Lothar Grall. March 15, 2011

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Lothar Grall. March 15, 2011"

Transcription

1 Climate Change, Somatic Capital, and the Timing of the Neolithic Transition Lothar Grall March 15, 2011 Abstract This research proposes somatic capital as a hitherto neglected variable in the discussion of factors impacting the timing of the Neolithic transition. The paper develops a model of long-run growth in population and technology that builds on the trade-off between quantity and quality of offspring. It suggests that harsh environmental conditions during the ice age altered the evolutionary optimal allocation of resources towards offspring quality. Higher somatic investment in offspring increased research productivity of individuals and accelerated the rate of technical progress. Thus, the adaptive response triggered within human populations living in cold and harsh climate for thousands of years had a significant impact on the timing of the Neolithic transition. The theory further suggests that differential somatic investment can be identified as deep-rooted determinant of comparative economic development. Keywords: Out-of-Africa hypothesis, Neolithic Revolution, Somatic Capital, Climate Change, Ice Age Conditions, Technological Growth, Population Growth JEL Classification Numbers: J10, O10, O30 Department of Economics, Justus-Liebig-University Giessen, Licher Str. 66, Giessen, Germany. Lothar.Grall@wirtschaft.uni-giessen.de.

2 1 Introduction The Neolithic transition to agriculture was a remarkable episode in human history. The shift to plant cultivation and animal husbandry from hunting and gathering significantly changed the long-run economic outcome of mankind. Agriculture began about 12,000 years ago (12 kya) in the fertile crescent in the Middle East, and not long after that in North China and in Europe. For the first time human societies were capable of supporting a non-food producing class of specialized craftsmen and knowledge creators. Agriculture is therefore a necessary condition for modern civilization itself. Modern research on long-run growth attempts to identify deep-rooted determinants of comparative economic development. The aims are to explain the transition from a period of Malthusian stagnation to one of sustained economic growth and to identify factors that generated the differential pattern of development across the world (Galor 2005, 2011; Galor and Moav 2002; Galor and Weil 2000). The timing of the Neolithic transition is a key event in this respect. Per-capita incomes, life expectancies, and population densities all seem to be correlated with the region-specific timing of the transition (Ashraf and Galor 2010; Galor and Moav 2007; Olsson and Hibbs 2005). Specifically, Diamond (1997) argues that favorable biogeographic conditions expedited the transition from foraging to farming in well endowed areas. Olsson and Hibbs (2005) provide empirical support for the Diamond hypothesis and show that current variations in economic prosperity still embody the effects of the timing of the Neolithic transition. Similarly, Putterman (2008) finds that the year of the transition significantly effects incomes today. Apparently, it is important to identify factors that influenced the timing of the transition. Here I want to add a novel twist to the discussion. According to this research it is not only biogeographic factors (Diamond 1997; Olsson and Hibbs 2005; Putterman 2008) or climatic fluctuations (Ashraf and Michalopoulos 2010; Dow, Reed, and Olewiler 2009) that had an impact on the timing, but also climate induced variation in humans itself. The theory builds on Robson (2010) who develops a model of preferences over the quality and quantity of children. Following Robson, it is a key assumption of this paper that individuals make an evolutionary optimal decision of somatic investment in offspring, maximizing the long-run number of descendants. 1 The term somatic capital or embodied capital is, in a physical sense, organized somatic tissue. In a functional sense, somatic capital includes physical stature and strength, but also factors like immune function, coordination, skill, and knowledge, all of which affect the profitability of human activities like resource acquisition (Kaplan 1996; Kaplan et al. 1 The idea of a trade-off between offspring quantity and offspring quality is not new. Fitness-maximizing trade-offs have long been studied within the context of life history theory in biology (Charnov 1993; Lessels 1997; Roff 1992, 2002; Stearns 1992) and anthropology (Hawkes and Paine 2006; Hill 1993; Lummaa 2007). In economics, Becker was the first to introduce both a qualitative and a quantitative dimension to the demand for children (Becker 1960; Becker and Lewis 1973; Willis 1973) - 1 -

3 1995). Concerning anatomically modern humans it is also reasonable to treat somatic capital as brain size or intelligence. It is therefore a second key assumption of this paper that higher somatic investment increases the innovation capability of individuals, leading to higher per-capita research productivity. In this paper I argue that the migration of early modern humans out of Africa into Western Asia and Eastern Europe between 40 and 45 kya and then into Europe between 40 and 36 kya triggered an evolutionary adaptation to the cold and harsh climate in Eurasia during the ice age. Lower hunter-gatherer productivity in climatically challenging environments was overcompensated by increased somatic investment in offspring, reallocating parental investment from child quantity towards child quality. A higher research productivity of individuals accelerated the rate of technical progress in human populations living in cold areas of the ice age, eventually leading to an earlier Neolithic transition. The theory differs from Robson (2010) in several important respects. First, I add climate as an exogenous variable that influences the optimal allocation between offspringquantity and offspring-quality. Robson s analysis focusses on an exogenous change in the production mode instead. Second, I consider the long time span between the appearance of anatomically modern humans more than 160 kya and the Neolithic Revolution. I do not restrict the analysis on the transition itself, but investigate the run-up to the transition. Third, I introduce technological growth and therefore endogenize the timing of the transition. In this context, I investigate the interaction between climate, optimal somatic investment, population growth, and technological growth. The aim of this research is twofold. First, it adds somatic capital as a hitherto neglected variable to the discussion of factors impacting the timing of the Neolithic transition. According to the theory it is not only biogeographic factors or climatic fluctuations but also climate induced variation in human somatic capital that influenced the timing of transition. This variable is interesting because it potentially fits as an omitted variable causing both an early switch to agriculture and rapid subsequent growth, possibly leading to spurious regressions in the studies of Olsson and Hibbs (2005) and Putterman (2008). Second, differential somatic investment and its link to research productivity is identified as a potentially deep-rooted determinant of comparative economic development. The main argument of this paper is grounded in anthropological, archaeological, and climatological evidence. It is helpful to summarize the respective findings before developing the model. Thus, the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the relevant literature on modern human origins, shortly discusses the climate of the past, and gathers evidence for differential somatic investment. Section 3 formalizes the assumptions about somatic investment and research productivity, and incorporates them into a simple model. Section 4 characterizes the dynamical system and analyzes the economy with respect to the timing of the Neolithic transition. Section 5 concludes

4 2 Modern human origins and evidence on differential somatic investment 2.1 The Out-of-Africa hypothesis and the climate of the past The Out-of-Africa hypothesis for modern human origins is widely accepted today: living humans exhibit remarkably little genetic diversity compared to nearly all other mammals, and the implication is that all living people share a recent common African ancestor (Klein 2009, p. 615). However, mounting evidence points to a lag between the emergence of modern human anatomy and the emergence of modern human behavior. Recent studies suggest modern anatomy evolved at least kya (White et al. 2003). By contrast, early evidence of symboling behavior in the form of personal adornment dates to only 77 kya (d Errico and Vanhaeren 2007). Even more, the total package of modern human behaviors language, art, personal ornamentation, specialized tools, complex social organization, extensive trade networks that indicates a capacity for abstract thought, was not in place until about kya (Nowell 2010). Although it is impossible to show that this capacity did not exist earlier, it was at this time when human populations in Africa gained a significant fitness advantage that finally led to the Out-of-Africa expansion. The spread of African populations to western Asia and eastern Europe is currently dated to between 45 and 40 kya, whereas western Europe was only reached between 40 and 36 kya (Klein 2009, p. 743). However, the timing of the human dispersal is still a fundamental issue and earlier southern routes of expansion are actively debated (e. g. Armitage et al. 2011). Those earlier expansions are of limited interest here, since they appear to have been non-permanent and lack signs of full modern behavior. When anatomically and behaviorally modern humans migrated into Eurasia around 45 kya, they had to cope with challenging climatic conditions. Proxy data such as ocean sediments and ice cores show that the climate of the past 100,000 years (100 kyr) was significantly colder than today. The average temperature in the northern hemisphere at the height of the last ice age was around 12 to 14 C lower than current values, whereas the global average cooling was at least 5 C. This is not true for the tropics, where average temperatures seem to have been much closer to current figures (Burroughs 2005, p. 41). Overall, the Earth cooled significantly at mid-to-high latitudes during the ice age, but surprisingly little everywhere else. The climate record for the northern hemisphere in figure 1 draws a detailed picture of the climatic challenges faced by African migrants in Eurasia after 45 kya. While the initial migration itself probably took place during an interstadial, a period of relative warmth, ice age conditions returned and reached a peak during the Last Glacial Maximum (LGM) between ca. 24 and 21 kya. The ice sheets reached their greatest extent around 21 kya and covered most of North America, all of Scandinavia, the northern half of the British Isles, and the Urals (Burroughs 2005, p. 40). Portions of northern Europe, the central East European Plain, and much of Siberia seem to have been abandoned at this time. People - 3 -

5 #$ -./ $56278.$9:5;$ %$!#$!&%$!&#$!"%$!"#$ %$ &%$ "%$ '%$ (%$ #%$ )%$ *%$ +%$,%$ &%%$ <8.$9=>2;$ Figure 1: Temperature change in the northern hemisphere of the past 100,000 years. The time series uses GISP2 ice core data with average values for every 200 years (World Data Center for Palaeoclimatology, Boulder, Colorado, USA). continued to occupy southwest Europe, although there is evidence on population stress (Hoffecker 2005, p. 192). The end of the last ice age was initiated by a profound warming in 14.5 kya. However, this interstadial was relatively short-lived and around 12.9 kya the climate dropped back into near glacial conditions. The temperature rose to modern values only around 10 kya. This date constitutes the beginning of the Holocene and marks the break from ice age conditions that characterized Eurasia before (Burroughs 2005, p. 47). 2.2 The Neolithic transition to agriculture It is generally accepted that the beginning of the Holocene created climatic conditions that allowed farming in certain parts of the world. In the ensuing millennia, the transition to agriculture independently occurred in several regions of the world. However, the timing of the transition differed significantly between the regions. The rough dates range between 11.5 kya in the Middle East from where it spread to Europe, followed by about 9.5 kya in North China, 8 kya in South China, 5.5 kya in Central Mexico, and 4.5 kya in Sub- Saharan-Africa. Apparently, there is a rough ecogeographic patterning in the timing of the Neolithic transition: societies from over 30 N latitude experienced on average an earlier transition than societies from under 30 N latitude. The literature has identified several important factors that influenced the timing of the Neolithic transition. First of all, favorable biogeographic conditions have been identified as key drivers. In his seminal book, Diamond (1997) tries to explain the dominance of Eurasian societies. He argues that geographic aspects like the major axes of continents and biogeographic aspects like the availability of domesticable plants and species generated favorable conditions for agriculture in Eurasia. Olsson and Hibbs (2005) provide - 4 -

6 empirical support for the Diamond hypothesis and find evidence for a link between biogeographic endowments and subsequent economic development. Beyond that, climatic fluctuations themselves have been identified as an important factor. Ashraf and Michalopoulos (2010) highlight the role of climatic sequences as a determinant of technological sophistication in a hunter-gatherer society. They find evidence for the idea that climatic volatile environments forced foragers to improve their productive endowments faster. Similarly, Dow, Reed, and Olewiler (2009) propose a model in which population and technology respond endogenously to climate. They argue that a negative climate shock that increases local population densities above a critical level is the trigger for the transition to farming. 2.3 Evidence on differential somatic investment Living with the ice age had profound evolutionary consequences for human populations outside Africa. As modern humans spread out across the globe, their physique and physical size changed in response to environmental and climatic challenges. Ruff (1994) demonstrates an ecogeographic patterning in body mass and body height in living humans, with populations from higher latitudes being larger on average than those from lower latitudes. Ruff, Trinkaus, and Holliday (1997) use the breadth of the head of the femur to calculate the body mass of early modern humans. They show that the ecogeographic patterning can be confirmed for them as well: specimens from over 30 N latitude were significantly larger than those from under 30 N latitude. They calculate an average weight of 67 kg for early modern humans dating from the period 35 to 21 kya, while those from the period 21 to 10 kya averaged 63 kg. Thus, body mass of early modern humans declined over the respective period. Ruff, Trinkaus, and Holliday (1997) estimate this decline to be 16% within higher-latitude males between 50 and 10 kya. Comparing early modern humans from the end of the Pleistocene (around 10 kya) to living humans, they show that the body mass of high-latitude males and females was not significantly different from that of high-latitude specimens today, whereas lower-latitude males and females were about 10% larger than living lower-latitude samples. Apparently, an ecogeographic patterning can be demonstrated for both living and prehistoric humans: people from more northerly latitudes are usually taller, broader, and heavier than people living near the equator. These differences in body proportions directly translate to differences in brain size. A number of studies show a robust correlation between body dimensions and brain volume. For example, Witelson, Beresh, and Kigar (2006) calculate body height to account for 1 to 4% of the variation in cerebral volume within each sex. There is also a robust empirical relationship between brain volume and intelligence. In a meta-analysis of 37 samples across 1530 people, McDaniel (2005) calculates a correlation of brain volume and intelligence of Thus, about 10% of the differences in IQ test scores can be attributed to differences in brain size. If these corre

7 lations are valid for early modern humans, people from more northerly latitudes were, on average, not only larger, but had also bigger brains and were slightly smarter than people living near the equator. This can be considered as indirect support for the proposed link between somatic investment and individual research productivity. Note that it is impossible to directly test the link between body size and intelligence for early modern humans, since skeletal remains are quiet about cognitive skills. However, the frequency of certain brain regulating genes in living populations might unexpectedly support this hypothesis. Microcephalin, a gene regulating brain size, is currently discussed in this respect (Evans et al. 2005; Mekel-Bobrov et al. 2007). A key element of the proposed theory is a relationship between geographic latitude (i. e. environmental harshness) and somatic investment on the one hand and somatic investment and technological progress on the other hand. Interestingly, the archaeological record supports this link, as a significant correlation has been found between technological complexity and geographic latitude (Hoffecker 2005, p. 191). Although it seems logical to assume that declining temperatures directly acted as a stimulus to technological change, Hoffecker (2005, p. 190) notes that, first, many early inventions probably were not critical to survival in these latitudes and, second, a series of important innovations took place after climates in northern Eurasia began to warm (i. e. following the coldest phase of the LGM). Thus, archaeological findings support a more indirect link between climate and technological progress, as proposed in this paper. 3 The basic structure of the model Consider an overlapping-generations economy in which activity extends over infinite discrete time. Individuals are identical and live for either one period (childhood) or two periods (childhood and adulthood). Children face a mortality risk that may prevent them from reaching adulthood. In their childhood, individuals consume part of their parental income. Those that survive, reach adulthood, work as hunter-gatherers, and produce a single homogenous good. Adults allocate their income between quantity and quality of offspring, that is, they choose the number of children, n t, and the amount of somatic capital, k t+1, invested in each of these. The model abstracts from adult consumption. Somatic capital is embodied energy investment and reflects factors like body size, strength, immune function, coordination, skill, or knowledge. It can be defined as a stock of attributes embodied in the soma of an organism which can be used for fitness-enhancing activities such as production (Kaplan 1996; Kaplan et al. 1995). Somatic capital is certainly influenced by genetic factors which might change just slowly over time. However, somatic capital can also change rapidly, since it is directly affected by nutrition and parental care during child growth (Robson 2010, p. 285)

8 3.1 Production Consider a population of p t adult hunter-gatherers that support their progeny on a fixed amount X of land or resources. In every period t, the economy produces output Y t with somatic capital k t, land X, and labor p t as inputs. The production function exhibits constant returns to scale in land and labor. Production is influenced by environmental harshness e t. A high degree of environmental harshness, that is cold and harsh climate, reduces production. In the process of development, the hunter-gatherer technology level A t is subject to endogenous growth. Since the amount of resources X is fixed it can be normalized to one (X = 1). Per-capita output of an adult hunter-gatherer can thus be written as (1) y t = f (k t, p t, A t, e t ). The following restrictions are imposed on the per-capita production function: Assumption 1. (i) As a function of k, adult output is zero if somatic capital falls short of a minimum amount k, and is positive with diminishing marginal productivity for k > k. More precisely, for each (p, A, e) > 0, there exists k > 0 such that f (k, p, A, e) = 0, for k [0, k]; f k (k, p, A, e) > 0 and f kk (k, p, A, e) < 0, for all k > k; and f k (k, p, A, e) 0, as k. (ii) An increase in environmental harshness is disadvantageous and reduces output. That means f e (k, p, A, e) < 0, for all k > k, (p, A, e) > 0. (iii) An increase in the population size, p, decreases per-capita output, since there is a fixed amount of land. Thus, f p (k, p, A, e) < 0, for all k > k, (p, A, e) > 0. (iv) An increase in the level of technology, A, is advantageous, in that f A (k, p, A, e) > 0, for all k > k, (p, A, e) > Preferences regarding quantity and quality of offspring It is a general accepted view among cultural anthropologists that culture has liberated humans from most constraints of biological evolution. While this may be true for contemporary humans, it is certainly not for prehistoric hunter-gatherer societies. Especially human fertility should always have been under relatively strong selection, at least until very recent times. The human system of fertility regulation seems well organized to respond adaptively to variable environments (Kaplan 1996, p ). Following Robson (2010), the fundamental trade-off between quantity and quality of offspring and its relationship to environmental variables is formalized in a simple way. Let k t be somatic capital of an adult hunter-gatherer at time t. An individual s level of somatic capital is determined by parental investment during childhood. Hence, the adult - 7 -

9 hunter-gatherer decides on somatic investment per child, k t+1. Since the model abstracts from adult consumption, the number of children is (2) n t = f (k t, p t, A t, e t ) k t+1, where f (k t, p t, A t, e t ) is the adult s income from hunting-gathering activities. Following the insight of Kaplan (1996), it is a key assumption of this paper that the human fertility system is naturally selected to generate preferences regarding quantity and quality of offspring that are evolutionary optimal. Individuals do not make particular numerical choices of quantity and quality. Rather, preferences are assumed to maximize reproductive fitness, which is measured by a dynastic setup in terms of the number of descendants at a distant future. 2 Reproductive fitness, W t, of an adult at time t is given by (3) W t = ω φ(p t+ j )n t+ j, j=0 where n t+ j is the number of children in generation j at time t + j, and φ(p t+ j ) is their probability of survival to adulthood. The entire product is equal to the expected number of living descendants after ω generations have passed, with ω 0. Assumption 2. The probability of survival to adulthood, φ(p) (0, 1), decreases with population size, φ (p) < 0, for all p > 0. This reflects increased prevalence of diseases in a denser population. It is possible to extend the model and to introduce survival probabilities that depend both on population and somatic capital. Somatic capital would then additionally reflect investments in immune function that improve survivability of individuals. 3.3 Optimization Members of generation t choose the number and quality of their children so as to maximize their reproductive fitness. Substituting (2) into (3) and taking the logarithm of both sides, the optimization problem of a member of generation t is (4) k t+1 = arg max k t+1 subject to k t+1 > k. { ω ( ) } ln φ(pt+ j ) + ln f (k t+ j, p t+ j, A t+ j, e t+ j ) ln k t+1+ j j=0 The first order condition of this optimization problem depends on expected values for population, p e t+1, environmental harshness, ee t+1, and technology, Ae t+1. That means, a hy- 2 Reproductive fitness is typically measured in terms of a quantity, r, called intrinsic rate of increase of a population. r depends on factors like age-specific birth rates, age-specific death rates, and the age distribution, which are not representable in an overlapping generations setup (Kaplan 1996, p. 97)

10 f k k t+1 k Figure 2: Optimal somatic investment. pothesis on expectation formation is needed. Since the growth rate of both population and technology was less than 0.01% per generation until 10 kya (Kremer 1993, p. 683) and hence not noticeable for prehistoric hunter-gatherers, static expectations are assumed: Assumption 3. Adults use static expectations to predict next-generation values of population, technology, and environmental harshness: p e t+1 = p t, A e t+1 = A t, and e e t+1 = e t. Following assumption 3, optimization with respect to k t+1 leads to the condition (5) f k (k t+1, p t, A t, e t ) = f (k t+1, p t, A t, e t ) k t+1, as depicted in figure 2. Somatic investment is optimal if the elasticity of the production function is one with respect to somatic capital. Note that (5) also follows from maximizing the term f (k t+1, p t, A t, e t )/k t+1 with respect to k t+1. This leads to the following proposition: Proposition 1. For each (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, there exists a unique amount of somatic capital k t+1 > k, maximizing f (k t+1, p t, A t, e t )/k t+1. An adult that invests k t+1 units of output in each child and bears f (k t, p t, A t, e t )/k t+1 children maximizes reproductive fitness W t. Proof. Follows immediately from assumptions 1 and 3. Condition (5) implies that members of generation t invest in somatic capital of their children according to an implicit functional relationship between k t+1, p t, A t, and e t, (6) K(k t+1, p t, A t, e t ) f k (k t+1, p t, A t, e t ) f (k t+1, p t, A t, e t ) k t+1 = 0. The derivatives of (6) can be positive or negative in general. However, several assumptions appear economically plausible. First, it is reasonable that hunting and gathering under ice age conditions in Eurasia was somatically more demanding than hunting and gathering under milder African conditions. This is the case if travel distances to prey - 9 -

11 animals increased and edible plants were harder to find. Hence, the marginal product of somatic capital increases with environmental harshness, f ke > 0. Second, it appears plausible that food acquisition became somatically less demanding with growing population size, for example by increased cooperation possibilities between hunter-gatherers. Thus, the marginal product of somatic capital decreases with population size, f kp < 0, but less than the average product, f p k < f kp, so that there is a net gain in somatic capital to offset the negative impact of population size on per-capita output. Third, it is reasonable that hunting and gathering became somatically more demanding with growing technological level, for example by increased cognitive demands to handle sophisticated hunting technology. Hence, the marginal product of somatic capital is assumed to increase with technology, f ka > 0, but less so than the average product, f A k This implies a net loss in somatic capital with increasing technological level. > f ka. Assumption 4. Let for all k t > k and (p t, A t, e t ) > 0 the marginal product of somatic capital increase with climate and technology, f ke > 0 and f ka > 0, but decrease with population, f kp < 0. The increase with technology and the decrease with population are smaller than the one of average product of somatic capital: f ka < f A k and f kp > f p k. Further assume f k k + f kk > 0 which simply assures that the factor demand for k is elastic. With assumption 4, the derivatives of (6) are readily given as K k < 0 K p > 0, K A < 0, and K e > 0 for all k t+1 > k and (p t, A t, e t ) > 0. This leads to the following proposition: Proposition 2. Optimal somatic investment is a single-valued function of e t, p t, and A t, (7) k t+1 k(p t, A t, e t ), where k e (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, k p (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, and k A (p t, A t, e t ) < 0. Proof. The proposition follows from (6) and assumption 4. The second derivatives of (7) depend on the third derivatives of the production function. A concave reaction of optimal somatic investment to population size appears plausible economically, since it is increasingly difficult to offset a negative impact on per-capita output by raising somatic investment. There might also be a genetic limit to body size. Assumption 5. For all (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, the function of optimal somatic capital is assumed to be concave in population size, k pp (p t, A t, e t ) < Research productivity and the evolution of technology Although Palaeolithic societies did not support a class of specialized knowledge creators, the term research is used in this paper to indicate improvements of the level of technology, A t. Technological innovations in the late Palaeolithic between 50 and 10 kya have been

12 things like bone awls, bone points, stone lamps, heated shelters, eyed needles, tailored clothing, storage pits, domesticated dogs, fishhooks, bow and arrow, and so on. Klein (2009, p ) provides a brief overview on late Palaeolithic technology. With the emergence of anatomically modern humans between kya technological innovations increasingly occurred, although very infrequently at first. With the total package of modern human behaviors being in place around kya, the rate of technological change significantly accelerated. People became far more inventive and made technological innovations at an unprecedented rate (Klein 2009, p. 672). As discussed in section 2, there is a significant correlation in living humans between body dimensions and brain size on the one hand and brain size and intelligence on the other hand. Larger people have on average bigger brains and are slightly smarter than people with smaller body proportions. To reflect this, it appears reasonable to treat somatic capital as brain size or intelligence which raise an individual s ability to innovate. Hence, it is a second key assumption of this paper that the research productivity of an adult hunter-gatherer increases with somatic capital k t. Assumption 6. Let g(k t ) > 0 be the research productivity of an adult hunter-gatherer with somatic capital k t. It is assumed that g(k t ) increases with k t, g (k t ) > 0. Following Kremer (1993, p. 686), I use a simplified formulation of the growth rate of technology. This formulation assumes that population affects the growth rate of technology linearly. That means a larger population produces proportionally more ideas. Thus, if the per-capita research productivity g(k t ) is independent of population size and if the level of technology affects research output linearly, the evolution of the technology parameter A t over time is given by (8) A t+1 = g(k t )p t A t, where g(k t )p t > 1 for p t 0 and k t > k. The initial level of technology and somatic capital at time 0 is historically given at A 0 and k 0. For a sufficiently large population size the rate of technological progress between time t and t +1 is positive, Â t = g(k t )p t 1 > 0. This research equation captures the fact that it is both quantity p t and quality k t of people that influence technological growth The evolution of population and climate The size of the population of adult hunter-gatherers at time t + 1, p t+1, is given by (9) p t+1 = f (k t, p t, A t, e t ) φ(p t )p t, k(p t, A t, e t ) 3 It is possible to extend the model and to introduce a generalized research equation following the lines of Kremer (1993, p ). However, for the considered period of time, a generalized research equation generates qualitatively similar results (Kremer 1993, p. 692)

13 where p t is the size of the population at time t, k(p t, A t, e t ) is optimal somatic investment per child, n t = f (k t, p t, A t, e t )/k(p t, A t, e t ) is the number of children per adult, and φ(p t ) is the survival probability of progeny. The growth rate of population is then ˆp t = n t φ(p t ) 1. The size of the population at time 0 is historically given at a level p 0. The evolution of environmental harshness, e t, over time is exogenously given. The exact time series is population-specific. It depends on the original climate in Africa before the migration out of Africa, on the timing of the migration itself, on the destination climate in Eurasia if a migration occurred, and on the development of world climate over time. Figure 1 gives an impression of climate change in the northern hemisphere during the considered period of time. Of course, it is impossible to incorporate a complex and exogenously given time series into the theoretical analysis of a dynamical system. This can only be done in a simulation. Hence, the dynamical system is analyzed under the assumption that the level of environmental harshness is fixed at an initially low level, e l. Later, the dispersal of anatomically and behaviorally modern humans out of Africa around 45 kya into Eurasia is modeled by an increase in environmental harshness from a low to a high level, e h, with e h > e l. 3.6 The transition to agriculture This paper promotes the idea that a region-specific rise in somatic investment has significantly accelerated pre-transition growth rates and therefore expedited the transition to agriculture in areas with harsh climatic conditions during the ice age. To show this formally, a certain level of technology, Ā, is assumed to be necessary for the Neolithic transition. A hunter-gatherer society that exhibits higher growth rates will reach this level of technology earlier in time and therefore observes an earlier transition to agriculture. Assumption 7. Let a technology level of Ā > A 0 > 0 be necessary for the Neolithic transition. A society that reaches this level of technology changes the mode of production from foraging to farming. Note that this assumption is very simplistic. It is illusory to expect to identify some precise moment in history when foragers decided to take their first steps as farmers. According to Barker (2006, p. 31), the transition from hunting to farming must be understood in terms of gradually evolving relationships between people, animals, and plants. Nevertheless, this oversimplification is helpful to clearly state the key issue of this paper. 4 The dynamical system The development of the economy is characterized by the evolution of population, technology, somatic capital, and climate. It is determined by a sequence {p t, A t, k t, e t } t=0 that

14 satisfies a three-dimensional nonlinear first-order autonomous system in every period t: (10) k t+1 = k(p t, A t, e t ) p t+1 = f (k t,p t,a t,e t ) k(p t,a t,e t ) φ(p t )p t A t+1 = g(k t )p t A t, where the evolution of climate {e t } t=0 is exogenously given. The dynamical system is analyzed in four steps. First, I assume a fixed level of technology and climate and characterize the evolution of somatic capital and population towards a conditional steady state. Second, the comparative static of the conditional steady state is described. Third, I relax the assumption of fixed technology and study global dynamics for a constant climate. Finally, I explore the effect of an increase in environmental harshness on global dynamics and derive the consequence for the timing of the Neolithic transition. 4.1 The evolution of somatic capital and population Initially, suppose a fixed level of technology, A t, and a constant climate, e. The conditional evolution of population and somatic capital is characterized by a sequence {p t, k t } t=0 that satisfies the following two-dimensional system: (11) k t+1 = k(p t, A t, e) p t+1 = f (k t,p t,a t,e) k(p t,a t,e) φ(p t )p t. This dynamical subsystem is characterized by a globally stable steady state equilibrium ( p, k). To see this, consider the phase diagram depicted in figure 3. The phase diagram contains a Conditional KK locus, which denotes the set of all pairs (p t, k t ) for which, conditional on a given technological level A t and climate e, somatic capital is constant, (12) KK At {(p t, k t ) : k t = k(p t, A t, e) A t }, and a Conditional PP locus, which denotes the set of all paris (p t, k t ) for which, conditional on a given technological level A t and climate e, the population size is constant, (13) PP At {(p t, k t ) : f (k t, p t, A t, e)φ(p t ) = k(p t, A t, e) A t }. Obviously, the locus KK At is a strictly concave and monotonically increasing curve in the (p t, k t ) space. It intersects the k t axis somewhere above k. This follows immediately from proposition 2 and assumption 5. Somatic capital is increasing below the locus KK At and decreasing above. The locus shifts upward as e increases. It shifts downward as A t increases in the process of technological growth

15 k t p t+1 = p t k k t+1 = k t k p pt Figure 3: The conditional dynamical system for fixed technology and climate. Proposition 3. The locus PP At is a single-valued function of p t, A t, and e t, (14) k t p(p t, A t, e t ), where p p (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, p e (p t, A t, e t ) > 0, and p A (p t, A t, e t ) < 0. The locus can be convex or concave in general. However, for all (A t, e t ) > 0 there exists p > 0 such that p p (p t, A t, e t ) > k p (p t, A t, e t ) for all p t > p. It intersects the k t axis at k > 0. Proof. See the appendix. The locus PP At is a strictly upward sloping curve in the (p t, k t ) space. It intersects the k t axis below the locus KK At. Furthermore, it intersects the locus KK At at a point ( p, k), as depicted in figure 3. Population increases above the locus PP At and decreases below. The locus shifts upward as e increases. It shifts downward as A t increases in the process of technological growth. Point ( p, k) is the conditional steady state equilibrium. Proposition 4. Let (A t, e) > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed. There exists a unique steady state equilibrium of the conditional dynamic system (11). The conditional steady state equilibrium values p > 0 and k > k satisfy the equations (15) φ( p) f k ( k, p, A t, e) = 1 and φ( p) f ( k, p, A t, e) = k. Proof. Follows immediately from (5), assumption 5, and propositions 2 and 3. Interestingly, the steady state level of population, p, has the property that it also yields the maximum possible population size. To see this, maximize population p t by choosing somatic capital k t+1 subject to the steady state constraint φ(p t ) f (k t+1, p t, A t, e) = k t

16 Then, reproduction is socially optimal if the surviving marginal product of somatic capital is one, φ(p t ) f k (k t+1, p t, A t, e) = 1, which is just the steady state condition of optimal individual reproduction (15). It follows that the optimal social reproduction rate and the optimal individual reproduction rate are identical. Proposition 5. Let (A t, e) > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed. The unique equilibrium steady state ( p, k) is also the unique solution to max k t+1 {p t : φ(p t ) f (k t+1, p t, A t, e) = k t+1 }. Proof. See the appendix. 4.2 Comparative statics of the conditional steady state This section analyzes the impact of an increase in environmental harshness and technology on the conditional steady state. Initially, suppose a fixed level of technology, A t, and a low level of environmental harshness, e l. As follows from proposition 4, there exists a conditional steady state equilibrium ( p, k) = (p l, k l ). Consider now an exogenous increase in environmental harshness from e l to e h, as experienced by a population of hunter-gatherers migrating out of Africa into Eurasia around 45 kya. The following lemma derives appropriate comparative static results: Lemma 1. Let A T > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed. A rise in environmental harshness, e, increases the conditional steady state level of somatic capital, k, but decreases the one of population, p. It also follows that the conditional steady state values of survivability φ( p) and per-capita output f ( k, p, A t, e) rise, whereas fertility f ( k, p, A t, e)/ k = 1/φ( p) falls. Proof. See the appendix. Hence, the cold and harsh climate in Eurasia triggered an evolutionary adaptation to a new conditional steady state, ( p, k) = (p h, k h ), where somatic capital has increased, k h > k l, but population has decreased, p h < p l. Survivability has increased due to the smaller population size. As fertility is the inverse of survivability in the conditional steady state, it is obvious that fertility has declined. The effect on productivity f ( k, p, A t, e) is unambiguously positive. This is interesting, as the model exhibits much richer behavior than a simple version of a Malthusian model. In particular, there is no biologically predetermined subsistence level here. Rather, the steady state equilibrium level of per-capita income reflects influences of environment and technology. A close look at survivability helps to get an intuition for the comparative static results. It is clear from the perspective of the whole population that fertility falls if survivability increases because a lower fertility is needed to keep population at a constant level. This is, however, not clear from the perspective of an individual because the fertility decline is the consequence of a free decision to substitute offspring-quantity for offspring-quality. A rise in survivability increases both the marginal benefit of quantity and the marginal

17 benefit of quality. Contrary to quantity, however, quality is related to the potential number of grandchildren, which are twice-discounted by survivability and doubly benefit of an increase. Hence, a rise in survivability increases the marginal benefit of quality more than it increases the marginal benefit of quantity. So, adult hunter-gatherers improve reproductive fitness if they substitute offspring-quantity for offspring-quality. Now, suppose a fixed level of environmental harshness, e, and a low level of technology A l. The conditional steady state is (p l, k l ). The following lemma derives comparative static results for an exogenous increase in the level of technology from A l to A h : Lemma 2. Let e > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed. A rise in the technological level, A t, decreases the conditional steady state level of somatic capital, k, but increases the one of population, p. It also follows that the conditional steady state values of survivability φ( p) and percapita output f ( k, p, A t, e) fall, whereas fertility f ( k, p, A t, e)/ k = 1/φ( p) rises. Proof. Analog to the proof of lemma 1. Hence, an exogenous rise in the level of technology from A l to A h leads to a new conditional steady state equilibrium, ( p, k) = (p h, k h ), where somatic capital has decreased, k h < k l, but population has increased, p h > p l. Interestingly, productivity f ( k, p, A t, e) unambiguously falls. These comparative static results simplify the analysis of global dynamics in the next section. 4.3 Global dynamics In this section the assumption of a fixed level of technology is relaxed and the evolution of the technology parameter A t over time according to (8) is fully incorporated into the analysis. The assumption of a constant climate e is maintained for the time being. Hence, the development of the economy is characterized by a sequence {p t, A t, k t } t=0 that satisfies the three-dimensional system (10) in every period t: (16) k t+1 = k(p t, A t, e) p t+1 = f (k t,p t,a t,e) k(p t,a t,e) φ(p t )p t A t+1 = g(k t )p t A t. This dynamical system is dominated by hyperbolic growth in population p t and technology A t for a population size that is significantly greater than zero, p t 0. To see this, note that the growth rate of technology increases with the level of population and that the growth rate of population increases with the level of technology, since f A (k t, p t, A t, e) > 0 and k A (p t, A t, e) < 0. Thus, there is a simple feedback loop between population and technology that leads to increasing growth rates over time. Hyperbolic growth implies that the growth rate is proportional to the level. It is thus faster than exponential growth, where the

18 A t A t+1 = A t p t+1 = p t à p = g(k t ) 1 pt Figure 4: The conditional dynamical system for fixed somatic capital and climate. growth rate is just constant (Korotayev, Malkov, and Khaltourina 2006, p ). This prediction of the model is entirely in line with empirical data about the prehistoric growth of the world population (Kremer 1993, p. 683). 4 The global dynamics of the system is illustrated by a phase diagram, depicted in figure 4, that describes the evolution of technology and population in the plain (p t, A t ). The phase diagram contains a Conditional AA locus, which denotes all pairs (p t, A t ), such that for a given amount of somatic capital k t the level of technology is constant, (17) AA kt {(p t, A t ) : g(k t )p t = 1 k t }, and a Conditional PP locus, which denotes all pairs (p t, A t ), such that for a given amount of somatic capital k t and environmental harshness e the population size is constant, (18) PP kt {(p t, A t ) : f (k t, p t, A t, e)φ(p t ) = k(p t, A t, e) k t }. Proposition 6. For each k t > k there exists a unique p = g(k t ) 1 such that A t AA kt and > 0 if p t > ˆp (19) A t+1 A t = 0 if p t = ˆp < 0 if p t < ˆp. Proof. Follows immediately from the definition of locus AA kt in (17). 4 Interestingly, the model approximately behaves like a set of two difference equations that Korotayev, Malkov, and Khaltourina (2006, p. 24) propose for the simulation of world population growth. See the proof of theorem 1 for details

19 Hence, the AA kt locus, as depicted in figure 4, is a vertical line at a level ˆp = g(k t ) 1. This critical level decreases with the amount of somatic capital, k t. Furthermore, it is independent from environmental harshness, e. Proposition 7. The locus PP kt is a single-valued function of p t, k t, and e t, (20) A t h(p t, k t, e t ), where h p (p t, k t, e t ) > 0, h k (p t, k t, e t ) < 0, and h e (p t, k t, e t ) > 0. The locus can be convex or concave in general. It intersects the A t axis at a value à > 0. Proof. See the appendix. Hence, the PP kt locus is a monotonically increasing curve in the (p t, A t ) space. It intersects the A t axis at a point (0, Ã) and shifts downward as somatic capital increases, but shifts upward with a rise in environmental harshness. As arrows indicate, it is apparent from figure 4 that the economy either enters the upper right area and winds up to a situation of increasing population and technology, or enters the lower left area and collapses to the origin. Which situation occurs, depends on the initial values of k 0, p 0, and A 0. If for a given A 0 > 0 and k 0 > k the initial population size is large enough, p 0 0, the economy approximately follows a hyperbolic growth pattern. What happens to somatic capital if population and technology both grow hyperbolically? The growth rate of somatic capital between time t and t + 1 is given by (21) ˆk t = k(p t, A t, e t ) k t 1. It is clear from lemma 2 that the conditional steady state value of somatic capital decreases whereas the one of population increases with the level of technology. Hence, ongoing technological progress leads to decreasing somatic capital. It follows that the growth rate of somatic capital in (21) is negative. This prediction of the model is well in line with the findings of Ruff, Trinkaus, and Holliday (1997) summarized in subsection 2.3, which estimate a decline in body mass of early modern humans of 16% within higher-latitude males between 50 and 10 kya. The conditional steady state values of somatic capital and population change continually, because the growth rate of technology is strictly positive in every period t. Hence, the steady state values are never reached. 5 Rather, it is clear from figure 3 that somatic capital jumps into the lower left area of the phase diagram with an increase in technology. From there it would monotonically adjust to the new steady state unless another rise in 5 It is possible to change this aspect of the model, if the growth rate of technology is assumed to be positive only every several periods. If the time between episodes of growth declines with population size, the long-run behavior of the model would be the same. In the short-run, however, the conditional steady state of somatic capital and population would indeed be reached (Galor and Weil 2000, p. 816)

20 technology occurred. Hence, ongoing technological progress keeps somatic capital in the lower left area of the phase diagram. It is clear from (21) and proposition 2 that the growth rate of somatic capital increases with the size of population, k p > 0, but decreases with the level of technology, k A < 0. Since both variables grow hyperbolically, the net effect is ambiguous. Since there are no signs of an accelerating decline in body mass of early modern humans, a negative but increasing growth rate of somatic capital seems more plausible. Theorem 1. Suppose k p + k A > 0. Let e > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed, and the initial values k 0, p 0, and A 0 large enough so that the economy enters the upper right area of the phase diagram in figure 4. There, the growth rates of p t and A t are positive and approximately follow a hyperbolic growth path, ˆp t p t and  t A t. The growth rate of k t is negative, ˆk t < 0, but increasing, ˆk t / t > 0. Proof. See the appendix. 4.4 The impact of an increase in environmental harshness on the timing of the Neolithic transition This section analyzes the impact of an increase in environmental harshness on global dynamics. Initially suppose a low level of environmental harshness, e l. The aim is to show that an exogenous increase from e l to e h, as experienced by a population of huntergatherers migrating into Eurasia around 45 kya, temporarily increases the growth rate of technology. In a hyperbolic growth setting this implies under plausible assumptions a permanently higher growth rate of technology and an earlier Neolithic transition. The analysis is divided into two parts. First, I assume a fixed level of technology, A, and analyze the short-run dynamics of an increase in environmental harshness. Second, I relax the assumption of fixed technology and incorporate the short-run dynamics into the analysis of long-run dynamics from theorem 1. Suppose a fixed level of technology, A. The impact of an increase in environmental harshness is derived in the following theorem: Theorem 2. Let (A, e l ) > 0 be arbitrary, but fixed, and (k l, p l ) the initial steady state. If e increases to e h, there exists a new steady state (k h, p h ) with k l < k h and p l > p h. There can be no jump in population, but p t decreases to p t+1 > p h. There is a jump up in somatic capital to k t+1 > k h. After the initial jump, population and somatic capital decrease monotonically to the new steady state equilibrium (k h, p h ). Proof. See the appendix. The phase diagram in figure 3 helps to to get an intuition for the result. It is clear from propositions 2 and 3 that both the Conditional KK locus and the Conditional PP locus

Development Economics Unified Growth Theory: From Stagnation to Growth

Development Economics Unified Growth Theory: From Stagnation to Growth Development Economics Unified Growth Theory: From Stagnation to Growth Andreas Schäfer University of Leipzig Institute of Theoretical Economics WS 10/11 Andreas Schäfer (University of Leipzig) Unified

More information

CHAPTER 10. Premodern Humans

CHAPTER 10. Premodern Humans CHAPTER 10 Premodern Humans Chapter Outline * Premodern Humans of the Middle Pleistocene * Middle Pleistocene evolution and culture * Neandertals: Premodern Humans of the Late Pleistocene -Molecular Connections:

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) One important feature of the world's population with the most significant future implications

More information

GRADE LEVEL EXPECTATIONS CORRELATION NOTATIONS

GRADE LEVEL EXPECTATIONS CORRELATION NOTATIONS Book Title: World Studies: The Eastern Hemisphere 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: Social Studies, Grade 6 Geography The World in Spatial Terms Grade 6 1. Use latitude

More information

Who Were Neanderthals and Did They Interbreed with Modern Humans?

Who Were Neanderthals and Did They Interbreed with Modern Humans? Anthropology 1020 Sharon Vidriales-Estrada Who Were Neanderthals and Did They Interbreed with Modern Humans? References 1. Wikipedia (Internet) www.wikipedia.org Neanderthals search 2. Scientific American

More information

Book Title: World Studies, Medieval Times to Today 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: Social Studies, Grade 6

Book Title: World Studies, Medieval Times to Today 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: Social Studies, Grade 6 Book Title: World Studies, 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: Social Studies, Grade 6 Geography The World in Spatial Terms Grade 6 1. Use latitude and longitude to determine

More information

Reading for Information Grade 2 Correlations to Idaho Content Standards

Reading for Information Grade 2 Correlations to Idaho Content Standards Science Life Science Physical Science Grade 2 Leveled Plants Live and Grow Plants: Alive and Growing Plants: Living and Growing It Takes Force Making Things Move Facts about Force Grade 2 Correlations

More information

Book Title: History of Our World, The Early Ages Edition 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: World History, Grade 6

Book Title: History of Our World, The Early Ages Edition 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: World History, Grade 6 Book Title: History of Our World, The Early Ages Edition 2005 Grade Level: 6 Publisher: Pearson Prentice Hall Subject/Course: World History, Grade 6 Geography The World in Spatial Terms Grade 6 1. Use

More information

Social Studies - Read the article "The Earliest Americans" and complete the Build Your Map Skills page and Extinct Animals of North America page.

Social Studies - Read the article The Earliest Americans and complete the Build Your Map Skills page and Extinct Animals of North America page. Day 2 Social Studies - Read the article "" and complete the Build Your Map Skills page and Extinct Animals of North America page. Language Arts - Draw a self-portrait of yourself in the center of a piece

More information

Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics

Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics How does geography influence the way people live? Why do people trade? Why do people form governments? Lesson 1 - How Does Geography Influence the

More information

Social Studies Curriculum Sixth Grade

Social Studies Curriculum Sixth Grade Social Studies Curriculum Sixth Grade A. History Students will examine the key historic movements, events, and figures that contributed to the development of modern Europe and American nations from early

More information

Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility. By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen

Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility. By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen I. Introduction II. III. IV. Theory Empirical Evidence A More General Utility Function V. Conclusions Introduction

More information

At Penn Museum Conference: Summary of Richerson

At Penn Museum Conference: Summary of Richerson At Penn Museum Conference: Summary of Richerson Steven O. Kimbrough kimbrough@wharton.upenn.edu 215-898-5133 29 September 2007 File: PennMuseum-foils-sok.tex/pdf. Two papers Conference paper: Rethinking

More information

Grade 5: Social Studies Practices

Grade 5: Social Studies Practices Grade 5: Social Studies Practices A. Gathering and Using Evidence 1. Develop questions to help identify evidence about topics related to the historical events occurring in the Western Hemisphere that can

More information

1/24/2008. The Creation of Two Worlds. The Creation of Two Worlds. The Creation of Two Worlds. Topics of Discussion. I. The Earth Calendar

1/24/2008. The Creation of Two Worlds. The Creation of Two Worlds. The Creation of Two Worlds. Topics of Discussion. I. The Earth Calendar Topics of Discussion I. The Earth Calendar II. 225-200 MYA: Pangaea III. Centralization of Evolution IV. 200-180 MYA: Break-up of Pangaea V. Decentralization of Evolution VI. Hominids and Humans VII. Culture

More information

Dublin City Schools Social Studies Graded Course of Study Grade 5 K-12 Social Studies Vision

Dublin City Schools Social Studies Graded Course of Study Grade 5 K-12 Social Studies Vision K-12 Social Studies Vision The Dublin City Schools K-12 Social Studies Education will provide many learning opportunities that will help students to: develop thinking as educated citizens who seek to understand

More information

Prentice Hall Conceptual Physics (Hewitt) 2006 Correlated to: Nebraska Science Standards and STAR Science Standards (Grades 9-12)

Prentice Hall Conceptual Physics (Hewitt) 2006 Correlated to: Nebraska Science Standards and STAR Science Standards (Grades 9-12) Predict and evaluate how change within a system affects that system. 12.1 UNIFYING CONCEPTS AND PROCESSES 12.1.1 By the end of twelfth grade, students will develop an understanding of systems, order, and

More information

Norwich City Schools Social Studies 6

Norwich City Schools Social Studies 6 Social Studies 6 Topic: Maps and Globes and Graphs and Time Transferable Concepts: change 3: Geography Geography Geographers use maps, globes, and graphs to study the Earth and everything on it. Types

More information

Louisiana Academic Standards Science Grade: 4 - Adopted: 2017

Louisiana Academic Standards Science Grade: 4 - Adopted: 2017 Main Criteria: Louisiana Academic Standards Secondary Criteria: Subjects: Science, Social Studies Grade: 4 Correlation Options: Show Correlated Louisiana Academic Standards Science Grade: 4 - Adopted:

More information

Three Lectures on Economic Growth. and International Trade. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Wuhan University. June 16-17, 2004

Three Lectures on Economic Growth. and International Trade. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Wuhan University. June 16-17, 2004 Three Lectures on Economic Growth and International Trade Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Wuhan University June 16-17, 2004 Plan of Lectures: Ricardian Theory of a Pre-Industrial Economy Fertility and Sustained Growth

More information

Name: Date: Period: #: Chapter 1: Outline Notes What Does a Historian Do?

Name: Date: Period: #: Chapter 1: Outline Notes What Does a Historian Do? Name: Date: Period: #: Chapter 1: Outline Notes What Does a Historian Do? Lesson 1.1 What is History? I. Why Study History? A. History is the study of the of the past. History considers both the way things

More information

Nevada Academic Content Standards Science Grade: 6 - Adopted: 2014

Nevada Academic Content Standards Science Grade: 6 - Adopted: 2014 Main Criteria: Nevada Academic Content Standards Secondary Criteria: Subjects: Science, Social Studies Grade: 6 Correlation Options: Show Correlated Nevada Academic Content Standards Science Grade: 6 -

More information

Word Cards. 2 map. 1 geographic representation. a description or portrayal of the Earth or parts of the Earth. a visual representation of an area

Word Cards. 2 map. 1 geographic representation. a description or portrayal of the Earth or parts of the Earth. a visual representation of an area Name: Date: Hour: Word Cards 1 geographic representation a description or portrayal of the Earth or parts of the Earth Example: A map is a representation of an actual location or place. 2 map a visual

More information

Growth: Facts and Theories

Growth: Facts and Theories Notes on Growth: Facts and Theories Intermediate Macroeconomics Spring 2006 Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania Growth In the last part of the course we are going to study economic growth, i.e. the

More information

Your web browser (Safari 7) is out of date. For more security, comfort and the best experience on this site: Update your browser Ignore

Your web browser (Safari 7) is out of date. For more security, comfort and the best experience on this site: Update your browser Ignore Your web browser (Safari 7) is out of date. For more security, comfort and the best experience on this site: Update your browser Ignore DOGGERL AND - THE EU RO PE THAT WAS The British Isles were once neither

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

RubensteinCh. 2. Population

RubensteinCh. 2. Population RubensteinCh. 2 Population Icebreaker Imagining Billions Q1: The equator stretches approx. 25,000 miles around Earth. If each of the world s 6.8 billion people was allotted 1 yard of space. How many times

More information

AP Human Geography Free-response Questions

AP Human Geography Free-response Questions AP Human Geography Free-response Questions 2000-2010 2000-preliminary test 1. A student concludes from maps of world languages and religions that Western Europe has greater cultural diversity than the

More information

Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch

Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch Quamrul Ashraf Williams College Oded Galor Brown University First Version: October 2008 This Version: January 2010 Abstract This paper conducts the first

More information

Grade 7 Social Studies

Grade 7 Social Studies Standard 1: History Students will examine the major movements, events, and figures that contributed to the development of nations in modern Africa, Asia, and the Southwest Pacific from acient civilizations

More information

Exam 1. Econ520. Fall 2013

Exam 1. Econ520. Fall 2013 Exam 1. Econ520. Fall 2013 Professor Lutz Hendricks UNC Instructions: Answer all questions. Clearly number your answers. Write legibly. Do not write your answers on the question sheets. Explain your answers

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Central Valley School District Social Studies Curriculum Map Grade 7. August - September

Central Valley School District Social Studies Curriculum Map Grade 7. August - September August - September Geographical/Historical Skills Identify and analyze timelines. Construct and use cause and effect charts. Differentiate between fact and opinion. Use of word webs, flip charts, outlines

More information

LOUISIANA STUDENT STANDARDS FOR SOCIAL STUDIES THAT CORRELATE WITH A FIELD TRIP TO DESTREHAN PLANTATION KINDERGARTEN

LOUISIANA STUDENT STANDARDS FOR SOCIAL STUDIES THAT CORRELATE WITH A FIELD TRIP TO DESTREHAN PLANTATION KINDERGARTEN LOUISIANA STUDENT STANDARDS FOR SOCIAL STUDIES THAT CORRELATE WITH A FIELD TRIP TO DESTREHAN PLANTATION KINDERGARTEN Standard 2 Historical Thinking Skills Students distinguish between events, people, and

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

GRADE 5 SOCIAL STUDIES SOCIAL STUDIES APPLICATION. SOCIAL STUDIES STANDARDS for Grade 5

GRADE 5 SOCIAL STUDIES SOCIAL STUDIES APPLICATION. SOCIAL STUDIES STANDARDS for Grade 5 GRADE 5 SOCIAL STUDIES The Archdiocese of Cincinnati has established the following Social Studies standards based on the most current teachings which are aligned to Ohio New Learning Social Studies Standards.

More information

The Creation of Two Worlds

The Creation of Two Worlds Topics of Discussion I. The Earth Calendar II. 225-200 MYA: Pangaea III. Centralization of Evolution IV. 200-180 MYA: Break-up of Pangaea V. Decentralization of Evolution VI. Hominids and Humans VII. Culture

More information

Ecology Regulation, Fluctuations and Metapopulations

Ecology Regulation, Fluctuations and Metapopulations Ecology Regulation, Fluctuations and Metapopulations The Influence of Density on Population Growth and Consideration of Geographic Structure in Populations Predictions of Logistic Growth The reality of

More information

Range of Opportunities

Range of Opportunities Geograhy Curriculum Cropwell Bishop Primary School Range of Opportunities Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year 6 All Key Stage 1 Key Stage 2 Investigate the countries and capitals of the United Kingdom.

More information

Chapter 4 Population and Economic Growth

Chapter 4 Population and Economic Growth Economic Growth 3rd Edition Weil Solutions Manual Completed download solutions manual Economic Growth 3rd Edition by David Weil: https://solutionsmanualbank.com/download/solution-manual-for-economic-growth-

More information

Casey Leonard. Multiregional model vs. Out of Africa theory SLCC

Casey Leonard. Multiregional model vs. Out of Africa theory SLCC Casey Leonard Multiregional model vs. Out of Africa theory SLCC 2 It is debated where humans came from and how they spread across the world. Since people don't all look the same, or are categorized into

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market Daron Acemoglu MIT September 20, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Technology and the Labor Market September 20, 2016. 1 / 51 Technology

More information

From Difference to Differential Equations I

From Difference to Differential Equations I From Difference to Differential Equations I Start with a simple difference equation x (t + 1) x (t) = g(x (t)). (30) Now consider the following approximation for any t [0, 1], x (t + t) x (t) t g(x (t)),

More information

Major questions of evolutionary genetics. Experimental tools of evolutionary genetics. Theoretical population genetics.

Major questions of evolutionary genetics. Experimental tools of evolutionary genetics. Theoretical population genetics. Evolutionary Genetics (for Encyclopedia of Biodiversity) Sergey Gavrilets Departments of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology and Mathematics, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-6 USA Evolutionary

More information

11/10/13. How do populations and communities interact and change? Populations. What do you think? Do you agree or disagree? Do you agree or disagree?

11/10/13. How do populations and communities interact and change? Populations. What do you think? Do you agree or disagree? Do you agree or disagree? Chapter Introduction Lesson 1 Populations Lesson 2 Changing Populations Lesson 3 Communities Chapter Wrap-Up How do populations and communities interact and change? What do you think? Before you begin,

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

Global South / Global North: Africa, Asia & Latin America versus US Midwest: Retracing 1500 to the present as Environmental History

Global South / Global North: Africa, Asia & Latin America versus US Midwest: Retracing 1500 to the present as Environmental History Global South / Global North: Africa, Asia & Latin America versus US Midwest: Retracing 1500 to the present as Environmental History The habitual weakness of the American people is to assume that they have

More information

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital Princeton University Press, 2017 Motivation In this chaper we introduce production and physical capital accumulation. Doing so will allow us to address two

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Stillwater Area Schools Curriculum Guide for Elementary Social Studies

Stillwater Area Schools Curriculum Guide for Elementary Social Studies Stillwater Area Schools Curriculum Guide for Elementary Social Studies Grade Four Draft March 21, 2006 Minnesota and the St. Croix Valley I. Historical Skills A. The student will acquire skills of chronological

More information

Peoples, Places and Cultures in Africa, Asia and the Southwest Pacific

Peoples, Places and Cultures in Africa, Asia and the Southwest Pacific GRADE 7 Peoples, Places and Cultures in Africa, Asia and the Southwest Pacific Course 0470-07 Students in seventh grade explore the history, geography, government, economic systems, current issues, and

More information

Greenland: Balancing the need for development and environmental protection. Arctic Frontiers 2016 Industry and Environment

Greenland: Balancing the need for development and environmental protection. Arctic Frontiers 2016 Industry and Environment Greenland: Balancing the need for development and environmental protection Arctic Frontiers 2016 Industry and Environment Speech by Minister for Finance, Mineral Resources and Foreign Affairs Mr. Vittus

More information

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting The second section of Chapter 11 of Dornbusch (1980) draws on Dornbusch (1976) Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political

More information

Social Studies Continuum

Social Studies Continuum Historical Skills chronological thinking understand that we can learn about the past from different sorts of evidence begin to use historical resources apply research skills by investigating a topic in

More information

Activity 6 Ride the Arctic Climate Rollercoaster

Activity 6 Ride the Arctic Climate Rollercoaster Activity 6 Ride the Arctic Climate Rollercoaster Forces of Change >> Arctic >> Activity 6 >> Page 1 ACTIVITY 6 RIDE THE ARCTIC CLIMATE ROLLERCOASTER CLIMATE CHANGE IN THE ARCTIC SINCE THE ICE AGE Graphic

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

A Correlation of. Eastern Hemisphere. Ohio s Learning Standards Social Studies: K-12 Grade 6

A Correlation of. Eastern Hemisphere. Ohio s Learning Standards Social Studies: K-12 Grade 6 A Correlation of Eastern Hemisphere To Grade 6 to,, Grade 6 Introduction This document demonstrates how, Eastern Hemisphere, Ohio Edition, meets : K-12 Social Studies for Grade 6. Correlation page references

More information

Perspectives on the Medieval Warm Period and the Little Ice Age. By Matt King

Perspectives on the Medieval Warm Period and the Little Ice Age. By Matt King Perspectives on the Medieval Warm Period and the Little Ice Age By Matt King Sources of Evidence Many different types of evidence Ice cores Human temperature documentation Food prices Tree rings Primary

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Great Native American Nations

Great Native American Nations Great Native American Nations Episode 1 Episode 2 Episode 3 Episode 4 Episode 5 Episode 6 Cheyenne: Indians of the Plains Iroquois: Indians of the Northeast Lakota Sioux: Indians of the Plains Navajo:

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

3/30/2012. Two Contrasting but Complementary Evolutionary Perspectives on Human Behavior:

3/30/2012. Two Contrasting but Complementary Evolutionary Perspectives on Human Behavior: Two Contrasting but Complementary Perspectives on Human Behavior: Psychology (EP) derived from a synthesis of biology and psychology Human Behavioral Ecology (HEB) derived from a synthesis of biology and

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

Orbital-Scale Interactions in the Climate System. Speaker:

Orbital-Scale Interactions in the Climate System. Speaker: Orbital-Scale Interactions in the Climate System Speaker: Introduction First, many orbital-scale response are examined.then return to the problem of interactions between atmospheric CO 2 and the ice sheets

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

Reading for Information Grade 2 Correlations to Oregon Content Standards

Reading for Information Grade 2 Correlations to Oregon Content Standards Life Science Earth Science Physical Science Health Grade 2 Leveled Plants Live and Grow Plants: Alive and Growing Plants: Living and Growing All about Soil What Is Soil? Facts about Soil It Takes Force

More information

Simple Solutions Social Studies Level 2. Level 2. Social Studies. Help Pages

Simple Solutions Social Studies Level 2. Level 2. Social Studies. Help Pages Level 2 Social Studies 147 148 adobe houses with bricks made of clay and straw ancestor a family member who lived before us appoint choose; leaders can appoint others barter trading one thing for another

More information

Analysis of the 500 mb height fields and waves: testing Rossby wave theory

Analysis of the 500 mb height fields and waves: testing Rossby wave theory Analysis of the 500 mb height fields and waves: testing Rossby wave theory Jeffrey D. Duda, Suzanne Morris, Michelle Werness, and Benjamin H. McNeill Department of Geologic and Atmospheric Sciences, Iowa

More information

Global Perspectives Goals & Objectives: (include numbers) Learning Essentials Materials/ Resources

Global Perspectives Goals & Objectives: (include numbers) Learning Essentials Materials/ Resources August/ September Early Civilizations Goal 1.6: Explain the rise of human civilization. 6-9.WHC.1.6.1 Describe types of evidence used by anthropologists, archaeologists, and other scholars to reconstruct

More information

Levels of Ecological Organization. Biotic and Abiotic Factors. Studying Ecology. Chapter 4 Population Ecology

Levels of Ecological Organization. Biotic and Abiotic Factors. Studying Ecology. Chapter 4 Population Ecology Chapter 4 Population Ecology Lesson 4.1 Studying Ecology Levels of Ecological Organization Biotic and Abiotic Factors The study of how organisms interact with each other and with their environments Scientists

More information

Chapter 4 Population Ecology

Chapter 4 Population Ecology Chapter 4 Population Ecology Lesson 4.1 Studying Ecology Levels of Ecological Organization The study of how organisms interact with each other and with their environments Scientists study ecology at various

More information

The Early State: Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Royal Holloway University of London

The Early State: Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Royal Holloway University of London The Early State: Malthusian Dynamics and Asymmetric Information Joram Mayshar Hebrew University of Jerusalem Omer Moav Hebrew University of Jerusalem Royal Holloway University of London Zvika Neeman Tel-Aviv

More information

MS-LS4-1 Biological Evolution: Unity and Diversity

MS-LS4-1 Biological Evolution: Unity and Diversity MS-LS4-1 Biological Evolution: Unity and Diversity MS-LS4-1. Analyze and interpret data for patterns in the fossil record that document the existence, diversity, extinction, and change of life forms throughout

More information

DEEP ORIGINS OF COMPARATIVE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

DEEP ORIGINS OF COMPARATIVE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT DEEP ORIGINS OF COMPARATIVE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Instructor: Dr. Dmitry Veselov (dveselov@hse.ru) From plus.google.com COURSE DESCRIPTION Abstract This course summarizes recent theoretical and empirical

More information

5 th Grade Social Studies Goals for the First Trimester Miss Gaull

5 th Grade Social Studies Goals for the First Trimester Miss Gaull 5 th Grade Social Studies Goals for the First Trimester Overview: American People, American Land The American People Government by the People Free Enterprise Lands and Regions Resources and the Environment

More information

The Human Animal. Molecular Evidence. Early Homo Evolution

The Human Animal. Molecular Evidence. Early Homo Evolution The Human Animal 1 Molecular Evidence Humans and Chimps/ Bonobos share 95% of our DNA in common The 5% is responsible for the important difference in body, brains and behaviours Gorilla Chimp. Bonobos

More information

The Human Animal. BIO 1300: The Human Animal

The Human Animal. BIO 1300: The Human Animal The Human Animal 1 Molecular Evidence Humans and Chimps/ Bonobos share 95% of our DNA in common The 5% is responsible for the important difference in body, brains and behaviours Gorilla Chimp. Bonobos

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Of topic specific knowledge and understanding To encourage progressive development in 'thinking geographically'

Of topic specific knowledge and understanding To encourage progressive development in 'thinking geographically' [August 2012] Content exemplars 1. Broad description of the content: Single paragraph, written with technical precision Content rigour (avoiding generic statements) Identifying the core of essential knowledge

More information

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 5. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division REGIONS AND PEOPLE OF THE WESTERN HEMISPHERE

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 5. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division REGIONS AND PEOPLE OF THE WESTERN HEMISPHERE SOCIAL STUDIES REGIONS AND PEOPLE OF THE WESTERN HEMISPHERE GRADE 5 I Can Checklist 2015-2016 Aligned with Ohio s Learning Standards for Social Studies Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

More information

Understanding the Predynastic. the beginnings of ancient Egyptian civilization

Understanding the Predynastic. the beginnings of ancient Egyptian civilization Understanding the Predynastic the beginnings of ancient Egyptian civilization The development of agriculture may have been promoted by climate changes that began around 7000 BC. Settled agricultural communities

More information

YEAR 12 HUMAN BIOLOGY EVOLUTION / NATURAL SELECTION TEST TOTAL MARKS :

YEAR 12 HUMAN BIOLOGY EVOLUTION / NATURAL SELECTION TEST TOTAL MARKS : YEAR 12 HUMAN BIOLOGY EVOLUTION / NATURAL SELECTION TEST TOTAL MARKS : 1.Natural selection is occurring in a population. Which of the following statements is CORRECT? The population must be completely

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t ) Notes on Kongsamut et al. (2001) The goal of this model is to be consistent with the Kaldor facts (constancy of growth rates, capital shares, capital-output ratios) and the Kuznets facts (employment in

More information

All living things share the characteristics of life.

All living things share the characteristics of life. Section 1: All living things share the characteristics of life. K What I Know W What I Want to Find Out L What I Learned Essential Questions What is biology? What are possible benefits of studying biology?

More information

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding Klaus Desmet SMU Dávid Krisztián Nagy Princeton University Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University World Bank, February

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

The Evolution of Population, Technology and Output

The Evolution of Population, Technology and Output MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Evolution of Population, Technology and Output Ragchaasuren Galindev 17. July 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/21803/ MPRA Paper No. 21803, posted 7.

More information

Warm ups *Name and briefly describe one of Africa s geographic regions.

Warm ups *Name and briefly describe one of Africa s geographic regions. Warm ups 2.28.2017 *Name and briefly describe one of Africa s geographic regions. Lesson Objective: *describe general time periods that the study of African history can be divided into *describe methods

More information

CHAPTER 2: KEY ISSUE 1 Where Is the World s Population Distributed? p

CHAPTER 2: KEY ISSUE 1 Where Is the World s Population Distributed? p CHAPTER 2: KEY ISSUE 1 Where Is the World s Population Distributed? p. 45-49 Always keep your vocabulary packet out whenever you take notes. As the term comes up in the text, add to your examples for the

More information

The Four World Zones Become Connected

The Four World Zones Become Connected The Four World Zones Become Connected By Cynthia Stokes Brown, Big History Project, adapted by Newsela staff on 07.30.16 Word Count 812 TOP: Asia from space. Photo: Corbis. MIDDLE: Bering Land Bridge National

More information

Chapter 16: Evolutionary Theory

Chapter 16: Evolutionary Theory Chapter 16: Evolutionary Theory Section 1: Developing a Theory Evolution: Artificial Selection: Evolution: I. A Theory to Explain Change Over Time B. Charles Darwin C. Theory: D. Modern evolutionary theory

More information

Economic Development: Theory and Policy

Economic Development: Theory and Policy Economic Development: Theory and Policy Andreas Schäfer University of Leipzig Institute of Theoretical Economics WS 12/13 Andreas Schäfer (University of Leipzig) Unified Growth Theory WS 11/12 1 / 62 Contents

More information

Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model

Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model University of Heidelberg Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 453 Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model Andreas Irmen and Rainer Klump

More information

The Ancient World. Chapter 1 The Beginnings of Human Society. What historical accomplishments is each civilization known for?

The Ancient World. Chapter 1 The Beginnings of Human Society. What historical accomplishments is each civilization known for? Chapter 1 The Beginnings of Human Society Chapter 1-Guiding Questions: What historical accomplishments is each civilization known for? How did physical geography affect the growth of ancient civilizations

More information

Causes of Extinctions?

Causes of Extinctions? Causes of Extinctions? Around 12,800 years ago, tens of millions of large animals abruptly became extinct, including mammoths, mastodons, saber-toothed tigers, giant armadillos, giant beavers, American

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201 L2: Economic growth II Anna Seim Department of Economics, Stockholm University Spring 2017 1 / 64 Contents and literature The Solow model. Human capital. The Romer model.

More information

A Correlation of. Ohio s Learning Standards in Social Studies. Grade 5

A Correlation of. Ohio s Learning Standards in Social Studies. Grade 5 A Correlation of 2019 To in Social Studies Grade 5 Introduction The all new myworld Interactive Social Studies encourages students to explore their world, expand their thinking, and engage their college,

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information