Macroeconomics Summary

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Macroeconomics Summary"

Transcription

1 Macroeconomics Summary Rebecca Sela January 11, 2006 To describe an economic model, we require: The number of agents The number of goods (and how they are indexed Preferences for the agents Information about the endowments of the agents Information about the technology The trading mechanism A competitive equilibrium specifies an allocation and prices, such that the allocation solves each household s problem given the prices and the production solves the firm s problem under those prices. For more general optimization problems, the general set-up is: Choose... to maximize... such that... or given... 1 Linear Stochastic Difference Equations Definition A stochastic linear difference equation is given by the model: x 0 Normal(ˆx 0, Σ 0 x t+1 = Ax t + Cw t+1 y t = Gx t w t iid Normal(0, I for all t 0. In this model, we call x t the state (and assume that it is not observed, w t the shocks, and assume that y t is observed. 1

2 Note that x t is a Markov process, with x t+1 x t Normal(Ax t, CC T. To compute moments of x t, we note that x t = A t x 0 + A t 1 Cw 1 + A t 2 Cw ACw t 1 + Cw t µ xt = E(X t = A tˆx 0 Σ x,t = AΣ x,t 1 A T + CC T Note that µ xt+1 = Aµ xt, which is a non-stochastic linear difference equation for the mean. To be able to use these equations to estimate moments from data, we must impose covariance stationarity, so that µ yt and therefore µ xt are constant. Suppose we may write: ( ( ( ( x1,t x1,t 0 = + x 2,t+1 A 21 A 22 x 2,t C2 w t+1 (Note that the first term corresponds to a non-zero mean. Suppose that all of the eigenvalues of A 22 have modulus strictly less than 1. Then, we choose the mean, µ x, to be the eigenvector of A associated with the unit eigenvalue. If, instead, A has all of its eigenvalues strictly less than 1 (in modulus, we choose µ x = 0. For covariance stationarity, we must choose ˆx 0 = µ x. In addition, for covariance stationarity, we must have Σ x,t constant. This yields the discrete Lyapunov equation, Σ x = AΣ x A T + CC T (which can be solved by guessing any A T + CC T until it converges. We may also compute auto-covariances of x and y (assuming covariance stationarity, for simplicity: Σ (0 and iterating on Σ (n x = AΣ (n 1 x C x (j = E((x t+j µ x (x t µ x T = A j Σ x C y (j = GC x (jg T = GA j Σ x G T This yields a non-stochastic difference equation for the covariances as well. We may also compute conditional expectations: E(x t+j x t = A j x t E(y t+j x t = GA j x t We may transform an ARMA(p, q model for y t into this form by setting x t = (y t, y t 1,..., y t p, w t 1,..., w t q T, setting the first row of A equal to the coefficients (and the other rows equal to 0 s and 1 s so that the lags are moved back one period, C to a vector of 0 s and 1 s that adds w t to x t and possibly keeps in the information set, and G = (1, 0,..., 0 T. If this model comes from a linear approximation to some other model, A, C, and G will be functions of some deep parameters, θ. Then, we will be able to compute moments based on the value of θ (or estimate θ from the moments based on data. 2

3 1.1 Vector Autoregression Definition Assume that E(y t = 0 and that y t is covariance stationary. vector autoregression (VAR is an equation of the form: y t = A j y t j + a t j=1 A where E(a t yt j T = 0 for all j 1. (VAR(N is given by: An vector autoregression of order N y t = N j=1 A (N j y t j + a (N t and imposes only E(a (N t yt j T = 0 for j = 1,..., n. In these equations, a t is the linear least squares forecast error. Note that this is a population equation (these are not estimates. To calculate A j, we minimize trace(e((y t N j=1 A(N j y t j (y t N This yields the first order conditions (also called the normal equations: N 0 = E y t y t j yt k T = C y (j N j=1 j=1 A (N j This is a population version of least squares. Calculation gets cumbersome as N. A (N j C y (k j 1.2 State Space Models and the Kalman Filter j=1 A(N Suppose we have a stochastic linear difference equation with measurement error in y t : x 0 Normal(ˆx 0, Σ 0 x t+1 = Ax t + Cw t+1 y t = Gx t + v t w t iid Normal(0, I v t iid Normal(0, R j y t j T. where v s and w t are independent for all s, t. Note that this model has m + p = dim(w + dim(v shocks in each period, but we observe only p variables in each period. In a VAR for y t, the p shocks in a ( t depend on both v t and w t. 3

4 If we could observe x t, then we would have the likelihood function: L({x t } T t=0 = f(x T x T 1...f(x 1 x 0 f(x 0 l({x t } T t=0 = T ( log f(x (x t Ax t 1 (CC 1 (x t Ax t log det(cc t=1 (where f(x 0 is the density for a normal distribution with mean ˆx 0 and variance Σ 0. However, y t is not Markov. Because we cannot condition on x t, we use our observations of y t (and our knowledge of ˆx 0 to estimate x t by ˆx t. That is, ˆx t = E(x t y t 1,..., y 0, ˆx 0. Then, we have the system: ˆx t+1 = Aˆx t + K t a t y t = Gˆx t + a t where a t = y t E(y t y 0,..., y t 1, ˆx 0 (the innovation in y t and K t = AΣ t G (GΣ t G + R 1. Note that Σ t+1 = AΣ t A + CC AΣ t G (GΣ t G + R 1 GΣ t A where Σ 0 comes from the initial density. This is a Ricatti difference equation. For a properly chosen Σ 0, Σ t and therefore K t will be constant; this is equivalent to seeing the infinite past of y. Then, a t = y t E(y t y t 1,..., y and the a t will equal the VAR errors. That is, we have a recursive representation of the VAR, also called the innovations representation of y t : ˆx t+1 = Aˆx t + Ka t y t = Gˆx t + a t Also, note that K t can be interpreted as the coefficient from the regression of x t+1 on a t. Since the a t are orthogonal to each other by assumption, the coefficients of the regression of x t on a t 1,..., a 0, ˆx 0 would be unchanged by including a t. Thus, the updating method for ˆx t is like adding another regressor. The algorithm for computing ˆx t is called the Kalman filter. This is equivalent to minimizing n t=1 (Y t Ŷt 2 subject to the constraint Y = GX + ɛσ, X = HX 1 + V Ω by choosing G, Σ, Ω, H. Then, we may write the likelihood recursively as: f(y T ˆx T f(y T 1 ˆx T 1...f(y 1 ˆx 1 f(y 0 where the last term will depend on the stationary distribution, and y t ˆx t Normal(Gˆx t, GΣ t G + R. (This is used in dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. More observations will improve the estimates of X, since one can improve the fit each period. 4

5 1.3 Linear-Quadratic Programming with No Discounting Suppose we want to maximize t=0 (x trx t + u tqu t subject to x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t (that is, x t is the state and u t is the control. This is a linear-quadratic model with no discounting. Let v(x 0 = x 0P x 0 be the optimal value function. Then, x P x = max u ( (x Rx + u Qu (x P x where x = Ax + Bu. Solving this, we find that: u = F x F = (Q + B P B 1 B P A P = R + A P A A P B(Q + B P B 1 B P A (If we did not impose that P t = P t+1, then we would have P t = R + A P t+1 A A P t+1 B(Q + B P t+1 B 1 B P A. This can be mapped to a Kalman filter, but time runs in the opposite direction. In fact, the Kalman filter problem is the dual of the dynamic programming problem, so every linear-quadratic Bellman equation maps to a Kalman filter. (There is a more general duality as well, but it does not extend to all problems. A linear-quadratic model with no discounting can also be solved with a Lagrangian: L = (x trx t + u tqu t + 2µ t+1(ax t + Bu t x t+1 t=0 Note that there is one constraint for each period. This leads to the first order conditions (with respect to u t, x t, and µ t for each t 0: 2Qu t + 2B µ t+1 = 0 u t = Rx t + A µ t+1 x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t We can then solve for one period in terms of the previous period: ( ( xt+1 xt L = N µ t+1 µ t We call and then apply the Schur Decomposition. This is another way to solve the Bellman equation, with the help of the correct shadow price. 2 Analyzing Dynamic Systems Suppose one can write Cx t+1 = Bx t, or, equivalently, x t+1 = Ax t. Then, x t = A t x 0 = V Σ t V T x 0, where A = V ΣV T is the eigenvalue decomposition. 5

6 The elements of x 0 must be chosen to match the initial conditions and the terminal conditions (stability in the limit, positivity for all time, or something else. To study a dynamic system: 1. Find the steady state. 2. Study the eigenvalues and eigenvectors. To deal with terminal conditions, one must compute with possible values of x 0 until one works. Shooting Algorithm: Choose c 0. Use c 0 and k 0 to compute the entire path of (c t, k t. If the path does not converge, adjust c Schur Decomposition Suppose we have: ( ( xt+1 xt L = N µ t+1 µ t We call x t the state variables and µ t the co-state variables. ( If L is invertible ( (though xt+1 xt this would all work out if it weren t, we have = M, where µ t+1 ( µ t ( M = L 1 xt+1 N. This leads to the difference equation system = M µ t+1 x0, t+1 µ 0 where x 0 is a given initial condition. Note that if x t ± then x t Rx t and the value function is unboundedly negative. Thus, we must choose µ 0 to ensure that x t does not diverge. (These are called transversality conditions. Proposition 2.1 Since M came from the first order conditions of an undiscounted infinite horizon optimization problem, if λ is an eigenvalue of M, then so is 1 λ. [ 0 Proof (Sketch. M is a symplectic matrix, so MJM In = J when J = I n 0 Then, M = J 1 M 1 J, and M has the same eigenvalues as M 1. Since M and M also have the same eigenvalues, the eigenvalues must come in reciprocal pairs. We may modify R, Q to ensure that no eigenvalues are of modulus exactly 1, so half of the eigenvalues have modulus less than 1 and the other half have modulus greater than 1. ]. 6

7 ( xt Let y t =, so that we are trying to solve y µ t = M t y 0. Applying the t [ ] Schur decomposition, there is some V such that V 1 W11 W MV = 12 = 0 W 22 W, with all the eigenvalue of W 11 less than 1 in modulus and all the eigenvalues of W 22 greater than 1 in modulus. Then, y t+1 = V W V 1 y t, or yt+1 = [ ] W V 1 y t+1 = W V 1 y t = W yt. Then, yt = W t t+1 y 0 = 11 W 12,t+1 0 W22 t+1 y 0, where W 12,t = W11 t 1 W 12 + W 12 W22 t 1. Note that W 11 t 0 and W22 t diverges because of their eigenvalues. Thus, we require that y2,0 = 0 to prevent divergence. [ This] is equivalent to requiring that V 21 x 0 + V 22 µ 0 = 0. Let V V 1 11 V = 12 V 21 V 22. Then, µ 0 = (V 22 1 V 21 x 0. Using a partitioned inverse formula, we find that µ 0 = V 21 V11 1 x 0. This yields an initial condition for µ 0 that ensures the stability of the system and will lead to the optimal solution. Note that for all t 0, µ t = V 21 V11 1 x t. Furthermore, 2µ t is the shadow price of x t, which is equal to V x 0 (x 0 = 2P x 0. Thus, P x 0 = V 21 V11 1 x Linear Approximation Suppose we have a model with forcing variables z t and endogenous variables, k t, related by an equation, H(k t, k t+1, z t, z t+1, z t+2 = 0. Assume that z t = z for all t > T for some T. First, solve for the steady state, using H( k, k, z, z, z = 0. Second, apply a Taylor series approximation about the steady state : H kt (k t k+h kt+1 (k t+1 k+h zt (z t z+h zt+1 (z t+1 z+h zt+2 (z t+2 z = 0 (where subscripts indicate partial derivatives with respect to that variable evaluated at the steady state. This is a second order linear difference equation and can be written as: φ 0 k t+2 + φ 1 k t+1 + φ 2 k t = A 0 + A 1 z t + A 2 z t+1 φ(lk t+2 = A 0 + A 1 z t + A 2 z t+1 We factor φ(l = φ 0 (1 λ 1 L(1 λ 2 L. For most problems, λ 2 < 1 β and λ 1 > 1 β ; for now, we assume that λ 2 < 1 and λ 1 > 1. Then, we may write: (1 λ 2 L 1 = (1 λ 1 L 1 = j=0 λ j 2 Lj ( λ 1 L(1 1 λ 1 L = 1 λ 1 L j=0 λ j L j 1 7

8 Thus, one root has a stable forward inverse and the other has a stable backward inverse. We may rewrite the difference equation as: λ 1 1 φ 2(1 λ 1 1 L 1 (1 λ 2 LLk t+2 = A 0 + A 1 z t + A 2 z t+1 (1 λ 2 Lk t+1 = λ 1 φ 2 (1 λ 1 1 L 1 (A 0 + A 1 z t + A 2 z t+1 k t+1 λ 2 k t = λ 1 φ 2 k t+1 = λ 1 k t λ 2 φ 2 A 0 1 λ A 1 A 0 1 λ 1 1 j=0 λ j + A 1 1 z t+j + A 2 This will be the solution that satisfies the boundary conditions. If there is a one-time change at time T, then the foresight of the change corresponds to the terms in λ1 A 0 +A 1 j=0 λ j 1 z t+j+a 2 j=0 λ j 1 z t+j+1 and φ 2 ( 1 λ 1 1 the returns to the steady state corresponds to movement with k t+1 λ 2 k t = 0. This occurs because the sums change as the upcoming shift(s moves closer and then are constant after the shift(s. If the steady state does not change and if there is no anticipation of a policy change, then there will be no transition at all. Most of the computational methods use approximations. If there is a very large change, then the approximation might fail. Also, in simulation, one might get close to the steady state and then veer off. 2.3 Dynamics with eigenvectors (and pictures For any model, we may compute c(k such that k t = k t+1 when consumption is set at c(k. At any point above the curve, capital will decrease in the next period, since there is too much consumption to keep capital constant. (This is a tendency to move left. At any point below the curve, capital will increase (the point moves right. The steady state capital leads to a vertical line of where capital will eventually be. If capital lies above the steady state, then consumption must decrease in the future (the point moves down. If current capital lies below the steady state, consumption increases in the future (the point moves up. The intersection of the two curves determines the steady state, while the location relative to the curves determines the dynamics of how to get there. Many paths diverge; usually only one leads back to the steady state. With an anticipated change, the transition is always onto the path to a steady state. (First, one jumps from the old steady state to the new trajectory. Then, one moves also the new trajectory to the new steady state. With multiple changes, steady state capital may shift multiple times (there might not be time to get to the steady state, but we can imagine the steady state capital moving anyway. This will affect consumption and capital choices j=0 λ j 1 z t+j + A 2 λ j 1 z t+j+1 j=0 λ j 1 z t+j+1 j=0 8

9 in the next period. After all the changes, consumption and capital will move monotonically back to the steady state. The direction of motion depends on the eigenvectors. Movement along the eigenvector is toward the steady state if the corresponding eigenvalue is less than 1 in modulus and away from the steady state if the corresponding eigenvalue is greater than 1 in modulus. For stability, all non-zero elements in the first period are associated with eigenvalues less than 1 in modulus. This is not always possible. If all eigenvalues are less than 1, then there may be multiple solutions (indeterminacy and any point will lead to some steady state. If all eigenvalues are greater than 1 in modulus, then the equilibrium is unstable, and any movement away from it will lead to divergence. The eigenvalue with the largest modulus will dominate the long run behavior, with x t λ t K v Kc K, where λ K is the largest eigenvalue, v K is the associated eigenvalue, and c K is the initial value. If c K = 0, a smaller eigenvalue will dominate, but that is unstable. 3 The Competitive Equilibrium Model Definition In this model, we define the state as s t S, where S does not depend on time. The history of an economy is s t 0 = s t = {s 0, s 1,..., s t }. Note that s t is a random variable and s t is a stochastic process. We define π t (s t to be the probability density of s t. 3.1 Arrow-Debreu We first consider a pure exchange economy with agents i = 1,..., I. The endowment of an individual at a certain time after a certain history is given by y i t(s t. We assume that the endowment is exogenous. The technology is pure endowment, which means that the good is nonstorable and that the aggregate endowment at time t is I i=1 yi t(s t. Let c i = {c i t(s t } t=0 be the stochastic process of consumption. We define preferences on consumption by U(c i = t=0 s t S t βt u i (c i t(s t πt(s i t. u i (c is the one period utility function, assumed to be increasing, concave, twice continuously differentiable, and with u (0 = (we often assume that u i = u is the same for all individuals. πt(s i t reflects the subjective beliefs of the individual about the stochastic process governing the economy (we usually assume that π t (s t is constant across all individuals and is the true process in the economy. We have Arrow-Debreu trading, where there are complete markets for all state-contingent goods at time 0. In these markets, q 0 t (s t is the historydate price (also called the time zero price of one unit of consumption at date t, if history s t occurs. (This leads to S t prices at time t, one for each history. 9

10 Preferences depend on expected utility. Von Neumann assumed that the true π t was known to everyone. Savage allowed πt i to vary, which gives Bayesian or subjective expected utility. Muth simply equated π t across all individuals, the true process in nature, and the econometrician. This is then exploited to do rational expectations econometrics (and reduces the number of parameters in the models. This might be plausible if agents have all been observing the same economy over a long time, and therefore are all approximately correct because of the law of large numbers. Definition Two probability distributions, π i t(s t and π j t (s t are mutually absolutely continuous if π i t(s t = 0 if and only if π j t (s t = 0. (That is, they consider the same events possible, though the probabilities might differ across possible events. If the subjective probability distributions are not mutually absolutely continuous, then there is some s t S t, and some individuals i, j such that π i t( s t = 0 and π j t ( s t > 0. Then, the price for the goods in that state is q 0 t ( s t > 0, and i will sell not only his endowment y i t( s t but would like to go short and sell more than his endowment; this means that no equilibrium exists (and we might need to impose a restriction like c i t 0 to ensure an equilibrium. This would not be possible if the probability were positive, because u (0 = would ensure that 0 or negative consumption is never chosen for any event with positive probability. Mutually absolute continuity imposes the constraint that beliefs about tail events (which can only be 0 or 1 must be identical. Definition In this economy, the present value of an agent s endowment if given by t=0 t=0 s t q0 t (s t yt(s i t. (Note that because the prices are set and known at time 0, there is no need for discounting or including probabilities. The present value of an agent s consumption is t=0 s t q0 t (s t c i t(s t. Prices are determined endogenously. Definition Financial wealth is the present value of future claims, t=0 s t q0(s t t (c i t(s t yt(s i t. Human wealth is the present value of future (labor income. The agent s problem in this economy is to maximize U(c i = t=0 s t βt u i (c i t(s t πt(s i t subject to the constraint t=0 s t q0 t (s t (c i t(s t yt(s i t 0, given {qt o (s t }. That is, they sell off their endowment and use the profits to choose consumption across states and times. There are no expectations in the budget constraint, only in the utility maximization. Definition A feasible allocation is a vector of c i t(s t 0 that satisfies I i=1 ci t(s t I i=1 yt i (st for all t, s t. Definition A price system is a stochastic process, q 0 t (s t, which is measurable with respect to s t (that is, the price at time t is known if the history, s t, is known. 10

11 Definition As Arrow-Debreu competitive equilibrium is a price system and a feasible allocation such that, given the price system, the allocation is the solution to the household problem for each i = 1,..., I. That is, the households solve their problem at time 0, knowing prices, future endowments, probabilities, and their own preferences. They trade in every market (since u (0 =. We assume there is an auctioneer outside the model that sets prices and ensures that each household satisfies the budget constraint. After time 0, no more trades are made; only deliveries are made. To compute an equilibrium, we first consider the social planner s problem in a command economy. Suppose each individual has a Pareto weight, λ i > 0. The social planner has a welfare function, W = I i=1 λ iu(c i. The Pareto problem is to maximize W subject to I i=1 ci t(s t I i=1 yt i (st for all t, s t. (This has no enforcement or information problems. We use Lagrange multipliers: ( I I I L = λ i U(c i + θ t (s t yt(s i t c t i(s t i=1 t=0 s t S t i=1 i=1 I ( I I = λ i β t u(c i t(s t π t (s t + θ t (s t yt(s i t c t i(s t i=1 t=0 s t S t t=0 s t S t i=1 i=1 Applying the Kuhn-Tucker Theorem, we maximize over the c i and minimize over the θ t (s t. This gives the first order necessary conditions for c i t(s t for all i, t, s t : λ i β t u (c i t(s t π t θ t (s t = 0 The complementary slackness conditions are: ( I θ t (s t (yt(s i t c i t(s t = 0 i=1 Using the first order conditions, and noting that θ t (s t, β t, and π t (s t do not depend on i, we find that u (c 1 t (s t u (c i t(s t = λ i λ 1 for any i = 2,..., I; the equilibrium ratio of marginal utilities depends only on the Pareto weights, which are time and history invariant. Thus, as λ i increases, i will consume more uniformly across all times and states. With strict concavity, u is invertible, and we may solve: c i t(s t = (u 1 ( λ 1 λ i u (c 1 t (s t If the allocation uses all the resources, we may substitute this to find: I yt(s i t = i=1 I i=1 ( (u 1 λ1 u (c 1 t (s t λ i 11

12 Since yt(s i t is known, this is one equation in one variable (c 1 t (s t for each t, s t. Thus, each individual s consumption depends only on the aggregate endowment and the Pareto weights. If there are two histories, s t and s t such that I i=1 yi t( s t = I i=1 yi t(s t, then consumption is the same in the two histories. This implies that there is no history dependence in consumption. We can use these results to compute the multipliers, θ t (s t (the result will be the same for any choice of i. In general, the multipliers will be affected by the choice of Pareto weights. In a competitive equilibrium, the household problem leads to the Lagrangian: ( L = β t u(c i t(s t π t (s t + µ i qt 0 (s t (yt(s i t c i t(s t t=0 s t S t t=0 s t S t Again, we maximize over the c i t(s t and minimize over the µ i. This gives the first order necessary condition for c i t(s t for each t, i, s t : β t u (c i t(s t π t (s t µ i q t (s t = 0 We may match up the first order necessary conditions for the social planner s problem and the household s problem: 1 µ i β t u (c i t(s t π t (s t = q t (s t λ i β t u (c i t(s t π t (s t = θ t (s t In contrast to the planner s problem, the household s endowment implicitly determines 1 µ i, which is their Pareto weight, but depends on unknown prices. This gives a system of simultaneous equations: t 1 µ i β t u (c i t(s t π t (s t = q t (s t s t q 0 t (s t (y i t(s t c i t(s t = 0 which must be solved for q 0 t (s t, c i t(s t, µ i for all i, t, s t. Negishi Algorithm Choose arbitrary positive Pareto weights. (Without loss of generality, we may assume that I i=1 λ i = 1. Compute the allocation using these weights. Solve for θ t (s t and set qt 0 (s t = θ t (s t. Check the budget constraint, t s t q0 t (s t (yt(s i t c i t(s t = 0 for each household. If household i is spending too much, then decrease λ i. If household i is spending too little, increase λ i. 12

13 Repeat with the new weights until all the budget constraints are exactly satisfied. (This becomes computationally intensive for large I, but works for any preferences. Definition Under constant relative risk aversion, u(c = c1 γ 1 γ for γ = 1. Then, u (c = c γ. (and u(c = ln(c Note that these preferences are homothetic (along any ray from the origin, the slope of the indifference curves the ray intersects is constant; this also implies Gorman aggregation and linear Engle curves through the origin. In this case, the marginal rate of substitution (across time and history depends only on ratios. Also, θ t (s t does not depend on λ i. Thus, we may compute the prices based on any λ i and compute allocations given those prices. Definition The state price deflator is given by p t 0(s t = q 0 t (s t /π t (s t. (This is more common than time zero prices in finance. Also in finance, sometimes scaled Arrow-Debreu prices are used; these are p 0 t (s t = q0 t (st β t π t(s t. Then, we have: t=0 s t S t q 0 t (s t y i t(s t = β t E(p 0 t (s t yt(s i t Definition Suppose an asset, z, pays dividends (in terms of the consumption good d t (s t in time t. Suppose that qt 0 (s t is the price of 1 unit of consumption paid at time t and state s t. Then the asset pricing formula for this asset at time 0 is: p 0 (z = qt 0 (s t d t (s t t=0 s t t=0 Definition Let s t+1 = (s t, s t+1. The one-step pricing kernel is Q t (s t+1 s t = q 0 t+1 (st+1 q 0 t (st. Note that, in a Markov environment, q t (s t Q(s t s t 1 Q(s t 1 s t 2...Q(s 1 s 0. Definition Suppose an asset pays dividends d k (s k in time k and state s k, for k = t,..., and s k agrees with a certain history, s t up to time t. This is called a tail asset. The price of this asset at time 0 contingent on history s t occurring is k=t s k s t q0 t+k (sk s t d t+k (s k s t. Note that q0 t+k q 0 t+1 = q t+1 t+k = Q(s t+1 s t. In general, we may price an asset from one period to the next as: S t = d t (s t + s S q t t+1(s t, s s t S t+1 (s t, s where (s t, s is the history at date t + 1 that begins with s t and ends at state s. This strips off the dividends before time t, looks only at the tail asset, and 13

14 uses time t units of consumption instead of time 0 units of consumption (which 1 scales everything by the constant,. (See if any of the derivation on the qt 0(st back of 42 is necessary; this is a more general result. Definition The stochastic discount factor is Λ t (s t+1 s t = Qt(st+1 st π t(s t = β u (c t+1 u (c t. In equilibrium, the agent will try to equate the intertemporal merginal rate of substitution with the interest rate. That is, 1 + r = u (c t βu (c = 1 t+1 SDF. The SDF will change each period, depending on the realization. Suppose we had complete markets at time 0 and then reopen trading at a later date. Then, endowments depend on both their incomes and their future claims (or future payments. That is, (financial wealth at time τ is given by: Ψ τ ( s τ = t=τ s t s τ q τ t (s t (c i t(s t y i t(s t (c i t(s t yt(s i t are the net claims for that history. Prices at time τ are given by: qt τ (s t = q0 t (s t qτ 0 (s τ = βt τ u (c i t(s t u (c i τ (s τ π(st s τ (see if the example on the back of 46 has anything else to add This means that there will be no trading if markets reopen. In equilibrium, households choose their level of demand of c t and their supply of k t+1, n t, while firms demand n t, k t and supply y t. Governments choose g t, and taxes. In equilibrium, by feasibility, everything must be equal. Once we have computed a competitive equilibrium, it can be used as a benchmark for insurance, asset prices, government debt, and so on. 3.2 Arrow Securities With Arrow securities, at time t, one can trade in markets based on the state at time t + 1. In this case, there is trading in each period and fewer markets at each time. This sort of trading will require borrowing constraints. For these economies, we assume that the states are a Markov chain, with initial density π 0 and transition density π(s t s t 1, so that: π t (s t = π(s t s t 1 π(s t 1 s t 2...π(s 1 s 0 π 0 (s 0 We also assume that yt(s i t = y i (s t, for stationarity. We then have the Bellman equation for each household: ( v(s, a = max c,a(s u(c + β s S v(s, a(s π(s s 14

15 subject to the budget constraint, c + s S Q(s, sa(s y i (s + a where a(s are the household assets in state s (also called the Arrow securities and Q(s, s is the price of a claim on consumption tomorrow if today is state s and tomorrow is in state s. Note that a(s may be negative. To prevent borrowing an infinite amount and consuming everything today (a Ponzi scheme, we also require that c 0 and a i (s A i (s for all i, s ; that is, the borrowing condition must hold across all states. Then, solving the household problem for each i will give the policy rule: c = h(s, a(s, a(s = g(s, s, a(s. We choose A i (s and the pricing kernel to match the equilibrium from the Arrow-Debreu economy. (This is good because Arrow-Debreu is associated with the welfare theorems, but Arrow securities are more like reality; if one is efficient and they give identical answers, then the other must be as well. Definition The natural borrowing limit is given by A(s = t=0 s t qt 0yt(s i t. This is the present value of the future endowment, and ensures that we can always have c 0 in future periods. Definition The j-step pricing kernel, Q j (s s is the price of consumption in j periods if today s state is s and the state j periods from now is s. It can be computed recursively as Q 1 (s s = Q(s s and Q j (s t+j s t = s t+1 S Q 1(s t+1 s t Q j 1 (s t+j s t+1. In general, a recursive equilibrium is defined by: a value function, a policy function (which maps to demand, a pricing kernel, q, and borrowing limits and budget constraints. 3.3 Computing a Competitive Equilibrium Generally, it is easier to compute an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium first and then match everything up to a Arrow securities equilibrium and work that out. The welfare theorems must hold in the economy to ensure that the planner s solution and the equilibrium coincide. An equilibrium is an allocation and a price system. In general, they are determined simultaneously. However, if there is a representative agent (this requires constant relative risk aversion with identical utilities and the same beliefs about probabilities, then the prices may be computed first. Under constant relative risk aversion, c i t(s t = φ i I c i t(s t = φ i i=1 15 I yt(s i t i=1

16 and there is complete risk sharing across all times and states. Then, prices are: ( I qt 0 (s t = β t u yt(s i t π t (s t i=1 (because we may scale by a constant and u (c 1 u (c = ( c1 2 c 2 γ. Any agent that does not have a corner solution can be used to compute prices (whether or not there are CRRA preferences, because all the ratios of marginal utilities are constant across consumers. Given these prices, we then solve the household problem to compute c 1 and then compute φ 1 from the budget constraints in the household problem. To move from time 0 trading to sequential trading, we compute the Arrow securities prices as Q(s t+1 s t = q0 t+1 (st+1 st. qt 0(st In any complete market, there exists a representative consumer, with preferences equal to the indirect utility function of the planner over the aggregate endowment (which may depend on the Pareto weights. That is: v(c = max c 1,...,c I : P I I θ i i=1 ci t (st =c(s t i=1 t=0 s t S t β t u i (c i t(s t φ i t(s t where the c i, u i, π i may differ across the consumers, and the θ i are Pareto weights. (With Gorman aggregation, the Pareto weights do not matter, because u, π t are constant across consumers and the Engle curves are straight lines. 4 Fiscal Policy and Growth In this economy, we have: t=0 one (representative individual with preferences given by t=0 βt U(c t, 1 n t where n t is labor (and 1 n t is leisure, technology given by c t +x t +g t F (k t, n t and k t+1 = (1 δk t +x t, where x t is investment, F is a neo-classical production function with constant returns to scale, and δ is the depreciation rate, and a government with an exogenous stream of consumption, g t, and a variety of exogenous taxes. The household budget constraint is: (q t (1+τ ct c t +(1 τ it q t (k t+1 (1 δk t (r t (1 τ kt k t +w t (1 τ nt n t q t τ ht where: t=0 16

17 τ ct is a flat consumption tax, τ it is an investment tax credit, τ kt is a tax on rental income (capital gains, τ nt is a tax on labor income, τ ht is a lump sum ( head tax, q t is the time zero price of consumption (or government consumption or investment at time t, r t is the capital rental price, and w t is the wage. Consumers maximize utility, taking the price system, (q t, r t, w t t=0, and taxes, (τ t t=0, as given. The government budget constraint is: q t g t (τ ct c t q t τ it q t (k t+1 (1 δk t + τ kt k t r t + w t τ nt n t + q t τ ht t=0 t=0 A government policy, (g t, τ t, is budget feasible if it satisfies the budget constraint. Note that the private sector chooses c t, k t, n t. Often, we assume that the head tax adjusts automatically to balance the budget. A competitive equilibrium in this economy consists of a price vector, an allocation, and a policy vector such that the allocation solves the household s problem, taking prices and taxes as given, and the policy vector obeys the government s budget constraint. We may rewrite the household s budget constraint to collect k t terms: q t c t (1 + τ ct t=0 w t (1 τ nt n t q t τ ht t=0 + t=0 (r t (1 τ kt + q t (1 τ it (1 δ q t 1 (1 τ i,t 1 k t t=1 +(r 0 (1 τ i0 + (1 τ i0 q 0 (1 δ lim T (1 τ it q T k T +1 We must have the no-arbitrage condition: r t (1 τ kt + q t (1 τ it (1 δ q t 1 (1 τ i,t 1 = 0 in every period. Otherwise, the consumer would want to amass an infinitely positive or negative amount of capital in that period, so they would have an infinitely high budget overall. We must have lim T (1 τ it q T k T +1 = 0 for the same reason. 17

18 The household first order conditions are: β t U c (c t, n t = µq t (1 + τ ct β t U n (c t, n t µw t (1 τ nt We assume that F is linearly homogenous, so that, by Euler s Homogenous Function Theorem, F (k, n = F k k + F n n, where F k, F n are the partial derivatives. Then, the value of the firm is t=0 (q tf k r t k t + (q t F n w t n t. To ensure that this is bounded, we must have: F k q t r t = 0 F n q t w t = 0 For simplicity, we assume that utility depends only on consumption, U(c, 1 n = u(c, with u > 0, u < 0, u (0 =. Then, labor is supplied inelastically, and n t = 1. This leaves a consumption first order condition: β t u (c t = µq t (1 + τ ct Because of constant returns to scale, we have F (k, 1 = f(k. Then, F k = f (k and F n = f(k f (kk. We can no longer use the welfare theorems to compute a competitive equilibrium since we have tax wedges. Instead, we use the first order conditions and the constraints directly: k t+1 = f(k t + (1 δk t g t c t r t = q t f (k t β t u (c t = µq t (1 τ ct u (c t = βu (c t τ ct 1 + τ c,t+1 ( 1 + τi,t+1 (1 δ τ k,t+1 f (k t τ it 1 + τ it The tax wedges distort the marginal choices; otherwise, we would have the usual Euler equations. We generally assume that {g t, τ t } y=0 are exogenous, and that the head tax, q t τ ht, automatically adjusts to satisfy the government budget constraint. Given a sequence of spending and taxes, this gives us a system of difference equations with the initial condition, k 0, the boundary condition lim T (1 τ it β T u (c T 1+τ ct k T +1 = 0, and forcing functions, g t, τ t that affect the choices of the control variables and therefore prices as well. In an equilibrium, if τ, g are constant, then q, r, w, k, c, n are all constant as well. Let z t = (g t, τ it, τ kt, τ ct, τ nt. Suppose that these variables stabilize, so that z t = z for all t > T. This allows us to compute a steady state, if c t and k t converge as well. Substituting k t = k t+1 = k, we find that: k = f( k + (1 δ k ḡ c 1 = β(1 δ + f ( k 1 τ k 1 τ i 18

19 We may solve the second equation for k, and then solve the first equation for c. If τ i = τ k and we set β = 1 1+ρ, then we find that ρ + δ = f ( k, which is the augmented golden rule of capital, which states that the marginal productivity of capital is the sum of the discount rate the the depreciation rate. If taxes and capital do reach a steady state, then lim T (1 τ it β T u (c T 1+τ ct k T +1 = 0, since β T 0 and everything else is constant. Let R t+1 be the gross real interest rate, which is equal to the reciprocal of the price of consumption tomorrow. Then, in this economy, R t+1 = 1 + τ ct 1 + τ c,t+1 ( 1 τi,t+1 1 τ i,t (1 δ + 1 τ k,t+1 1 τ it f (k t+1 Then we may rewrite the consumption Euler equation as u (c t = βr t+1 u (c t+1. Under CRRA preferences, u (c = c γ, and we notice that: ( ct+1 log = 1 γ log β + 1 γ log R t+1 c t and high consumption growth is associated with high interest rates. These can also be solved by using linear approximations and solving equations in terms of future variables or by using the Schur decomposition. If consumption jumps in one period, then capital will jump in the next period. 4.1 Effects of Policies Suppose the economy is at steady state, and then a policy adjustment is announced. We first compute the effect on the steady state. Then, we may use the shooting algorithm (or one of the other methods to compute the path of the economy as it transitions. In general, between the time a policy is announced and when it is implemented, people act differently because of foresight. After foresight has moved people away from the steady state, the economy moves back to the (possibly new steady state in the transient response. For example, suppose g t increases permanently at time T. From time 0 (when the policy is announced to time T 1, capital will increase, the interest rate will decrease, and consumption will decrease. After time T, capital will decline back to the steady state level (which is unchanged, since g does not affect the steady state, the interest rate will increase back to the old steady state, and consumption will continue declining to a new steady state (in which the additional government consumption has completely crowded it out. If τ ct has a foreseen increase at time T, there will be no change in steady state consumption, capital, or interest rate. However, consumption increases in anticipation of the increase in the consumption tax and then drops sharply when the tax is increased. Note that we can model a one-time increase in τ ct as a one-time pulse in τ kt, since an increase in the consumption tax leads to a one-time pulse in 1+τct 1+τ c,t+1, which will affect the interest rate like a one-time 19

20 pulse in 1 τ k,t+1. The consumption tax is not distorting when it is constant, but when it changes, it acts like a tax on capital, which is distorting. 4.2 Ricardian Equivalence Suppose we have a representative agent with preferences t=0 βt u(c t, with u (c > 0, u (c < 0, u (0 =, so that c t 0 for all t. Assume {y t } is exogenous and known. We impose the budget constraint c t + R 1 b t+1 y t + b t, where b t are the assets at time t. We assume that this is a small, open economy, so that R > 1 is a constant, known, risk-free interest rate for both borrowing and lending, fixed by the world economy. There are two possible borrowing constraints: No borrowing: b t b t+1 = 0 for all t. Natural borrowing constraint: b t+1 b t+1 = j=0 R j y t+j, based on setting all future consumption to 0 in order to pay back the loan. Households choose (c t, b t+1 t=0 to maximize their utility subject to c t + R 1 b t+1 y t + b t and one of the borrowing constraints. Then, the first order conditions are u (c t βru (c t+1 for all t 0, where equality holds when borrowing is not constrained. We assume that βr = 1. Then, if b t+1 > 0, u (c t = u (c t+1 and c t = c t+1. That is, the consumers completely smooth consumption if their borrowing constraints allow. If b t+1 = b t+1, then u (c t > u (c t+1 and c t < c t+1. In this case, income must be higher in the future. That is, any corner solution means that the consumer is expecting income growth and would like to smooth consumption using future income. At the period in which the present value of future income is maximized, the borrowing constraint no longer matters. Suppose there are lump sum taxes, τ t. Then, the consumer s new budget constraint and natural borrowing limit are: c t + R 1 b t+1 y t + b t τ t bt = R j (τ t+j y t+j j=0 The government budget constraint is B t +g t = τ t +R 1 B t+1, where B t is government debt. The only constraint on government debt is that lim T R T B t+t = 0 for all t. We assume that the government can borrow even if households cannot. In equilibrium, the government chooses (g t, τ t, B t+1 t=0 and the representative agent chooses (c t, b t+1 t=0 to satisfy their constraints and so that the household maximizes utility. Proposition 4.1 The Ricardian Proposition. Suppose that households are subject to the natural borrowing limit. Given initial condition, (b 0, B 0, let {c t, b t+1 } t=0, 20

21 {g t, τ t, B t+1 } t=0 be an equilibrium. Consider any other tax policy, ˆτ t, that satisfies t=0 R tˆτ t = t=0 R t τ t. Then, {c t, ˆb t+1 } t=0, {g t, ˆτ t, ˆB t+1 } t=0 is an equilibrium, where ˆb = j=0 R j (c t+j ˆτ t+j y t+j and ˆB t = j=0 R j (ˆτ t+j g t+j. Notice that the change in government borrowing and the change in private borrowing exactly offset each other, so that the private agents are just saving up to pay for future taxes. This proposition no longer holds in this form if agents are not allowed to borrow. In the more general model with all forms of taxes, we may change the timing of the head tax without affecting anything, as long as the present value is unchanged, t=0 qτ ht = t=0 qτ ht. This shows that deficits of a particular kind do not matter, because the head tax does not affect the constraints (because they only depend on the present value of the head tax, the no-arbitrage condition, or the first order conditions. This is a form of Ricardian equivalence. Ricardian equivalence can be shown to hold in a sequential model as well. In that case, R 1 is the price of an Arrow security. Ricardian equivalence applies to certain forms of distorting taxes as well Non-overlapping Generations Model Suppose that instead of a single infinitely lived agent there is a sequence of agents that live one period. Assume each has the utility function, V t = u(c t + βv t+1, so that their total utility depends on their own consumption and on the total utility of their child. This can be written as V t = j=0 βj u(c t+j. Each agent is subject to the budget constraints: c t + R 1 b t+1 y t + b t τ t b t 0 where b t is the bequest to the child. To write this recursively, we assume that z t is a finite-dimensional summary (and perfect predictor of all future taxes and endowments. Then, y t = f(z t, τ t = h(z t, and z t+1 = g(z t. Then, the state is (z t, b t, and we have the Bellman equation: V (z t, b t = max c t,b t+1 u(c t + βv (z t+1, b t+1 with the constraints above. This yields identical results to the previous model with no borrowing. As before, we can only get Ricardian equivalence if a new tax policy keeps all the bequests positive. In this case, this is called the operational bequest motive. 5 Rational Expectations Equilibrium Definition A rational expectations equilibrium or recursive competitive equilibrium is a policy function, h, an actual aggregate law of motion, G A, and a 21

22 perceived law of motion, G, such that h solves the agent s problem given G and h implies that G = G A. That is, when the agents take the perceived law of motion as given and optimize based on it, the perceived law of motion and the actual law of motion are identical. The assumption of rational expectations ties down the agent s forcasting model to be the correct one. To compute a rational expectations equilibrium in the linear case: Guess G 0, G 1 (the perceived law of motion. Compute h 0, h 1, h 2 (the choice of the agents given the perceived law of motion. Set G 0 = h 0, G 1 = h 1 + h 2 (the actual law of motion and repeat. This will not necessarily converge. This sets G j = T (G j 1. We can also use a learning algorithm, in which we observe the history of p t, Y t and estimate G 0, G 1 from a regression on the history, optimizing based on those. This method is more likely to converge. This sets G j = γt (G j 1 +(1 γg j 1, for some γ (0, 1, which is more stable. The rational expectations equilibrium is a fixed point in the perceived law of motion. Some rational expectations equilibria can be transformed into a social planner s problem with the same first order conditions and solution. Note that this differs from the standard Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. There, there is no uncertainty about prices or other endogenous variables. Rational expectations are needed because one must forecast future endogenous variables. 5.1 Example Suppose we consider the partial equilibrium model in which a representative firm maximizes profits, where the price depends on industry output and changing the amount of output is costly. That is, the firm maximizes t=0 βt R t where R t = p t y t 1 2 (y t+1 y t 2 p t = A 0 + A 1 Y t Y t = ny t If the firm is a price taker (which will necessarily happen if n is large, then the firm maximizes profits taking Y t as given. This leads to a value function of: v(y 0, Y 0 = max y 1 (A 0 A 1 Y 0 y 0 d 2 (y 1 y βv(y 1, Y 1 subject to the law of motion Y 1 = H(Y 0 = H 0 + H 1 Y 0, where H 0, H 1 are the perceived law of motion by the firm of industry output. The firm s solution will 22

23 lead to a linear decision rule of the form y t+1 = h 0 +h 1 y t +h 2 Y t, where h 0, h 1, h 2 depend on H, d, β, A 0, A 1. If n = 1, this leads to the actual law of motion which is Y t+1 = h 0 + (h 1 + h 2 Y t. In this case, the first order conditions for the firm are: d(y t+1 y t + β(a 0 A 1 Y t+1 + d(y t+2 y t+1 = 0 Since Y t = y t, this gives a second order difference equation in Y t : d(y t+1 Y t + β(a 0 A 1 Y t+1 + d(y t+2 Y t+1 = 0 with boundary conditions that Y 0 is given and a limiting conditions. Then, this could be solved with the shooting algorithm or the Schur decomposition, which would yield Y t+1 = H 0 + H 1 Y t. We can also use the difference equation: dy t (d(1 + β + βa 1 Y t+1 + βdy t+1 + βa 0 = 0 This difference equation must also come from a well-posed problem, and the solution will give the rational expectations equilibrium. In this case, we can integrate the demand curve to find the consumer surplus plus firm revenue: y The total social surplus is: S t = S(Y t, Y t+1 = 0 (A 0 A 1 sds = A 0 Y 1 2 A 1Y 2 Yt 0 (A 0 A 1 sds 1 2 d(y t+1 Y t 2 This means that the firms decision corresponds to the social planner s problem to maximize t=0 βt S(Y t, Y t+1, given Y 0, perhaps using the Bellman equation V (Y 0 = t=0 βt S(Y t, Y t+1. This will yield the same Euler equation and therefore is an equivalent problem. 6 Applications 6.1 The market for engineers (Sherwin Rosen, 2004 Consider the system of simultaneous equations: ( est s t = a 0 + a 1 P t + e st N t = (1 δn t 1 + s t k N t = d 0 d 1 w t + e dt P t = β j+k (1 δ j k E t (w t+k+j e dt j=0 = E t (β(1 δp t+1 + β k (1 δ k w t+k ( σ 2 Normal(0, s 0 0 σd 2 23

24 where s t is the supply of freshman engineers, k is the time to train an engineer, N t is the stock of engineers, and w t is the wage. In this model, the number of students entering depends on the expected present value of wages and an exogenous shock, the stock of engineers depreciates (as people retire and new graduates enter, and the demand for engineers depends on the wage and an exogenous shock. A rational expectations equilibrium is a stochastic process, {s t, N t, w t, P t } t=0, such that the equations hold simultaneously. In this model, the state is N 1, s 1,..., s k while prices and wages are endogenous but not in the state. Let y t be a vector that includes both the state variables and the other endogenous variables. Then, we may write Ly t+1 = Ny t for some L, N. We may then invert L to find that y t+1 = My t, and we may then find the Schur decomposition. Since such a solution will exist, this set-up must be related to a planning problem of the form t=0 (β(1 δt Φ, where the objective, Φ, depends on integrals of both s t and N t, which are the demand and supply curves. Then, these equations must be the first order conditions of some planning problem. This model helps explain cycles in wages for jobs that require time for training. 6.2 Growth with Taxes Based on Prescott s lecture, In this model: C t + X t = Y t = (Ae γt 1 θ Kt θ Ht 1 θ K t+1 = K t δk t + X t This model sets e γ = 1.02 to match the long-run growth rate of GDP per capita from 1900 to the present and θ = 0.3 to match the capital share of output in the US economy. The stand-in household chooses h t, c t to maximize t=0 βt N t (log c t + α log(1 h t, where α affects the labor supply elasticity. This model allows consumption to grow while hours worked has stayed relatively constant with economic growth. Households have the budget constraint: N t p t ((1 + τ ct c t + x t (1 τ nt w t h t r t k t + τ kt (r t δ T t 0 t=0 Note that all taxes are refunded as a lump sum and there is a depreciation allowance in the capital tax. Also, in this formulation, r t, w t are multiplied by p t, the price level. 24

25 Using these equations, we find that, in per capita terms: y t = Y t N t = (Ae γt 1 θ kt θ h 1 θ t 1 1 θ log y t = log A + γt + θ log y t = log A + γt + θ 1 θ log 1 θ log k t + log h t ( kt y t + log h t This decomposes per capita GDP into a productivity factor, trend growth, a capital factor, and a labor factor. This model yields the Lagrangian: L = N t (β t (log c t +α log(1 h t +µp t ((1 τ nt w t h t +r t k t τ kt (r t δk y +T (1+τ ct c t k t+1 +(1 δk t t=0 Then, the no-arbitrage condition for capital is: r t p t p t τ kt (r t δ (1 δp t p t 1 = 0 In the steady state, p t = β t p 0. Let β = 1 1+i. Then: 1 + i = 1 β = p t 1 p t = r t (1 τ kt + τ kt δ + (1 δ r t = i + δ 1 τ kt The first order conditions for the household are: β t c t = µp t (1 + τ ct αβ t 1 1 h t = µp t (1 τ nt w t Dividing the two yields 1 h t = 1+τct 1 τ ht αct w t. Since the wage is the marginal product of labor, w t = (1 θ yt h t. This yields the equilibrium relationship: 1 θ h = 1 θ + c 1+τc y α( 1 τ h This helps explain the difference in GDP per capita across countries using taxes, but ignores many other factors. 25

26 6.3 Labor Decisions Suppose there are a large number of workers in the economy, with technology y = f(n = γn, so that γ is the real wage. The individual s utility is given by U(c V (n, where U is concave and V is convex. (Rogerson, Hansen. Suppose n {0, 1}, so that the utility is U(γ A if the individual works and U(0 otherwise. An individual will choose to work if U(γ A U(0 > 0; we assume a random utility model so that not all A A U (γ agents make the same decision. If U (0 < γ <, the worker would choose to enter a lottery to determine whether he is employed. This might lead to state-contingent commodity trading so that the worker can equate the marginal utilities of consumption and leisure. Suppose a fraction Φ of the population is chosen to work in the lottery. We require a planning problem to determines Φ. The planner maximizes Φ(u(c 1 A + (1 Φu(c 2 over Φ, c 1, c 2, subject to Φc 1 + (1 Φc 2 = Φγ, c 1, c 2 0, and Φ [0, 1]. We then equate the fraction, Φ, to the ex ante probability. The optimal choice is c 1 = c 2. If A changes, then Φ changes as well. If we include this decision in Prescott s utility function, we end up with an alternative equilibrium condition: where 1 1 η h = (1 + α(c/y 1 θ 1 + τ c 1 1 τ n 1 η 1 comes from the decision of whether to work. 6.4 Monetary Policy (From Kyndland and Prescott Suppose there is a leader in the economy that wants to maximize ( t=0 βt (y try t + u zt tqu t, where y t =, with z x t being the natural state variables, which are t inherited from the past, and x t being the jump variables which depend on both the past and future. (In monetary policy, the jump variables are the private sector s reaction to both policy and the economy as a whole. The leader has a model for the economy: ( ( ( I 0 zt+1 Â11 Â = 12 G 21 G 22 x t+1 Â 21 Â 22 ( zt x t + ˆBu t This includes both a law of motion for the state variables and a relationship for the jump variables (implementability constraints that depend on both the past ( and the future, based on the first order conditions of the private sector. If I 0 is invertible, then we may write y G 21 G t+1 = Ay t + Bu t. The leader s 22 problem is to maximize subject to that law of motion. This differs from a linear-quadratic optimization because x 0 is not given. To solve this problem: 26

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 47 Introduction Authors:

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11. Macroeconomics I University of Tokyo Lecture 12 The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11. Julen Esteban-Pretel National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies The Cass-Koopmans Model: Environment

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco (FEUNL) Macroeconomics Theory II February 2016 1 / 18 Road Map Research question: we want to understand businesses cycles.

More information

The representative agent model

The representative agent model Chapter 3 The representative agent model 3.1 Optimal growth In this course we re looking at three types of model: 1. Descriptive growth model (Solow model): mechanical, shows the implications of a given

More information

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) D(S)GE and Growth Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 43 Macroeconomics is Dynamic

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Slides II - Dynamic Programming Slides II - Dynamic Programming Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides II - Dynamic Programming Spring 2017 1 / 32 Outline 1. Lagrangian

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

1 Overlapping Generations

1 Overlapping Generations 1 Overlapping Generations 1.1 Motivation So far: infinitely-lived consumer. Now, assume that people live finite lives. Purpose of lecture: Analyze a model which is of interest in its own right (and which

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600. Alternative Methods of Discrete Time Intertemporal Optimization We will start by solving a discrete time intertemporal

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018 Lecture 2 (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings Erick Sager February 6, 2018 Econ 606: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Spring 2018 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (2/6/18)

More information

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B Lecture 2 Giulio Fella c Giulio Fella, 2014 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B - Lecture 2 40/197 Aim of consumption theory Consumption theory aims at explaining consumption/saving decisions

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004 Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 5b (Part I), Spring 2004. Consider an exchange economy with two (types of) consumers. Type-A consumers comprise fraction λ of the economy s population and type-b

More information

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016 Christian Groth A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics February 15, 216 (3-hours closed book exam) 1 As formulated in the course description, a score of 12 is

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Chapter 5: The government budget deficit Ben J. Heijdra Department of Economics & Econometrics University of Groningen 1 September 2009 Foundations of

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 5, 2014 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 5, 2014 1 / 56 Growth

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter 6 1 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter

More information

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Yulei Luo Economics, HKU November 13, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ECON0703: ME November 13, 2017 1 / 43 The Nature of Optimal Control In static optimization,

More information

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 13

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 13 Macroeconomics I University of Tokyo Lecture 13 The Neo-Classical Growth Model II: Distortionary Taxes LS Chapter 11. Julen Esteban-Pretel National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies Environment! Time

More information

Lecture 7: Stochastic Dynamic Programing and Markov Processes

Lecture 7: Stochastic Dynamic Programing and Markov Processes Lecture 7: Stochastic Dynamic Programing and Markov Processes Florian Scheuer References: SLP chapters 9, 10, 11; LS chapters 2 and 6 1 Examples 1.1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Stochastic Technology

More information

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Econ 50a second half) Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 7 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.. This problem introduces wealth inequality

More information

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II)

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) ECO 503: Macroeconomic Theory I Benjamin Moll Princeton University Fall 204 /6 Plan of Lecture Sequence of markets CE 2 The growth model and

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now PERMANENT INCOME AND OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION On the previous notes we saw how permanent income hypothesis can solve the Consumption Puzzle. Now we use this hypothesis, together with assumption of rational

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017 Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination August 2015 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 4 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital Princeton University Press, 2017 Motivation In this chaper we introduce production and physical capital accumulation. Doing so will allow us to address two

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1 Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm February 25, 2007 Problem : Pareto Optimality The planner solves the following problem: u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + v(l ) + v(l 2 ) () {c,c 2,l,l

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks 14.452. Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks Olivier Blanchard April 2006 Nr. 1 1. What starting point? Want to start with a model with at least two ingredients: Shocks, so uncertainty.

More information

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and Economics 210B Due: September 16, 2010 Problem 1: Constant returns to saving Consider the following problem. c0,k1,c1,k2,... β t Problem Set 10 1 α c1 α t s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: Practice Questions for Mid-Term I Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: y f(k) = k α ; α (0, 1) (1) where y and k are output per worker and capital per worker respectively.

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Housing with overlapping generations

Housing with overlapping generations Housing with overlapping generations Chiara Forlati, Michael Hatcher, Alessandro Mennuni University of Southampton Preliminary and Incomplete May 16, 2015 Abstract We study the distributional and efficiency

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

Macro I - Practice Problems - Growth Models

Macro I - Practice Problems - Growth Models Macro I - Practice Problems - Growth Models. Consider the infinitely-lived agent version of the growth model with valued leisure. Suppose that the government uses proportional taxes (τ c, τ n, τ k ) on

More information

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2 SGZ Macro Week 3, : Suboptimal Equilibria 1 Basic Points Effects of shocks can be magnified (damped) in suboptimal economies Multiple equilibria (stationary states, dynamic paths) in suboptimal economies

More information

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default, Econometrica 2000 Notes on Alvarez Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000 Jonathan Heathcote November 1st 2005 1 Model Consider a pure exchange economy with I agents one

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set 10. - Solutions Question 1 1. AUTARKY Autarky implies that the agents do not have access to credit or insurance markets. This implies that you cannot trade across

More information

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences) III C Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Literature Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences) Population growth: L(0) = 1, L(t) = e nt (n > 0 is

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination January 2016 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 3 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

Stochastic Problems. 1 Examples. 1.1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Stochastic Technology. 1.2 A Model of Job Search

Stochastic Problems. 1 Examples. 1.1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Stochastic Technology. 1.2 A Model of Job Search Stochastic Problems References: SLP chapters 9, 10, 11; L&S chapters 2 and 6 1 Examples 1.1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Stochastic Technology Production function y = Af k where A is random Let A s t

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu) ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 21 Consider the neoclassical economy without population growth and technological progress. The optimal growth

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Topic 8: Optimal Investment Topic 8: Optimal Investment Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 22, 2013 Luo, Y. SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22 Demand for Investment The importance of investment. First, the combination of

More information

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Consumption and Savings Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Lecture 10 Topics in Macroeconomics November 6, 2007 Lecture 10 1/18 Topics in Macroeconomics Consumption and Savings Outline

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0 Review Questions: Two Sector Models Econ720. Fall 207. Prof. Lutz Hendricks A Planning Problem The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by β t uc Mt,

More information

Endogenous Growth Theory

Endogenous Growth Theory Endogenous Growth Theory Lecture Notes for the winter term 2010/2011 Ingrid Ott Tim Deeken October 21st, 2010 CHAIR IN ECONOMIC POLICY KIT University of the State of Baden-Wuerttemberg and National Laboratory

More information

Growth Theory: Review

Growth Theory: Review Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Endogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 March 2009 Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 1/104 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 Outline Growth Accounting

More information

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Readings Acemoglu, Chapter 9. Motivation Neoclassical growth model relies on the representative household. OLG models allow for

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany October 3, 2018 Contents I 1 Central Planner 2 3 B. Heer c Public Economics: Chapter

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are: Econ 510a second half Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #5 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, December 8 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Solution 1. a In the Mehra-Prescott

More information

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, 2017 9:00 am - 2:00 pm INSTRUCTIONS Please place a completed label (from the label sheet provided) on the

More information

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution Professor Gianluca Violante, TA: Diego Daruich New York University Spring 2014 1 Problem 1 Consider a two-sector version of the neoclassical growth model,

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551 Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551 Tack Yun Indiana University Seoul National University Spring Semester January 2013 T. Yun (SNU) Macroeconomics 1/07/2013 1 / 32 Business Cycle Models for Emerging-Market

More information

Growth Theory: Review

Growth Theory: Review Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1.1, Exogenous Growth Topics in Growth, Part 2 June 11, 2007 Lecture 1.1, Exogenous Growth 1/76 Topics in Growth, Part 2 Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical Framework

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Lecture notes on modern growth theory Lecture notes on modern growth theory Part 2 Mario Tirelli Very preliminary material Not to be circulated without the permission of the author October 25, 2017 Contents 1. Introduction 1 2. Optimal economic

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model ECO 503: Macroeconomic Theory I Benjamin Moll Princeton University Fall 2014 1/17 Competitive Eqm in the Growth Model Recall two issues we are interested

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

TA Sessions in Macroeconomic Theory I. Diogo Baerlocher

TA Sessions in Macroeconomic Theory I. Diogo Baerlocher TA Sessions in Macroeconomic Theory I Diogo Baerlocher Fall 206 TA SESSION Contents. Constrained Optimization 2. Robinson Crusoe 2. Constrained Optimization The general problem of constrained optimization

More information

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61 The Ramsey Model Alessandra Pelloni TEI Lecture October 2015 Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October 2015 1 / 61 Introduction Introduction Introduction Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model: di ers

More information

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside Sharon G. Harrison Barnard College, Columbia University July 9, 2008

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 3005 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 3010 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Autumn 2010 Lecture 5: The neoclassical

More information

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita.

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita. Discrete Math Camp Optimization Problem Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo April 2, 2016 Goal of day 4 Discrete We discuss methods both in discrete and continuous : Discrete : condition

More information

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Economics 522 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University Spring 2014 ERH (Princeton University ) Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Spring 2014 1 / 34 Restuccia and Rogerson

More information