)σEɛ + U (1)wσ 2 Eɛ 2 + O(σ 3 ) = 0, (2) where the remainder O(σ 3 ) captures the approximation error of the 2nd-order Taylor expansion to the original condition in (1). Step 2: Computing the solution to the AES The second step of the solution procedure is to compute the optimal portfolio fraction w of the risky asset from the approximated equilibrium condition in (2). Setting the mean and the variance as in Samuelson s example, i.e. Eɛ = σµ a and Eɛ 2 = σ 2 a, results in w = µ a U (1) σa 2 U (1) + O(σ3 ), which is the classical mean-variance approximation when omitting the remainder O(σ 3 ). The simple portfolio choice example already highlights the key aspects of the AES-approach. First, it shows how the 2nd-order Taylor series expansion about σ = 0 8

9 approximates the expectational optimality condition (1) by a non-stochastic equation that explicitly takes into account uncertainty via the first and second moments of the shocks to the excess return. The solution to the new equilibrium (2) system therefore also depends on these moments. Second, the simple example shows that the approximation error of the Taylor series expansion O(σ 3 ) is simply the Euler error of the exact solution to the new equilibrium (2), w = µa U (1). The accuracy of σa 2 U (1) the solution to the new equilibrium system AES as the approximate solution to the true problem ES thus increases in the order k of the Taylor series expansion AES. Third, the example also reveals why the procedure allows to solve problems where the solution is locally indeterminate in the deterministic version of the model. In the deterministic case when σ = 0, the optimality condition (1) is trivially satisfied so that w cannot be determined. The higher-order Taylor terms in (2), however, provide a system of equilibrium conditions that uniquely determines w. The solution procedure thereby makes local linear methods applicable to problems where the deterministic equilibrium system when σ = 0 is locally indeterminate. 4 4 Note that by construction the perturbation coefficient σ is used to scale the effective distribution of the shocks. In principle, instead of introducing it as a coefficient on the shock terms, the perturbation coefficient could have also been introduced directly into the shock distribution as coefficients on the moments. In fact, the latter approach is the underlying idea of Samuelson (1970) when he introduced a scaling parameter by which he let shrink the riskiness of the stochastic returns to zero to obtain the non-stochastic outcome. He coined the term compact probability for the distribution that is parameterized in the scaling coefficient. In fact, Samuelson did not explicitly use the scaling coefficient as the perturbation parameter, but his approach rests on Taylor series expansion in the shock terms, too. 9

10 3 The General Form of the Dynamic Rational Expectations Model The dynamic, discrete-time equilibrium model can be cast into the general form of a nonlinear stochastic vector difference equation, 0 = E t f(y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, z t+1 ), (3) for t = 0, 1,...,, where y t R ny is the vector of endogenous variables nonpredetermined at the beginning of time t, x t R nx is the vector of predetermined endogenous variables, and z t R nz is the vector of exogenous variables. 5 The stochastic equilibrium system (denoted by ES) is characterized by the function f : R 2 ny R 2 nx R 2 nz R n. It is the collection of all equilibrium conditions which determine the solution to the n = n y + n x endogenous variables. The law of motion of the exogenous variables follows a stochastic process which is implicitly described by where M : R nz R nz R nɛ 0 = M(z t+1, z t, σɛ t+1 ), (4) R nz. The process of the exogenous state variables is assumed to be dynamically stable. The disturbances to the exogenous variables are collected by the vector ɛ t R nɛ across time with finite first k moments. which is independently and identically distributed The stochastic equilibrium system (3) is conceived as the perturbation of the deterministic equilibrium system by small random shocks σɛ t+1. Taking the distribution of 5 In principle, the partition of variables into states and controls is not necessary for the proposed solution method but it is done for expositional convenience. The same procedure can also be applied to the more general formulation as in Sims (2000) and Kim et al. (2008) where the partitioning into states and controls is part of the solution procedure as it follows from the partitioning into predetermined and non-predetermined disturbances. For the reader s convenience, the exposition of the general setup follows Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) as closely as possible but allows for more general laws of motion of the exogenous variables. 10

11 shocks as given, the perturbation parameter σ on the shock vector ɛ t+1 allows to scale the risk in the equilibrium system. In (3), E t denotes the mathematical expectations operator conditional on the information available at time t, when the current state (x t, z t ) is completely observable. The Solution The solution process to (3) evolves according to the following rules for the endogenous predetermined and non-predetermined variables: x t+1 = h(x t, z t ) and y t = g(x t, z t ), with z t+1 = m(z t, σɛ t+1 ), where the equilibrium rules are vector valued functions with h : R nx R nz R nx and g : R nx R nz R ny, and where the exogenous variables are assumed to follow the law of motion with m : R nz R nɛ R nz. Substituting the solution process into the system of nonlinear stochastic equilibrium equations in (3) allows to restate the stochastic equilibrium system in terms of the current state and the corresponding solution to the endogenous variables as E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) E t f (g(x t, z t ), x t, z t, g(h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )). The general model can then be stated for the true solution process as 0 = E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) z t+1 = m(z t, σɛ t+1 ). (5) The deterministic model when σ = 0 can thus be stated as 0 = F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) z t+1 = m(z t, 0), 11

12 where g 0 ( ) and h 0 ( ) denote the solution to the deterministic model. Law of Motion for exogenous state variables. The law of motion for the exogenous state variables is often assumed to be linear in both z t and σɛ t+1 where usually z t is the log of a variable. This directly yields the law of motion of the form z t+1 = m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) = Az t + Bσɛ t+1 for some matrices A of size n z n z and B of size n z n ɛ. The more general form in (4) allows for nonlinear processes and interactive disturbances that enter the law of motion non-additively. This, of course, requires the approximation to the exogenous law of motion to be consistent with the approximation to the solution for the endogenous variables. The set of equations M( ) = 0 which describe the process of the exogenous variables is necessarily independent of the endogenous variables and the system of equilibrium equations in (ES). The approximate solution to m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) can therefore be easily computed in isolation using the standard perturbation approach by means of the implicit function theorem. For instance, the first order Taylor series expansion in z t and σ about some steady state z with z = m( z, 0) for σ = 0 yields m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) = z + m z ( z, 0)(z t z) + m ɛ ( z, 0)σɛ t+1, where m z ( z, 0) and m ɛ ( z, 0) denote the respective partial derivatives of m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) with respect to z t and σɛ t+1 evaluated at ( z, 0). The linear Taylor coefficients are computed by plugging the solution to the law of motion into (4) and setting the derivatives of M(m(z t, σɛ t+1 ), z t, σɛ t+1 ) with respect to z t and ɛ t+1 equal to zero. To be specific, m z and m ɛ are obtained by solving M zt+1 m z +M zt = 0 and M zt+1 m ɛ +M ɛt+1 = 0, respectively. Second and higher-order approximations are computed analogously. 6 6 Take as an example the linear form M(z t+1, z t, σɛ t+1 ) = z t+1 Az t Bσɛ t+1, where ɛ t+1 is i.i.d with mean zero. The steady state is z = 0 for ɛ = 0. The respective derivatives of M( ) are M zt+1 = I nz, M zt = A, and M ɛt+1 = Bσ, where I nz denotes the identity matrix of size n z n z. Consequently, m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) = Az t + Bσɛ t+1. 12

13 Regularity Conditions. It is assumed that f( ) is smooth in the sense that up to the order of approximation k + r all derivatives exist, where k denotes the order of the Taylor series expansion to the equilibrium system in risk and r denotes the order of the Taylor series approximation to the functional form of the solution g( ) and h( ). Moreover, since solving for the Taylor series expansion in g( ) and h( ) makes extensive use of the Implicit Function Theorem, it is assumed that the solvability conditions on the respective derivatives of f are met and that g( ) and h( ) are continuous and have the necessary k + r derivatives. The regularity conditions ensure that first, a k-th order Taylor series expansion of the equilibrium system (3) about the deterministic model is computable, and second, that the r-th order expansion of the solution to the problem h( ) and g( ) can be computed from the approximated equilibrium system using the implicit function theorem. Similar conditions apply to M( ) and m( ) for the exogenous variables. In addition to the local properties of the functional forms, the k moments of the distribution of ɛ exist and are finite. For a more detailed discussion of the regularity conditions and also about the necessity of bounds on the support of the shocks which also applies here, see Jin and Judd (2002) and Kim et al. (2008). 4 Solving the Model by Approximating the Stochastic Equilibrium System ES The aim is to find an approximation for g( ) and h( ) of the dynamic stochastic equilibrium model in (3) which is computable from the deterministic model F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) where σ = 0. The solution procedure consists of two steps: The first step is to restate the original system of stochastic equilibrium equations E t f( ) by a kth-order Taylor series expansion in the perturbation parameter about σ = 0. This corresponds to a Taylor series approximation in the stochastic disturbances about the deterministic model F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )). The first step thus directly adopts the notion that the stochastic equilibrium system emanates from the perturbation 13

14 of the deterministic equilibrium system by small random shocks σɛ t+1. The result is an approximated system of equilibrium conditions AES which is non-stochastic and nonlinear in the endogenous variables, but which is linear in the first k moments of the exogenous disturbances. The second step of the solution procedure is then to compute the solution to the new equilibrium system AES as the approximation to the true solution process for g( ) and h( ). 4.1 Step 1: The Approximation of the Stochastic Equilibrium System ES (Computing the AES) The following proposition states the approximation of the stochastic equilibrium system by a Taylor series expansion about the deterministic model in terms of F ( ) as stated in (5). Proposition 1. At a given state (x t, z t ), the k-th order Taylor series expansion of the stochastic equilibrium system E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) in the perturbation parameter about the deterministic model when σ = 0 yields E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) = F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) + F ɛ i(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σe t ɛ i t ! F ɛ i ɛ j(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 2 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t ! F ɛ i ɛ j ɛ l(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 3 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t O(σ k+1 ), for i, j, l = 1,..., n ɛ. The Taylor series expansion is non-stochastic and nonlinear in the state (x t, z t ), and it is linear in the first k moments E t ɛ i t+1, E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1,... for i, j,.. = 1,..., n ɛ of the exogenous shock distribution. F ɛ i( ), for instance, denotes the derivative of F ( ) with respect to the exogenous shock ɛ i, F ɛ i ɛ j( ) denotes the derivative of F ɛ i( ) with respect to ɛj, and so on, and it 14

15 is resorted to Tensor notation only to suppress summation signs. Proof. The proof of Proposition 1 is an application of the stochastic version of Taylor s theorem. See Appendix. The approximation of the stochastic equilibrium system by the k-th order Taylor series thus delivers a non-stochastic system of equations which preserves the nonlinearities of the equilibrium conditions in the state vector (x t, z t ), but which explicitly takes into account the stochastic environment of the rational expectations model. The respective Taylor coefficients are deterministic because the Taylor series is expanded about the deterministic model when σ = 0. By taking the expectations conditional on the observed state (x t, z t ), the k-th order Taylor series is linear in the first k moments of the shock distribution. Therefore, in the neighborhood of the deterministic model F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )), the Taylor series approximation to the equilibrium system captures the effect of the stochastics on the true model up to the first k moments. Note that the kth-order Taylor series expansion in Proposition 1 is exact if either higher moments of the exogenous shock distribution are zero, or if derivatives to F ( ) of all higher-orders are zero. 7 Moreover, the Taylor series expansion converges to the exact equilibrium system in k if F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) is analytic in the neighborhood of the given state (x t, z t ). Using the definition of F ( ), the approximation to the equilibrium system in 7 An example is the simple consumption-savings problem with CARA utility function (see Supplement B). 15

16 Proposition 1 can be stated explicitly as E t f(y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, z t+1 ) = f (y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, m(z t, 0)) + f ɛ i (y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, m(z t, 0)) σe t ɛ i t ! f ɛ i ɛ j (y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, m(z t, 0)) σ 2 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t ! f ɛ i ɛ j ɛ (y t, x l t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, m(z t, 0)) σ 3 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t O(σ k+1 ) f σ (y t, x t, z t, y t+1, x t+1, m(z t, 0)) + O(σ k+1 ), (6) where the law of motion for the exogenous state variables implies z t+1 = m(z t, 0) in the deterministic case when σ = 0. The associated actual law of motion for z t is appropriately approximated by the k-th order Taylor expansion in the perturbation parameter about the deterministic law, z t+1 = m(z t, 0) + m ɛ i(z t, 0)σɛ i t ! m ɛ i ɛ j(z t, 0)σ 2 ɛ i t+1ɛ j t ! m ɛ i ɛ j ɛ l(z t, 0)σ 3 ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t O(σ k+1 ) m σ (z t, 0) + O(σ k+1 ). The solution to the approximated equilibrium system is denoted by x t+1 = h σ (x t, z t ) and y t = g σ (x t, z t ), with z t+1 = m σ (z t, 0). Substituting the solution process into the approximated system of nonlinear stochastic 16

17 equilibrium equations in (6) again allows to restate the system in terms of the current state and the respective solution to the endogenous variables as F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) f σ (g σ (x t, z t ), x t, z t, g σ (h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t, 0)), h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t, 0)). The k-th order Taylor expansion of the general model in the perturbation parameter σ about the deterministic model when σ = 0 can be stated as 0 = F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) z t+1 = m σ (z t, 0). (7) The approximated equilibrium system itself is now a system of n equations describing the joint equilibrium process for the endogenous variables y t, x t, y t+1, and x t+1, taking as given the process of the exogenous variables z t and z t+1 = m σ (z t, 0). The useful implication is that we can seek the solution to the new equilibrium system in (6), i.e. g σ ( ) and h σ ( ), as the proper approximation to the true solution g( ) and h( ) of the original problem in (3). Importantly, the solution to (6) is then also parameterized in the first k moments of the exogenous disturbances. Moreover, the approximation error relative to the true stochastic equilibrium system is in the order of O(σ k+1 ) (see Proposition 1). It is thus a quantitative statement about the accuracy of the approximated equilibrium system. It is also a statement about the accuracy of the solution process g σ ( ) and h σ ( ) as the approximation to the true solution because O(σ k+1 ) simply denotes the expected Euler residual of the exact solution to the new equilibrium system (6). To see this, note that E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) + O(σ k+1 ) = O(σ k+1 ). (8) This will be exploited in Section 5 where accuracy properties are discussed. 17

18 Remark on the approximation of the stochastic equilibrium system. In the rational expectations model, approximating the stochastic equilibrium conditions requires to take into account the response of the endogenous non-predetermined variables y t+1 to exogenous disturbances ɛ t+1 and thereby changes in the exogenous state z t+1. Because the approximated equilibrium system AES is the Taylor series expansion about the deterministic model when σ = 0, the endogenous responses to changes in the exogenous shocks are computed from the solution to the deterministic model. These equilibrium responses of the endogenous non-predetermined variables to changes in the exogenous state, gz( ) 0 and gzz( ), 0 are computed from solving Fz 0 (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) = 0 and Fz,z(x 0 t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) = 0. This refers to standard approaches as explained in detail for instance in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) and Jin and Judd (2002). A general derivation of the 2nd-order AES is provided in the Supplemental Material. For explicit examples of how to compute the 2nd-order AES, compare the applications of the AES-approach to the consumption-savings problem (Supplement B) and the asset pricing model (Supplement C). 4.2 Step 2: Computing the Linear Solution to the AES The second step of the solution procedure is to compute the functional form of the solution to the endogenous variables g σ ( ) and h σ ( ) from the non-stochastic and nonlinear vector difference equation in (6). To compute the linear solution, first it is solved for the steady state to the AES which is defined as follows: Definition 1 (Steady State). The steady state (ȳ σ, x σ, z) of the AES satisfies ȳ σ = g σ ( x σ, z) and x σ = h σ ( x σ, z), with z = m( z, 0), where the shock realization is ɛ = 0 and ȳ σ, x σ and z solve F σ ( x σ, z; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0. 18

19 This definition of the steady state to the AES is the natural extension of the definition of the deterministic steady state to stochastic setups. It also corresponds to the definition of the risky or stochastic steady state as in Juillard (2012) and Coeurdacier et al. (2011). The linear solution to the AES is then computed by the first-order Taylor series approximation to g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) about the steady state (ȳ σ, x σ, z), i.e. g σ ( x σ + δ x, z + δ z ) = ȳ σ + g σ x( x σ, z)δ x + g σ z ( x σ, z)δ z, and h σ ( x σ + δ x, z + δ z ) = x σ + h σ x( x σ, z)δ x + h σ z ( x σ, z)δ z. The first-order Taylor coefficients gq σ ( ) and h σ q ( ) are computed from solving Fq σ ( x σ, z; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0 for q = x, z, respectively, following the standard procedure. Similarly, higher-order approximations to g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) can be computed analogously. 5 Approximation Error of the AES, the Euler Residuals, and Accuracy Properties In this section, a discussion of the error of the Taylor series approximation of the equilibrium system AES and its implication for the accuracy of the approximated solution follows. 5.1 The Approximation Error of the AES and the Euler Residuals The accuracy properties of numerical solutions are commonly assessed by computing Euler equation residuals. Such accuracy tests are proposed in den Haan and Marcet 19

20 (1994) and Santos (2000). Applying this concept to our setup, the Euler residual associated with the solution process g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) is defined as the residual of the true stochastic equilibrium system evaluated at this solution process: Definition 2 (Euler Residuals). Let g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) denote the solution process for the endogenous variables which solve the equilibrium system F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0. The corresponding Euler residual Ut+1 σ is defined as U σ t+1 = F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )). This definition of the Euler residual restates the usual Euler residual as in den Haan and Marcet (1994) in terms of the functional form of the solution to the approximated equilibrium. The Euler residuals are thus the prediction errors to the true expectational equilibrium conditions in F ( ) associated with the respective solution process. For the true solution process g(x t, z t ) and h(x t, z t ), in the rational expectations equilibrium the average Euler residual converges to zero. The following proposition presents the convergence statement about the average Euler residual corresponding to the exact solution to the approximated equilibrium system, g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ). Proposition 2. Let g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) denote the solution to the kth-order Taylor series approximation to the stochastic equilibrium system, F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0. Then 1 T T Ut+s σ s=1 a.s. O(σ k+1 ) as T, where O(σ k+1 ) denotes the error of the Taylor approximation to the true stochastic equilibrium system. Proof. See Appendix. 20

21 5.2 The Approximation Error of the AES and the Accuracy of the Exact Solution to the AES Recall from the discussion of Proposition 1 that the difference between the original stochastic equilibrium system E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) and the kth-order Taylor approximation AES is simply the approximation error (see equation (8)). Proposition 2 states that the average Euler residual of the exact solution the AES, g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) with F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0, converges to the approximation error of the AES to the original stochastic equilibrium system which is in the order of O(σ k+1 ). As a consequence, the accuracy of the approximation to the solution increases in the order k of the Taylor series approximation F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) to the stochastic equilibrium system, too. This is stated formally in the next Proposition. Proposition 3. Let g(x t, z t ) and h(x t, z t ) denote the true solution and let g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) denote the solution to the kth-order Taylor series approximation to the stochastic equilibrium system F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0. Then g(x t, z t ) g σ (x t, z t ) = O(σ k+1 ) and h(x t, z t ) h σ (x t, z t ) = O(σ k+1 ), where O(σ k+1 ) denotes a term in the order of magnitude of the error of the Taylor approximation to the true stochastic equilibrium system. Proof. See Appendix. The approximation error of the solution g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) to the AES is therefore bounded by a term which is of the same order of magnitude as the Euler error and the approximation error of the AES to the true stochastic system, respectively (compare also Santos (2000)). As a result, solving nonlinear rational expectations models by first approximating the equilibrium system yields not only the moments of the exogenous shock distribution to become parameters of the model and its solution. It also increases the accuracy of the approximated solution process in the order k of 21

22 the Taylor approximation to the true stochastic equilibrium system relative to the conventional procedure when computing the solution directly from the deterministic model (k = 0). 5.3 The Approximation Error of the AES and the Accuracy of the Linearized Solution to the AES The result of Proposition 3 can be translated into accuracy statements about the steady state as well as first- and higher-order derivatives of the solution process g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) at its steady state. Specifically, define the corresponding steady state of the true stochastic system by (ȳ, x, z), where the equilibrium system is exposed to uncertainty, but where the endogenous and exogenous state variables remain unchanged and solve x = h( x, z) and M( z, z, 0) = 0 with z = m( z, 0), respectively. The steady state of the true stochastic system then solves E t F ( x, z, σɛ t+1 ; g( x, z), h( x, z)) = 0 with ȳ = g( x, z). Proposition Let (ȳ, x, z) denote the steady state of the true stochastic equilibrium system and (ȳ σ, x σ, z) the steady state of the AES. Then ȳ ȳ σ = O(σ k+1 ) and x x σ = O(σ k+1 ). 2. Let g s p,s q,...,s u( x, z) and h s p,s q,...,su( x, z) denote the r-th order derivatives of the true solution at the steady state (ȳ, x, z) and g σ s p,s q,...,s u( xσ, z) and g σ s p,s q,...,s u( xσ, z) the r-th order derivatives of the exact solution to the AES at the steady state (ȳ σ, x σ, z). Then g s p,s q,...,s u( x, z) gσ s p,s q,...,s u( xσ, z) = O(σ k+1 ) and h s p,s q,...,s u( x, z) hσ s p,s q,...,s u( xσ, z) = O(σ k+1 ), with s = [x, z ] and p, q, u = 1,..., n x + n z. 22

23 Proof. See Appendix. From Proposition 4 follows immediately that the implied error of the linearized solution to the approximated equilibrium system is also bounded by a term in the order of magnitude of O(σ k+1 ). Corollary 1. Let g(x t, z t ) and h(x t, z t ) denote the linearized solution to the true stochastic equilibrium system computed about (ȳ, x, z), and let g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) denote the linearized solution to the AES computed about (ȳ σ, x σ, z). Then g(x t, z t ) g σ (x t, z t ) = O(σ k+1 ) and h(xt, z t ) h σ (x t, z t ) = O(σ k+1 ). Proof. See Appendix. Corollary 1 states that the approximation error of the linearized solution is of the same order of magnitude as the size of the Euler error of the k-th order AES. It shows that the characteristic equilibrium interaction between the stochastic environment and nonlinearities has indeed first-order implications on the solution. Capturing this effect therefore increases the accuracy of the linearized solution. The solution to the AES linearized in the state vector thus fully captures these effects up the kth moments of the exogenous shock distribution. Note that the conventional wisdom about linear solutions is that they cannot account for uncertainty. This is trivially true if the linear solution is computed for the deterministic model where the stochastic environment is neglected. Once it is computed for an approximated equilibrium system that explicitly takes into account the stochastic environment, the linear solution to this approximated system is no longer independent of uncertainty. Discussion of the Implications. Capturing the first-order implications of risk in the linear solution might have important consequences for the analysis of the model economy, because the linear solution already determines the key properties of the model such as the dynamic behavior and the equilibrium distribution. Most notably, 23

24 because the linear solution to the kth-order AES captures equilibrium implications of nonlinearities in the stochastic environment up to the first k moments, the AESapproach also captures the effect of risk on the equilibrium properties with respect to existence and uniqueness up to the first k moments. This is in stark contrast to the conventional perturbation approach. The conventional perturbation cannot take into account the equilibrium implications of risk because existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium is generically assessed for the deterministic model (i.e. the 0thorder AES). This is true not only for the conventional linear solution but for any order of the conventional approximation approach. It is also worth pointing out the relevance of the above results for using the approximated solution to the model for simulation, estimation, and forecasting. Consider for instance likelihood based methods. Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2006) demonstrate that for a given sample size T the likelihood associated with the approximated solution to the stochastic equilibrium model converges to the true likelihood as the approximation error to the solution becomes smaller (Proposition 1, p. 101). Moreover, in a comment on Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2006), Ackerberg et al. (2009) show that as T increases, the difference between the maximum likelihood parameter estimates of the approximated solution and the true parameters converges to a term which is in the same order of magnitude as the approximation error, i.e. O(σ k+1 ) (Theorem 2, p. 2015). These results imply that computing the solution from the kth-order AES also increases the accuracy of the parameter inference based on the approximated solution process. Similar accuracy statements can be made about forecasts based on the linear solution to the AES. The one-step-ahead forecast based on the linear solution to the kth-order AES can be stated as y t+1 x t+2 = gσ (h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t )) h σ (h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t )) + O p ( ẑ t+1 ) + O( ˆx t+1 + σ k+1 ), 24

25 where g σ (x t, z t ) and h σ (x t, z t ) denote the linearized solution to the AES computed about (ȳ σ, x σ, z) and where ˆx t+1 = x σ x t+1 and ẑ t+1 = z z t+1 are the deviations from steady state. The term O p ( ẑ t+1 ) denotes the order of magnitude in probability. As a consequence, the accuracy of the one-step-ahead forecast based on the DSGE model is also increasing in the order k. Accuracy statements about n-step-ahead forecasts are obtained accordingly. Supplement C provides an application of the AES-approach to the asset pricing model taken from Burnside (1998). The model permits an exact assessment of the accuracy of the AES-approach. The exercise substantiates the theoretical accuracy results quantitatively: The approximation error of the linear solution to the 2ndorder AES is 1-2 orders of magnitude smaller than the approximation error of the conventional linear solution for the steady state and coefficients linear in the state variable, the equilibrium distribution, and the maximum likelihood estimates of the deep parameters. The exercise also demonstrates how the AES-approach captures the implications of risk on the existence and uniqueness of the solution which is completely absent in the conventional perturbation approach of any order. When comparing the linear solution to the 2nd-order AES to the conventional 2nd-order approximation, the numerical example indicates that it is more important to capture the equilibrium effects of nonlinearities associated with risk on the slope (linear coefficient) than to capture the nonlinearities of the solution through higher-order terms in the state-vector in the conventional 2nd-order solution. 6 Concluding Remarks This paper demonstrates how to compute a linear solution to a DSGE model that accounts for the interaction between nonlinearities and the stochastic environment. The fundamental concept of the AES-approach is to disentangle the account of the 25

26 stochastic environment of the original set of equilibrium conditions in the first step from computing the functional form of the solution processes in the second step. Once this separation is made, it is obvious that computing the functional form of the solution processes to approximated equilibrium system is not restricted to perturbation methods at all but any local or global method is applicable, too. Here, the attention is restricted to the linear solution to the AES because of the simplicity and widespread use of linear methods in solving and estimating DSGE models. 26

27 A Proofs of the Propositions Proof of Proposition 1. By the stochastic Taylor s Theorem, at a given state (x t, z t ), there exists a measurable function ξ(ɛ t+1 ) [0, σɛ t+1 ] such that for the k-th order Taylor series expansion of the stochastic equilibrium system F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) in the perturbation parameter about the deterministic model when σ = 0, F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) = F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) + F ɛ i(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σɛ i t ! F ɛ i,ɛ j(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 2 ɛ i t+1ɛ j t ! F ɛ i,ɛ j,ɛ l(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 3 ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t R(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 ))σ k+1, for i, j, l,... = 1,..., n ɛ. Note that by assumption (Regularity condition), the k + 1-th derivatives of F ( ) exist. R(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 ))σ k+1 denotes the measurable remainder of the Taylor series which must be finite almost surely for the equilibrium system to hold. The remainder is thus in probability in the order of magnitude of O p (σ k+1 ). For instance, in case of k = 2, R(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 )) = 1 F 3! ɛ i,ɛ j,ɛ l(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 ))ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t+1. Taking expectations then implies with E t R(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 )) < and thus E t R(x t, z t, ξ(ɛ t+1 ))σ k+1 = O(σ k+1 ) that E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) = F (x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( )) + F ɛ i(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σe t ɛ i t ! F ɛ i,ɛ j(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 2 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t ! F ɛ i,ɛ j,ɛ l(x t, z t, 0; g 0 ( ), h 0 ( ))σ 3 E t ɛ i t+1ɛ j t+1ɛ l t O(σ k+1 ). 27

28 Note that by the definition of the approximated equilibrium system in (AES-Sol), the above equation can be restated as E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g( ), h( )) = F σ (x t, z t ; g( ), h( )) + O(σ k+1 ). Consequently, the exact solution to the AES, g σ ( ) and h σ ( ) solves F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = 0 which implies E t F (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) + O(σ k+1 ) = O(σ k+1 ). (9) Proof of Proposition 2. Using the definition of the approximated equilibrium system in (7) and in Proposition 1, F σ (x t, z t ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )), the Euler residuals can be stated as the sum of the Euler residuals to the approximated equilibrium system plus the approximation error of the approximated equilibrium system to the true equilibrium system, i.e. U σ t+s+1 = F (x t+s, z t+s, σɛ t+s+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) = F σ (x t+s, z t+s, σɛ t+s+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) + R(x t+s, z t+s, ξ(ɛ t+s+1 ))σ k+1, where F σ (x t+s, z t+s, σɛ t+s+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) is finite for all s and independently distributed with mean zero. The approximation error R(x t+s, z t+s, ξ(ɛ t+s+1 ))σ k+1 is finite for all s, independently distributed, and its mean is in the order of magnitude of O(σ k+1 ). By the law of large numbers 1 T T F σ (x t+s, z t+s, σɛ t+s+1 ; g σ ( ), h σ ( )) s=1 a.s. 0 as T, because g σ ( ) and h σ ( ) is the exact solution to AES, and 1 T T R(x t+s, z t+s, ξ(ɛ t+s+1 ))σ k+1 s=1 a.s. O(σ k+1 ) as T, 28

29 which together imply that 1 T T Ut+s σ s=1 a.s. O(σ k+1 ) as T. Proof of Proposition 3. By the mean value theorem, there exists some finite n (n y + n x + n z ) matrix W (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) at (x t, z t ) for each σɛ t+1 such that f(g(x t, z t ), x t, z t, g(h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )) =f(g σ (x t, z t ), x t, z t, g σ (h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t, 0)), h σ (x t, z t ), m σ (z t, 0)) g(x t, z t ) g σ (x t, z t ) + W (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) h(x t, z t ) h σ (x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) m σ (z t, 0) (10) where W (x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) = [W g ( ) W h ( ) W m ( )] with W i g(x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) = f i g(x t,z t)( g(x t, z t ), x t, z t, g( h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )) W i h(x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) = f i h(x t,z t)( g(x t, z t ), x t, z t, g( h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )) W i m(x t, z t, σɛ t+1 ) = f i m(z t,σɛ t+1 )( g(x t, z t ), x t, z t, g( h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), h(x t, z t ), m(z t, σɛ t+1 )), for g(x t, z t ) = (1 τ i )g(x t, z t )+τ i g σ (x t, z t ), h(x t, z t ) = (1 τ i )h(x t, z t )+τ i h σk (x t, z t ), and m(x t, z t ) = (1 τ i )m(z t, σɛ t+1 ) + τ i m σ (z t, 0) with τ i [0, 1] for all equations i = 1,..., n. 29

Perturbation Methods I: Basic Results

Perturbation Methods I: Basic Results Perturbation Methods I: Basic Results (Lectures on Solution Methods for Economists V) Jesús Fernández-Villaverde 1 and Pablo Guerrón 2 March 19, 2018 1 University of Pennsylvania 2 Boston College Introduction

More information

Ambiguous Business Cycles: Online Appendix

Ambiguous Business Cycles: Online Appendix Ambiguous Business Cycles: Online Appendix By Cosmin Ilut and Martin Schneider This paper studies a New Keynesian business cycle model with agents who are averse to ambiguity (Knightian uncertainty). Shocks

More information

Solution Methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. March 16, 2016

Solution Methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. March 16, 2016 Solution Methods Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania March 16, 2016 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Solution Methods March 16, 2016 1 / 36 Functional equations A large class of problems

More information

An Introduction to Perturbation Methods in Macroeconomics. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

An Introduction to Perturbation Methods in Macroeconomics. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania An Introduction to Perturbation Methods in Macroeconomics Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Introduction Numerous problems in macroeconomics involve functional equations of the form:

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES A THEORY OF PRUNING NO 1696 / JULY Giovanni Lombardo and Harald Uhlig

WORKING PAPER SERIES A THEORY OF PRUNING NO 1696 / JULY Giovanni Lombardo and Harald Uhlig WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1696 / JULY 2014 A THEORY OF PRUNING Giovanni Lombardo and Harald Uhlig In 2014 all ECB publications feature a motif taken from the 20 banknote. NOTE: This Working Paper should

More information

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations Sungbae An Singapore Management University Bank Indonesia/BIS Workshop: STRUCTURAL DYNAMIC MACROECONOMIC MODELS IN ASIA-PACIFIC

More information

Risky Linear Approximations

Risky Linear Approximations Risky Linear Approximations Alexander Meyer-Gohde This Version: June 13, 2014 Abstract I construct risk-corrected approximations around the stochastic steady state and ergodic mean that are linear in the

More information

Perturbation Methods II: General Case

Perturbation Methods II: General Case Perturbation Methods II: General Case (Lectures on Solution Methods for Economists VI) Jesús Fernández-Villaverde 1 and Pablo Guerrón 2 February 21, 2018 1 University of Pennsylvania 2 Boston College The

More information

SMOOTHIES: A Toolbox for the Exact Nonlinear and Non-Gaussian Kalman Smoother *

SMOOTHIES: A Toolbox for the Exact Nonlinear and Non-Gaussian Kalman Smoother * SMOOTHIES: A Toolbox for the Exact Nonlinear and Non-Gaussian Kalman Smoother * Joris de Wind September 2017 Abstract In this paper, I present a new toolbox that implements the exact nonlinear and non-

More information

A Model with Collateral Constraints

A Model with Collateral Constraints A Model with Collateral Constraints Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 2, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Collateral Constraints December 2, 2012 1 / 47 Motivation Kiyotaki

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. A note on Kalman filter approach to solution of rational expectations models

Volume 30, Issue 3. A note on Kalman filter approach to solution of rational expectations models Volume 30, Issue 3 A note on Kalman filter approach to solution of rational expectations models Marco Maria Sorge BGSE, University of Bonn Abstract In this note, a class of nonlinear dynamic models under

More information

Approximation around the risky steady state

Approximation around the risky steady state Approximation around the risky steady state Centre for International Macroeconomic Studies Conference University of Surrey Michel Juillard, Bank of France September 14, 2012 The views expressed herein

More information

Perturbation Methods

Perturbation Methods Perturbation Methods Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania May 28, 2015 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods May 28, 2015 1 / 91 Introduction Introduction Remember that

More information

Second-order approximation of dynamic models without the use of tensors

Second-order approximation of dynamic models without the use of tensors Second-order approximation of dynamic models without the use of tensors Paul Klein a, a University of Western Ontario First draft: May 17, 2005 This version: January 24, 2006 Abstract Several approaches

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Perturbation Methods for Markov-Switching DSGE Models

Perturbation Methods for Markov-Switching DSGE Models Perturbation Methods for Markov-Switching DSGE Models Andrew Foerster, Juan Rubio-Ramirez, Daniel F. Waggoner, and Tao Zha February 2013; Revised November 2015 RWP 13-01 PERTURBATION METHODS FOR MARKOV-SWITCHING

More information

A robust Hansen Sargent prediction formula

A robust Hansen Sargent prediction formula Economics Letters 71 (001) 43 48 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase A robust Hansen Sargent prediction formula Kenneth Kasa* Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 770, San

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction. 1.1 Background

Chapter 1. Introduction. 1.1 Background Chapter 1 Introduction Science is facts; just as houses are made of stones, so is science made of facts; but a pile of stones is not a house and a collection of facts is not necessarily science. Henri

More information

Solutions Methods in DSGE (Open) models

Solutions Methods in DSGE (Open) models Solutions Methods in DSGE (Open) models 1. With few exceptions, there are not exact analytical solutions for DSGE models, either open or closed economy. This is due to a combination of nonlinearity and

More information

Applications for solving DSGE models. October 25th, 2011

Applications for solving DSGE models. October 25th, 2011 MATLAB Workshop Applications for solving DSGE models Freddy Rojas Cama Marola Castillo Quinto Preliminary October 25th, 2011 A model to solve The model The model A model is set up in order to draw conclusions

More information

Asset pricing in DSGE models comparison of different approximation methods

Asset pricing in DSGE models comparison of different approximation methods Asset pricing in DSGE models comparison of different approximation methods 1 Introduction Jan Acedański 1 Abstract. There are many numerical methods suitable for approximating solutions of DSGE models.

More information

Risk Matters: Breaking Certainty Equivalence

Risk Matters: Breaking Certainty Equivalence Risk Matters: Breaking Certainty Equivalence Juan Carlos Parra-Alvarez (a,c), Hamza Polattimur (b), and Olaf Posch (b,c) (a) Aarhus University, (b) Universität Hamburg, (c) CREATES February 2017 Abstract

More information

Nonlinear and/or Non-normal Filtering. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Nonlinear and/or Non-normal Filtering. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania Nonlinear and/or Non-normal Filtering Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Motivation Nonlinear and/or non-gaussian filtering, smoothing, and forecasting (NLGF) problems are pervasive

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA On the Solution of the Growth Model with Investment-Specific Technological Change Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan Francisco Rubio-Ramírez Working Paper 2004-39 December

More information

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011 Department of Economics University of Maryland Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011 Objective As a stepping stone to learning how to work with and computationally

More information

Working Paper Series. on approximating Dsge models. expansions. No 1264 / november by Giovanni Lombardo

Working Paper Series. on approximating Dsge models. expansions. No 1264 / november by Giovanni Lombardo Working Paper Series No 1264 / november 21 on approximating Dsge models by series expansions by Giovanni Lombardo WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1264 / NOVEMBER 21 ON APPROXIMATING DSGE MODELS BY SERIES EXPANSIONS

More information

Perturbation Methods with Nonlinear Changes of Variables K L. J H I S, CA April, 2002

Perturbation Methods with Nonlinear Changes of Variables K L. J H I S, CA April, 2002 Perturbation Methods with Nonlinear Changes of Variables K L. J H I S, CA 94305 @.. April, 2002 A. The perturbation method is commonly used to approximate solutions to dynamic economic models. Two types

More information

Taking Perturbation to the Accuracy Frontier: A Hybrid of Local and Global Solutions

Taking Perturbation to the Accuracy Frontier: A Hybrid of Local and Global Solutions Dynare Working Papers Series http://www.dynare.org/wp/ Taking Perturbation to the Accuracy Frontier: A Hybrid of Local and Global Solutions Lilia Maliar Serguei Maliar Sébastien Villemot Working Paper

More information

DYNARE SUMMER SCHOOL

DYNARE SUMMER SCHOOL DYNARE SUMMER SCHOOL Introduction to Dynare and local approximation. Michel Juillard June 12, 2017 Summer School website http://www.dynare.org/summerschool/2017 DYNARE 1. computes the solution of deterministic

More information

Solving Linear Rational Expectation Models

Solving Linear Rational Expectation Models Solving Linear Rational Expectation Models Dr. Tai-kuang Ho Associate Professor. Department of Quantitative Finance, National Tsing Hua University, No. 101, Section 2, Kuang-Fu Road, Hsinchu, Taiwan 30013,

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Dynamics of Externalities: A Second-Order Perspective Yi Wen and Huabin Wu Working Paper 8-44B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/8/8-44.pdf

More information

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions William D. Lastrapes Department of Economics Terry College of Business University of Georgia Athens,

More information

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics Thomas M. Mertens NYU Stern Risk Economics Lab April 17, 2012 1 / 78 Motivation Many problems in finance and economics are high dimensional. Dynamic Optimization:

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

News or Noise? The Missing Link

News or Noise? The Missing Link News or Noise? The Missing Link Ryan Chahrour Boston College Kyle Jurado Duke University September 7, 2016 Abstract The macroeconomic literature on belief-driven business cycles treats news and noise as

More information

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 3

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 3 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B Lecture 3 Giulio Fella c Giulio Fella, 2014 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B - Lecture 3 84/197 Predictions of the PICH 1. Marginal propensity to consume out of wealth windfalls 0.03.

More information

Estimation of moment-based models with latent variables

Estimation of moment-based models with latent variables Estimation of moment-based models with latent variables work in progress Ra aella Giacomini and Giuseppe Ragusa UCL/Cemmap and UCI/Luiss UPenn, 5/4/2010 Giacomini and Ragusa (UCL/Cemmap and UCI/Luiss)Moments

More information

Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS

Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 1. A LIST OF PITFALLS Linearized models are of course valid only locally. In stochastic economic models, this usually

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania, NBER, and CEPR Juan Rubio-Ramírez Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Estimating Dynamic Macroeconomic

More information

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002 Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002 Tim Uy University of Cambridge March 10, 2015 Introduction Solving DSGE models used to be very time consuming due to log-linearization required Dynare is a collection

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco (FEUNL) Macroeconomics Theory II February 2016 1 / 18 Road Map Research question: we want to understand businesses cycles.

More information

First order approximation of stochastic models

First order approximation of stochastic models First order approximation of stochastic models Shanghai Dynare Workshop Sébastien Villemot CEPREMAP October 27, 2013 Sébastien Villemot (CEPREMAP) First order approximation of stochastic models October

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 This note describes very briefly how to conduct quantitative analysis on a linearized

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Under Remittance Fluctuations. Technical Appendix and Additional Results

Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Under Remittance Fluctuations. Technical Appendix and Additional Results Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Under Remittance Fluctuations Technical Appendix and Additional Results Federico Mandelman February In this appendix, I provide technical details on the Bayesian estimation.

More information

BEAR 4.2. Introducing Stochastic Volatility, Time Varying Parameters and Time Varying Trends. A. Dieppe R. Legrand B. van Roye ECB.

BEAR 4.2. Introducing Stochastic Volatility, Time Varying Parameters and Time Varying Trends. A. Dieppe R. Legrand B. van Roye ECB. BEAR 4.2 Introducing Stochastic Volatility, Time Varying Parameters and Time Varying Trends A. Dieppe R. Legrand B. van Roye ECB 25 June 2018 The views expressed in this presentation are the authors and

More information

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Cosmin Ilut Duke & NBER Pavel Krivenko Stanford March 2016 Martin Schneider Stanford & NBER Abstract This paper proposes a simple perturbation

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

Decentralised economies I

Decentralised economies I Decentralised economies I Martin Ellison 1 Motivation In the first two lectures on dynamic programming and the stochastic growth model, we solved the maximisation problem of the representative agent. More

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Modeling the Evolution of Expectations and Uncertainty in General Equilibrium Francesco Bianchi and Leonardo Melosi September 2013 WP 2013-12 Modeling the Evolution of Expectations

More information

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Outline State space-observer form. convenient for model estimation and many other things. Bayesian inference Bayes rule. Monte Carlo integation.

More information

Nonlinear Solution of Heterogeneous Agent Models by Approximate Aggregation

Nonlinear Solution of Heterogeneous Agent Models by Approximate Aggregation Nonlinear Solution of Heterogeneous Agent Models by Approximate Aggregation Michael Reiter, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna February 21 Abstract The paper deals with the computation of DSGE models

More information

1 Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models

1 Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models September 29, 2001 SCHUR.TEX Economics 731 International Monetary University of Pennsylvania Theory and Policy Martín Uribe Fall 2001 1 Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models Consider a vector x t

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/23 Housekeeping. Class organization. Website with notes and papers as no "Mas-Collel" in macro

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018 Lecture 2 (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings Erick Sager February 6, 2018 Econ 606: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Spring 2018 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (2/6/18)

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Zurich, September 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Address the Following Type of Question:

More information

Nonlinear and Stable Perturbation-Based Approximations

Nonlinear and Stable Perturbation-Based Approximations Nonlinear and Stable Perturbation-Based Approximations Wouter J. Den Haan and Joris De Wind April 26, 2012 Abstract Users of regular higher-order perturbation approximations can face two problems: policy

More information

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-2, 417 423 (2015) Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles Andrea Beccarini University of Münster, Department of Economics, Am Stadtgraben 9, 48143, Münster,

More information

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Lecture 4: The state space representation and the Kalman Filter Hernán D. Seoane UC3M January, 2016 Today s lecture State space representation

More information

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Matthew Osborne University of Toronto November 25, 2013 Abstract

More information

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Outline State space-observer form. convenient for model estimation and many other things. Bayesian inference Bayes rule. Monte Carlo integation.

More information

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability. Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability. Literature Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (JPE 1997): Ramsey model with endogenous labor income tax + balanced budget (fiscal)

More information

A comparison of numerical methods for the. Solution of continuous-time DSGE models. Juan Carlos Parra Alvarez

A comparison of numerical methods for the. Solution of continuous-time DSGE models. Juan Carlos Parra Alvarez A comparison of numerical methods for the solution of continuous-time DSGE models Juan Carlos Parra Alvarez Department of Economics and Business, and CREATES Aarhus University, Denmark November 14, 2012

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PERTURBATION METHODS FOR MARKOV-SWITCHING DSGE MODELS. Andrew Foerster Juan Rubio-Ramírez Daniel F.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PERTURBATION METHODS FOR MARKOV-SWITCHING DSGE MODELS. Andrew Foerster Juan Rubio-Ramírez Daniel F. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PERTURBATION METHODS FOR MARKOV-SWITCHING DSGE MODELS Andrew Foerster Juan Rubio-Ramírez Daniel F. Waggoner Tao Zha Working Paper 20390 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20390 NATIONAL

More information

Comparing Accuracy of Second Order Approximation and Dynamic Programming

Comparing Accuracy of Second Order Approximation and Dynamic Programming Comparing Accuracy of Second Order Approximation and Dynamic Programming Stephanie Becker, Lars Grüne and Willi Semmler June 6, revised version January 7 Abstract The accuracy of the solution of dynamic

More information

Perturbation and Projection Methods for Solving DSGE Models

Perturbation and Projection Methods for Solving DSGE Models Perturbation and Projection Methods for Solving DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Discussion of projections taken from Christiano Fisher, Algorithms for Solving Dynamic Models with Occasionally Binding

More information

An approximate consumption function

An approximate consumption function An approximate consumption function Mario Padula Very Preliminary and Very Incomplete 8 December 2005 Abstract This notes proposes an approximation to the consumption function in the buffer-stock model.

More information

Title. Description. Remarks and examples. stata.com. stata.com. Introduction to DSGE models. intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge

Title. Description. Remarks and examples. stata.com. stata.com. Introduction to DSGE models. intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge Title stata.com intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge Description Remarks and examples References Also see Description In this entry, we introduce DSGE models and the dsge command. We begin with an overview

More information

Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average

Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average SFB 649 Discussion Paper 211-87 Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average Hong Lan* Alexander Meyer-Gohde* * Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Germany SFB 6 4 9 E C O N O M I C R I S K B E R L

More information

Switching Regime Estimation

Switching Regime Estimation Switching Regime Estimation Series de Tiempo BIrkbeck March 2013 Martin Sola (FE) Markov Switching models 01/13 1 / 52 The economy (the time series) often behaves very different in periods such as booms

More information

A Method for Solving DSGE Models with Dispersed Private Information 1

A Method for Solving DSGE Models with Dispersed Private Information 1 A Method for Solving DSGE Models with Dispersed Private Information Cedric Tille Geneva Graduate Institute HEID and CEPR Eric van Wincoop University of Virginia and NBER March 7, 20 Cedric Tille gratefully

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

Deterministic Models

Deterministic Models Deterministic Models Perfect foreight, nonlinearities and occasionally binding constraints Sébastien Villemot CEPREMAP June 10, 2014 Sébastien Villemot (CEPREMAP) Deterministic Models June 10, 2014 1 /

More information

ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting

ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting Economic time series often appear nonstationary, because of trends, seasonal patterns, cycles, etc. However, the differences may appear stationary. Δx t x t x t 1 (first

More information

Regime-Switching Perturbation for Non-Linear Equilibrium Models

Regime-Switching Perturbation for Non-Linear Equilibrium Models Regime-Switching Perturbation for Non-Linear Equilibrium Models Nelson Lind UC San Diego October 10, 2014 Abstract Salient macroeconomic problems often lead to highly non-linear models for instance models

More information

Optimal Policy with Partial Information in a Forward-Looking Model: Certainty-Equivalence Redux

Optimal Policy with Partial Information in a Forward-Looking Model: Certainty-Equivalence Redux SWCE206.tex Optimal Policy with Partial Information in a Forward-Looking Model: Certainty-Equivalence Redux Lars E.O. Svensson and Michael Woodford First draft: January 1999 This version: June 2002 Abstract

More information

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Mathematics for Economics and Finance Mathematics for Economics and Finance Michael Harrison and Patrick Waldron B 375482 Routledge Taylor & Francis Croup LONDON AND NEW YORK Contents List of figures ix List of tables xi Foreword xiii Preface

More information

News or Noise? The Missing Link

News or Noise? The Missing Link News or Noise? The Missing Link Ryan Chahrour Boston College Kyle Jurado Duke University November 2, 2017 Abstract The literature on belief-driven business cycles treats news and noise as distinct representations

More information

Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences

Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences Walt Pohl Karl Schmedders Ole Wilms Dept. of Business Administration, University of Zurich Becker Friedman Institute Computational

More information

Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average

Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average Solving DSGE Models with a Nonlinear Moving Average Hong Lan Alexander Meyer-Gohde This Version: July, Abstract We propose a nonlinear infinite moving average as an alternative to the standard state space

More information

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University Sept 2016 D. Liu (NJU) Solving D(S)GE 09/16 1 / 63 Introduction Targets of the

More information

ECO 513 Fall 2008 C.Sims KALMAN FILTER. s t = As t 1 + ε t Measurement equation : y t = Hs t + ν t. u t = r t. u 0 0 t 1 + y t = [ H I ] u t.

ECO 513 Fall 2008 C.Sims KALMAN FILTER. s t = As t 1 + ε t Measurement equation : y t = Hs t + ν t. u t = r t. u 0 0 t 1 + y t = [ H I ] u t. ECO 513 Fall 2008 C.Sims KALMAN FILTER Model in the form 1. THE KALMAN FILTER Plant equation : s t = As t 1 + ε t Measurement equation : y t = Hs t + ν t. Var(ε t ) = Ω, Var(ν t ) = Ξ. ε t ν t and (ε t,

More information

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations Technical Appendix Yongsung Chang Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania Frank Schorfheide Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania January

More information

Solving General Equilibrium Models. with Incomplete Markets and Many Assets

Solving General Equilibrium Models. with Incomplete Markets and Many Assets Solving General Equilibrium Models with Incomplete Markets and Many Assets June 23, 2006 Martin D. D. Evans Viktoria Hnatkovska Georgetown University and NBER Georgetown University Department of Economics

More information

Existence and Uniqueness of Perturbation Solutions in DSGE Models

Existence and Uniqueness of Perturbation Solutions in DSGE Models Dynare Working Papers Series http://www.dynare.org/wp/ Existence and Uniqueness of Perturbation Solutions in DSGE Models Hong Lan Alexander Meyer-Gohde Working Paper no. 14 September 2012 142, rue du Chevaleret

More information

Chapter 1 Theory and Econometrics

Chapter 1 Theory and Econometrics Chapter 1 Theory and Econometrics Complete market economies are all alike... Robert E. Lucas, Jr. (1989) 1.1. Introduction Economic theory identifies patterns that unite apparently diverse subjects. Consider

More information

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53 State-space Model Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia November 2014 Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics - 2014 1 / 53 Outline 1 Motivation 2 Introduction 3 The Kalman filter 4 Forecast errors 5 State

More information

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Friday September 8 th : Lecture 10 Gerzensee, September 2017 Roger E. A. Farmer Warwick University and NIESR Topics for Lecture 10 Tying together the pieces

More information

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Outline State space-observer form. convenient for model estimation and many other things. Preliminaries. Probabilities. Maximum Likelihood. Bayesian

More information

Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies

Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies A Brief Introduction Craig Burnside Duke University September 2006 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Discrete State Space Methods September 2006 1 / 42

More information

Matching DSGE models,vars, and state space models. Fabio Canova EUI and CEPR September 2012

Matching DSGE models,vars, and state space models. Fabio Canova EUI and CEPR September 2012 Matching DSGE models,vars, and state space models Fabio Canova EUI and CEPR September 2012 Outline Alternative representations of the solution of a DSGE model. Fundamentalness and finite VAR representation

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLUTION AND ESTIMATION METHODS FOR DSGE MODELS. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde Juan F. Rubio Ramírez Frank Schorfheide

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLUTION AND ESTIMATION METHODS FOR DSGE MODELS. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde Juan F. Rubio Ramírez Frank Schorfheide NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLUTION AND ESTIMATION METHODS FOR DSGE MODELS Jesús Fernández-Villaverde Juan F. Rubio Ramírez Frank Schorfheide Working Paper 21862 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21862 NATIONAL

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders

Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders Mikhail Anufriev Giulio Bottazzi S.Anna School for Advanced Studies, Pisa, Italy February 20, 2005

More information

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods) MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION IN A DSGE MODEL: PART II SEPTEMBER 30, 200 Canonical Dixit-Stiglitz Model MONOPOLISTICALLY-COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

More information

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework Online Appendix to the paper Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework October 5, 2015 Part I: Maturity specific shocks in affine and equilibrium models This Appendix present

More information

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide. Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide. Fabrice Collard (GREMAQ, University of Toulouse) Adapted for Dynare 4.1 by Michel Juillard and Sébastien Villemot (CEPREMAP) First draft: February

More information

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe Columbia University European Central Bank Conference on Monetary Policy Frankfurt am Main, October 29-3, 218

More information