Sufficient Statistics for Top End Wealth Inequality

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Sufficient Statistics for Top End Wealth Inequality"

Transcription

1 Sufficient Statistics for Top End Wealth Inequality Dan Cao Georgetown University Wenlan Luo Georgetown University July 2016 Abstract Are there simple and observable aggregate statistics that might help determine and forecast the degree of wealth inequality? Do they explain the differences in wealth inequality across economies and over time? To answer these questions, we build a general equilibrium, neoclassical growth model, in which the stationary wealth distribution has heavy right tail with the Pareto tail index, θ. In the simplest cases of the model, the tail index depends on interest rate r, growth rate g, aggregate labor income share EY, and aggregate capital to output ratio, KY, summarized in a formula θ = ˆθ r, g, EY, KY rather than the simple gap r g, put forth in Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21st century. In addition, financial development, production technology, corporate and wealth taxes affect the tail index through their effects on these sufficient statistics. When we calibrate the model to the U.S. economy, we find that the model requires significant persistent heterogeneous returns to investment in order to generate the tail index of U.S. wealth distribution. In this calibration, earnings inequality and, to a lesser extent, initial wealth distribution have negligible effects on top end wealth inequality. The transition of the model economy after a uniform wealth destruction shock or changes in corporate tax but not after a financial deregulation shock produces the joint dynamics of EY, KY, and wealth inequality experienced in major developed economies after World War II. Lastly, we find empirical evidence for persistent heterogeneous returns in the PSID surveys. Keywords: Top End Wealth Inequality; Pareto Wealth Distribution; Sufficient Statistics; Heterogeneous Returns; r-g; Corporate Tax; Financial Development For useful comments and discussions we thank Daron Acemoglu, George Akerlof, Jinhui Bai, Alberto Bisin, Mary-Ann Bronson, Paco Buera, Martin Evans, Garance Genicot, Pedro Gete, Mark Huggett, Roger Lagunoff, Ben Moll, Thomas Piketty, Vincenzo Quadrini, Martin Ravallion, Richard Rogerson, John Rust, and participants at Georgetown macroeconomic seminar. We also thank Son Le for excellent research assistance and his initial involvement in the project. Corresponding author. address: dc448@georgetown.edu 1

2 1 Introduction The recent empirical work by Piketty 2014, Saez and Zucman 2016, and others has found that the wealth distribution in major developed countries is highly unequal, especially in the U.S. The distribution has thick right tails, which are well approximated by Pareto Law. Are there simple and observable aggregate statistics that might help determine and forecast the degree of wealth inequality, and relatedly the Pareto tail index? Do they explain the differences in wealth inequality across economies and over time? Piketty 2014 proposes a theory, formalized in Piketty and Zucman 2015, that the Pareto tail index, θ, is determined by a simple sufficient statistics: the gap between interest rate, r, and the growth rate of the economy, i.e., θ = ˆθ 0 r g, for some function ˆθ 0.. While this simple theory is very appealing and makes important predictions about the future of wealth inequality in major developed countries, 1 it has come under fierce criticism including Acemoglu and Robinson 2015, Jones 2015, Mankiw 2015, Krusell and Smith 2015, Ray 2015, and others. One criticism that stands out is that, by focusing on r g, Piketty 2014 implicitly assumes that the saving rate out of capital income is equal to 1. 2 In this paper, we show that when we endogenize this saving rate in a fully optimizing, general equilibrium model, the tail index is a function of the model s parameters and observable equilibrium variables other than, and in addition to, the simple gap r g. 3 In the simplest cases, we have the following formula: θ = ˆθ 1 r, g, EY, KY, where EY and KY are the aggregate labor income share and capital to output ratio, respectively. In general equilibrium, the observables, EY and KY, provide information about the endogenous saving rate, as well as the implied aggregate capital accumulation and equilibrium rate of return to capital or rates of return to capital if the rates differ across agents. Returning to the question asked at the beginning of this paper, our formula for θ sug- 1 For example, recent low growth in OECD countries should imply high wealth inequality in the near future. 2 Admittedly, the formula in Piketty and Zucman 2015 for top end inequality involves the exogenous average saving rate their equation for ω between equations 15.3 and 15.5, despite lack of emphasis. However, this exogenous saving rate might be unobservable, unlike r and g. 3 Our results also apply under the assumption that the saving rate is exogenously given but is constant over time. What turns out to be more important is the general equilibrium implications of this saving rate. 2

3 gests that, although there might be useful sufficient aggregate statistics, in general, one would need more information about the economy than r g to determine and forecast top end wealth inequality. Relatedly, in general equilibrium, observable aggregates provide information about unobservable parameters that are valuable for such an enterprise. Moreover, in the class of models that we consider, under the restrictive assumption that the agents in the model face the same rate of returns to capital, i.e., interest rate r, as assumed by Piketty 2014 and Piketty and Zucman 2015, the model, when calibrated to match the historical values of EY, KY, r, g in the U.S., has a tail index of the stationary wealth distribution that is too high. That is top end wealth inequality is too low compared to the estimates from U.S. data. Heterogeneous rates of return to capital are indispensable in helping the model match the historical tail index. Our model builds on a general equilibrium framework in continuous time and features idiosyncratic investment risk as in Quadrini 2000 and Angeletos In the model, the agents share the same utility function but might differ in their investment returns, which are determined by their investment productivity. 4 For tractability, we assume that at any instant, there are at most two levels of investment returns, high or low. In the special case of homogenous returns that we also consider, the two returns are the same. The agents are subject to idiosyncratic shocks, as in Huggett 1993 and Aiyagari 1994, with Poisson arrival rates. If an agent is hit by a shock, her return switches from high to low, or low to high. In addition, to capture earnings inequality, we allow for permanent heterogeneity in labor productivity across agents. There is a bond market that allows the agents to save or borrow, subject to a borrowing constraint. Given the idiosyncratic investment returns and the financial market structure, the agents make the consumption, saving, and investment decisions to maximize their inter-temporal expected utility, taking interest rate and wage rate as given. We study the properties of the recursive competitive equilibrium of the model, in which prices are determined such that relevant markets, bond and labor markets, clear at all time. The model delivers several sets of results. First, in the stationary balanced growth path of the model, the stationary wealth distribution has a right Pareto tail, with the tail index determined by a simple quadratic equation. Following Piketty 2014, we define top end wealth inequality as the tail index, θ a lower tail index corresponds to more wealth 4 Heterogenous investment returns in our model can have several interpretations. They might arise from different degrees of financial sophistication while investing in publicly traded financial instruments, as documented in Calvet, Campbell, and Sodini 2007, differential access to high return investments in private businesses, or from entrepreneurship as documented and modeled in Quadrini 2000 and Cagett and De Nardi While we do not take a stand on the precise channel leading to heterogeneous returns, our model has a direct entrepreneurship interpretation. 3

4 inequality. Piketty 2014 and Piketty and Zucman 2015 argue that top end inequality is a function of the difference between interest rate and the growth rate of the economy. In our second set of results, we generalize this result or rather intuition to our model economy with heterogenous investment returns. We show that θ = ˆθ 2 g H g, where g H is the endogenous growth rate of wealth of the agent with weakly higher investment returns, relative to the endogenous growth rate of the economy. In addition, ˆθ 2 is strictly decreasing, i.e., the higher the gap g H g, the higher top end wealth inequality. The aforementioned formula contains endogenous and potentially unobservable variables. In two special cases, we obtain sharper characterizations and more user-friendly formulae. First, in the special case of homogenous returns, we show that θ = ˆθ 1a r, g, n, EY, KY, where n is population growth rate. Second, under strictly heterogenous investment returns but log utility and without population growth, we have θ = ˆθ 1b r, g, EY, KY. Therefore, at least in these cases, top end inequality is determined by factors other than the simple difference between interest rate and growth rate of the economy. In addition, we show that, everything else being equal, lowering labor income share, or aggregate growth rate, is associated with an increase in top end wealth inequality ˆθ 1b ˆθ 1b g EY > 0 and > 0, as discussed in Piketty However, an increase in capital to output ratio corresponds to a decrease in top end wealth inequality ˆθ 1b KY suggested by Piketty > 0, unlike the outcome We then calibrate the model to the U.S. economy and show that the parameters can be chosen to match important moments in the data, including the aggregate capital to output ratio, labor income share, and top end wealth inequality. In the calibration, in order to generate a Pareto tail index of 2 for top end wealth inequality, we need strictly heterogeneous returns with a difference of around 4% in un-levered returns 6% in levered returns that lasts on average 10 years. In this calibrated model, in which top end wealth inequality is determined by heterogenous investment returns, we also look at the importance of earnings inequality and initial wealth distribution at the beginning of the agents lifetime - initial wealth inequality - on top end wealth inequality. We find that varying 4

5 earnings inequality and initial wealth inequality, while keeping the aggregate variables constant, do not alter top end wealth inequality as measured by the Pareto tail index, or to a lesser extent, the top wealth share statistics top 0.1%, 1%, or 5% wealth shares. Outside the stationary balanced growth path of the calibrated model, we examine the joint dynamics of top end wealth inequality and the aggregate variables, capital to output ratio and labor income share, over transitional paths after a significant destruction of physical capital which was experienced in major European countries during WWI and WWII and after changes in corporate tax which were experienced in the U.S. during and after WWII and in the 1970s. We find that the dynamics of capital to output ratio and labor income share in the model have similar patterns as in the data increasing capital to output ratio and decreasing earning to output ratio over time. In addition, top end inequality follows a U-shape over the transitional paths, as also observed in the data by Piketty 2014, however in much smaller magnitudes and at lower speeds. We also consider the transitional path after a relaxation of borrowing constraints, which corresponds to financial deregulation in the 1980s in the U.S. Although relaxing borrowing constraints increases top end wealth inequality, it leads to lower capital to output ratio and higher labor income share, neither of which is consistent with the evidence in U.S. data documented in Piketty and Zucman Lastly, as the model calls for persistent heterogenous returns to match top end wealth inequality in the data, we find some evidence for persistent differences in returns to wealth across households from the PSID surveys. For each household in the survey, we define returns as the ratio between the sum of financial income - asset income from farm and business, rent, interest, dividends, income from royalty and trust funds excluding capital gains because of data quality - and core asset the sum of net worth, excluding other debts, home equity, and vehicles. The resulting returns to wealth display great heterogeneity and persistence. We also find that persistent heterogeneous returns can be inferred from wealth mobility. For example, households which have experienced episodes of high returns are also more likely to show upward wealth mobility in the future. The current paper belongs to the theoretical literature on Pareto distribution for wealth. Early work started with Stiglitz 1969; more recently, Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2011, 2015, 2016, Moll 2012, Toda 2014, Achdou et al. 2015, Nirei and Aoki 2016, and others have provided interesting and important mechanisms to generate stationary wealth distribution with Pareto tails. 5 The Pareto tail index in these papers are given by formulae involving unobservable parameters and variables. For example, Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2011, 2015, 2016 provide formulae for the tail index that require knowledge of the 5 Benhabib and Bisin 2016 provide an excellent survey of the literature. 5

6 entire distribution of stochastic investment returns and the entire demographic structure of the economy. In this context, Piketty 2014 s and Piketty and Zucman 2015 s r g theory is compelling since one needs to observe only simple aggregate statistics from an economy to gauge the degree of wealth inequality in that economy. In this paper, following the intuition in Piketty 2014 and Piketty and Zucman 2015, we not only show that wealth distribution has a right Pareto tail as found in the earlier literature, but we also attempt to go a step further by characterizing how the tail parameters vary with the underlying parameters and observable aggregate variables in the economy. In general equilibrium, observable aggregates provide information about unobservable parameters that help determine and forecast wealth inequality. This mechanism is absent in partial equilibrium papers, such as Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2011, 2015, Our paper is also related to the growing literature studying idiosyncratic investment risks. In this literature, most papers, including Angeletos 2007, Toda 2014, Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2015, Piketty and Zucman 2015, and Nirei and Aoki 2016, assume I.I.D. investment risks, or, more precisely, investment returns. 6 In this paper, we extend their analysis to allow for persistent idiosyncratic investment risks. From this perspective, our paper is closely related to Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2011, 2016, Buera and Shin 2011, Moll 2012, Moll 2014, Achdou et al. 2015, Buera and Moll 2015, who consider persistent idiosyncratic investment risks. Our paper can be seen as a simplification of these papers. We use a simple two-level idiosyncratic investment risk Poisson process, which allows us to obtain sharp analytical characterizations of top end wealth inequality and transitional paths in general equilibrium with or without production. 7 Heterogenous returns in our paper can be interpreted as returns to entrepreneurs versus workers, as in the literature on entrepreneurship, including Quadrini 2000, Cagett and De Nardi 2006, and Buera In these papers, entrepreneurs have access to more productive production technologies than non-entrepreneurs. This assumption can be mapped into heterogeneous returns to investment in our model. However, unlike these papers, we do not assume fixed-costs of starting up a business or decreasing returns to scale. This assumption allows us to preserve the homogeneity of the optimization problem of the agents, which simplifies the characterization of wealth distribution 6 Piketty and Zucman 2015 assume I.I.D. saving rates, but this assumption is isomorphic to I.I.D. investment risks assumption. The analytical results in Nirei and Aoki 2016 rely on I.I.D. investment shocks, but the authors relax this assumption in their quantitative investigation. 7 Benhabib et al and Gabaix et al. 2015, Online Appendix provide analytical characterizations of the Pareto tail index for wealth distribution under persistent investment shocks as we do, but only in a partial equilibrium setting in which the rates of returns are exogenous. General equilibrium might lead to interesting comparative statics, such as a non-monotone effect of financial development on the tail index, as shown in Moll 2012 and in our Proposition 2. 6

7 and transitional paths. Another strand of literature starting with Huggett 1996 attempts to explain the high degree of wealth inequality using models with idiosyncratic earnings shocks over the lifecycle of households. However, this class of models cannot match wealth inequality at the very top unless one assumes very large temporary earnings shocks as in Castaneda et al Using a similar model, Kaymak and Poschke 2016 show that increases in earnings inequality have accounted for most of the increase in wealth inequality in the U.S. since the 1970s. In our model, in which wealth inequality is driven by persistent heterogeneous investment returns, changing earnings inequality has negligible effects on wealth inequality. Benhabib, Bisin, and Zhu 2011 and Benhabib, Bisin, and Luo 2015 also emphasize this point in a partial equilibrium context. Over transitional paths, Gabaix et al. 2015, Online Appendix have recently argued that heterogenous returns give rise to fast transitional dynamics of top end wealth inequality. However, in their analysis, the authors take the returns on wealth as exogenously given. In our paper, the returns are endogenously determined by the total supply of capital and labor along transitional paths. We find that, despite significant return heterogeneity, the transition of top end wealth inequality is rather slow. Empirically, we find some evidence for heterogeneous and persistent returns to wealth in the data from PSID surveys. Fagereng et al have found similar evidence in Norwegian household level data. Saez and Zucman 2016 have also found that, for foundations, total rates of returns - including unrealized capital gains - rise sharply with foundation wealth. Using Swedish household level data, Calvet, Campbell, and Sodini 2007 documented that more financially sophisticated households earn higher mean returns from investments in publicly traded financial instruments. The rest of this paper is organized as follow. Section 2 presents a general model with capital accumulation, production, and labor. Section 3 presents a special case, the AK model, and results on top end inequality and transitional dynamics. In Section 4, we calibrate the main model to the U.S. economy and investigate the quantitative implications of the model. Lastly, Section 5 presents empirical evidence for persistent heterogeneity in idiosyncratic investment returns and their implications for wealth mobility. Section 6 concludes. 2 An Neoclassical Economy in Continuous Time In this section, we develop a neoclassical growth model in continuous time as presented in Acemoglu 2009 but with heterogenous agents facing idiosyncratic death shocks and 7

8 investment shocks, which determine the productivity of their capital investment. The agents can finance their projects only by issuing risk-free debt, collateralized by their capital. 2.1 The Environment Time - t - is continuous and runs from 0 to. 8 The economy is populated by a continuum of agents that are indexed by h N t = [0, N t ] where N t is population size at time t. Investment Productivity Let i h t denote the individual state of agent h at time t. We assume that i h t follows a two-state Markov chain, i h t I = {L, H}, which capture low i h t = L and high investment productivity i h t = H, with Poisson switching rates λ LH and λ HL from one state to the other. By the law of large numbers, the fraction of agents with high investment returns and low investment returns are respectively λ LH M H = λ HL + λ LH λ M L = HL = 1 M λ HL + H. λ LH In each instant, the agents can produce output using a constant-return-to-scale technology, which depends on the idiosyncratic state, using capital and labor 9 Y t = F i h t k h t, l h t. We assume that the high type is more productive than the low type. Assumption 1. For any k, l > 0, F H k, l > F L k, l. While in this paper we focus on the case in which there are only two-level of investment productivities, we can extend easily the model to allow for more heterogeneity in this dimension. In addition, when agents with lower productivity actively produce in equilibrium, this model is equivalent to one in which a competitive representative firm 8 We have also studied and solved the model in discrete time. However, the solution for the equilibrium wealth distribution is much simpler in continuous time. 9 The production function includes depreciation, i.e. Y t is net output. The CES production function in Section 4 is an example. 8

9 uses the less productive production function and entrepreneurs that have access to the more productive production. The macroeconomic literature on entrepreneurship such as Quadrini 2000 and Cagett and De Nardi 2006 often embraces this interpretation. Labor Productivity Each agent is also endowed with x h t efficiency units of labor. We assume that x h t grows at the rate g x common across households: x h t+t = x h t eg xt. 10 We assume that the initial labor productivity of an agent is determined when she is born. Normalized by a constant trend G x,t = e gxt, defined over R + with c.d.f Ψx and mean x h t G x,t is initially drawn from a distribution Death Shocks, Population Growth, and Redistribution Population N t grows at a constant rate n 0 and the initial population is normalized to 1. We also assume that agents are hit by death shock, arriving at Poisson rate λ > 0.Therefore, there are n + λn t t new borns in each infinitesimal [t, t + t] time interval. The investment productivity of the new born can be H or L with the fraction M H and M L respectively. The labor productivity of the new borns, relative to the constant trend G x,t, are drawn from the distribution Ψ.. The total wealth of the dying agent is redistributed to the new borns according to a redistribution function Γ i,t ψ. That is, conditional on investment productivity type i, each agent receives a draw of fraction ψ from the distribution Γ i,t Pr ψ ψ = Γ i,t ψ. The agent then obtains a fraction ψ of the total wealth of the dying agents per new born. We also assume that the support of Γ i,t belongs to R +. Since in each instant, there is a mass λ tn t of dying agents and a mass λ + n N t of new borns, and the total wealth of the dying agents is redistributed fully, we must have M H ψdγ H,t ψ + M L ψdγ L,t ψ = 1. In most cases, we assume that the redistribution function preserves the total wealth of agents with the same investment productivity. 10 In Online Appendix E, we extend the model to allow for heterogenous but deterministic growth rate of labor productivity across agents. As shown in Gabaix et al. 2015, heterogenous growth rates of labor productivity can potentially help explain high labor income inequality and a rapid rise in labor income inequality. However, we cannot allow for idiosyncratic productivity shocks over the agents lifetime since the optimization problem of the agents would no longer be homogenous in total wealth. 11 The model does not exhibit the scale effect, so normalizing the mean of Ψ to 1 is without loss of generality. 9

10 Assumption 2. The distribution function is type preserving i.e. M i ψdγ i,t ψw t = W i,t ψ for i = H, L, where W t is aggregate financial wealth and W i,t is the aggregate financial wealth of all agents with investment productivity i conditional aggregate. Death shocks and redistribution are crucial in preventing the wealth distribution from ever expanding and give rise to a stationary distribution. 12 The redistribution functions Γ i,t also correspond to wealth inequality at the beginning of the agents lifetime - initial wealth inequality. In the calibration of the model in Section 4, we use the estimates by Huggett et al of wealth inequality at the ages in PSID for Γ i. Utility, Constraints, and Optimization function The agents share the same instantaneous utility c 1 σ 1 σ if σ = 1 uc = logc if σ=1. Let {r t, e t } t=0 denote the sequence of interest rates and wages. Agent h chooses a sequence of capital holding k h t, bond holding bh t, and consumption ch t to maximize subject to dw h t dt [ max E exp ρ + λ t ] u c ct h t h dt,kh t,bh 0 t } = max {F i k h lt h t, lt h e t lt h + r t bt h + e t xt h ct h 2 ht w h t = k h t + b h t, 3 where wt h denote the financial wealth of agent h at time t. The budget constraint, 2, and portfolio constraint, 3, are standard. At time t, change in financial wealth, dwh t dt, consists of return from capital investment, interest from bond holding, r t b t, labor earning, e t xt h, minus consumption, ct h. Financial wealth, wh t, is allocated to capital holding kh t and bond holding bt h. The agent is also subject to the borrowing constraint 5 defined below. Let Q t denote the present discounted value of future labor income for each agent, i.e. 12 See Gabaix 2009 for other types of assumptions that guarantee the existence of a stationary wealth distribution with Pareto tail such as a reflecting barrier. 1 10

11 human wealth, Q h t = 0 t exp r t+t dt e t+t xt+t h dt. Since x h t grows at the rate g x, we also have Q h t = q tx h t, where q t = The dynamics of Q h t and q t are then given by 0 t exp r t+t g 0 1 x dt 1 e t+t dt. dq h t dt = r t Q h t e t x h t and dq t dt = r t g x q t e t. 4 Given Qt h, we assume that the borrowing constraint takes the form 0 k h t and 0 mk h t + bt h + Qt h, 5 where m 0, 1. It is important that the borrowing constraint is in terms of borrowing plus the present discounted value of labor income so that the optimization problem of the agent is homogeneous, as we will see below. 13 The definition of an equilibrium is standard. Definition 1. For any initial distribution of wealth { w0 h } h N, a competitive equilibrium is 0 described by stochastic processes: the processes for interest rates and wage rates {r t, e t } t=0, wealth distribution { w h t } t=0,h N t, capital and bond holdings { k h t, bh t } t=0,h N t and consumption { c h t } t=0,h N t ; such that i The allocation { w h t, kh t, bh t, ch t } solves agent h s maximization problem 1 given the processes for interest rates and wage rates. and ii Bond and labor markets clear in each instant h N t b h t dh = 0, lt h dh = xt h dh. h N t h N t Notice that by Walras Law, the market clearing condition in the bond market implies 13 Angeletos 2007 makes a similar assumption on borrowing constraint, except for m = 0. 11

12 that market for consumption goods also clear, i.e total output equals to total consumption plus total investment: F i k ht h Nt h t, lt h dh = c h dwt h t dh + h N t h N t dt dh. Together with the portfolio choice constraint 3, the market clearing condition in the bond market implies market clearing in capital market: k h t dh = wt h dh. h N t h N t Given the homogeneous structure of the model, in the following subsection, we show that a competitive equilibrium has a simpler representation. Indeed, the definition of competitive equilibrium suggests that we need to keep track of the whole wealth distribution to solve for the equilibrium. However, taking advantage of the homogeneity of the agents optimization problem, we show that only some aggregates are sufficient to determine the equilibrium in economy. Having solved for the equilibrium prices and policy functions, we can then go back to solve for the equilibrium wealth distribution. In this sense, solving for an equilibrium is decoupled into solving for the equilibrium aggregates and solving for the equilibrium wealth distribution. 2.2 Markov Equilibrium To obtain sharper characterization of a competitive equilibrium, we first characterize the agents optimal dynamic strategies using the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman HJB equation for their value functions in a competitive equilibrium. To simplify the notation, we use the following auxiliary functions, R i e and S i e: R i ek = max F i k, l el lt h and S i ek denote the maximizer. Because F i has constant returns to scale, we have F i k, S i ek = R i ek + es i ek. R i e and S i e are basically the payments to capital and labor per unit of capital used in the production function F i. Let Vt, it h, xh t, wh t denote the value function from the maximization 1 of agent h. The following lemma provides the PDE that characterizes V. 12

13 Lemma 1. The HJB equation for V is ρ + λ V V t = max c,k,b uc + V x g xx t + V w R i h t e tk + r t b c + e t x t + λ i h t, i h t Vt, ih t, x h t, w h t Vt, i h t, x h t, w h t 6 where the maximization problem is subject to the constraints wt h = k + b and 0 k and 0 mk + b + Qt h we adopt the standard notation that H = L and L = H for i h t and it h. Proof. Online Appendix C. We conjecture and verify that the value function V has the form: V h t, it h, xt h, wt h vt, it h = wt h + xh t q 1 σ t if σ = 1 vt, it h + 1 ρ+ λ log wt h + xh t q t if σ=1. In addition, we work with b t = b t + Qt h. Given the functional form for V, the HJB equation for the agents, 6, becomes ρ + λvt, i h t vt, ih t t = max c,k,b H i h t c, k, b; vt, i h t + λ i h t, i h t vt, ih t vt, i h t 7 where uc + 1 σvr i e t k + r t b c when σ = 1 H i c, k, b; t, v = logc + 1 ρ+ λ R ie t k + r t b c when σ = 1 and the maximization problem is subject to 8 1 = k + b and 0 k and 0 mk + b. 9 This implies that the policy functions are linear in total wealth, i.e. financial wealth plus human wealth: k h t = k i h t b t h = b t it h ct h = c t it h t wt h + Qt h wt h + Qt h wt h + Qt h. 13

14 Let W i,t = h:it h=i wh t dh denote the total wealth conditional on investment productivity type i. The market clearing condition in the bond market becomes: b H t W H,t + M H G t N t q t + b L t W L,t + M L G t N t q t G t N t q t = 0, 10 and in the labor market becomes: S H e t k H,t W H,t + M H G t N t q t + S L e t k L,t W L,t + M L G t N t q t = G t N t 11 which depends only on W H,t, W L,t, q t. The following lemma provides the equations that determine the dynamics of these three variables. Lemma 2. In a competitive equilibrium, the aggregate dynamics of aggregate conditional wealth satisfy, for i {H, L} dw i,t dt = k i,t R ie t + bi,t r t ci,t W i,t + q t M i G t N t λ i, i W i,t + λ i,i W i,t + λ M i ψdγ i,t ψw i,t M i ψdγ i,t ψw i,t dq t dt M ig t N t g x q t M i G t N t ψ ψ 12 and q t satisfies 4. Proof. Online Appendix C. The analysis above suggests that W H,t, W L,t, q t are sufficient endogenous state variables to determine interest rate, wage rate and allocations at time t. The following definition formalizes the intuition. Definition 2. A Markov equilibrium is a competitive equilibrium in which the equilibrium prices r t, e t and policy functions, ci,t, k i,t, b i,t depend only on the aggregate state variables W H,t, W L,t, q t. It is also important to characterize the dynamics of the aggregate growth rate of the economy and of the wealth shares of agents with the same investment productivity. Indeed, let g t denote the growth of the aggregate total wealth, which is given by g t = 1 d W H,t + W L,t + Q t, W H,t + W L,t + Q t dt 14

15 and X t is the wealth share of agents with high investment productivity: X t = W H,t + M H N t q t W t + Q t. The following result characterizes the dynamics of g t and X t as functions of the agents policy functions. Lemma 3. In a competitive equilibrium, the dynamics of the growth rate of total wealth is given by In addition, X t satisfies g t = R H e t k H,t + r t b H,t H,t c Xt + R L e t k L,t + r t b L,t L,t c 1 Xt Q t + n. 13 W t + Q t dx t dt = g H,t g L,t X t1 X t λ HL X t + λ LH 1 X t + λ M H ψdγ H,t ψ1 X t M L ψdγ L,t ψx t ψ ψ Q t λm H M L ψdγ H,t ψ ψdγ L,t ψ ψ ψ W t + Q t Q t + n M W t + H X t, 14 Q t where gi,t denote the relative growth rate of type i agents: g i,t R ie t k i,t + r tb i,t c i,t g t. Proof. Online Appendix C. From the expression for g t in 13 and the definition of gi,t above, we obtain 0 = g H,t X t + g L,t 1 X t + n. 15 W t + Q t Q t 15

16 When Assumption 2 holds, equation 14 simplifies to dx t dt = g H,t g L,t X t1 X t λ HL X t + λ LH 1 X t Q t + n M W t + H X t. 16 Q t The results above fully characterize the aggregate dynamics of the economy without the knowledge of the entire wealth distribution among the agents in the economy. Given the aggregate dynamics, the following lemma provides the PDEs that characterize the evolution of the wealth distribution over time. Let ω h t denote the total wealth financial plus human wealth of agent h relative to the average total wealth in the population at time t: and let p i t, ω denote: ωt h = wh t + q txt h, W t +Q t N t p i t, ω = Prω h t ω, i h t = i. By the law of large numbers, p H t, ω p L t, ω, is also the fraction of agents with high investment return low investment return and with relative total wealth exceeding ω. p H t, ω and p L t, ω satisfy the following Kolmogorov forward equation. Lemma 4. p H and p L satisfy the following PDEs: p i t, ω t = p it, ω ω ω gi,t + n λ i, i + λ + n p i t, ω + λ i, i p i t, ω + λ + n ω W t + Q t J i,t, q tg t N t W t λ λ+n W t λ λ+n 17 where J i,t y 1, y 2 = Γ i,t y 1 y 2 x dφx and p i also satisfies the boundary conditions: Proof. Online Appendix C. lim p it, ω = 1 and lim p i t, ω = 0. ω 0 ω 16

17 2.3 Stationary Balanced Growth Path In this subsection, we look for a stationary equilibrium as in Huggett 1993 and Aiyagari 1994, in which interest rate, wage rate, rates of return on investment, wealth redistribution functions, and relative wealth distributions remain unchanged over time. However, the economy as a whole grows at a constant rate. Definition 3. A stationary stationary balanced growth path, or balanced growth path BGP for short, is a Markov equilibrium in which interest rate, wage rate, rates of return on investment, growth rate, and relative wealth distribution are constant over time. The concept of stationary balanced growth path is standard see for example Huggett et al and Acemoglu and Cao With strictly concave production functions, we can easily show that in a BGP the economy grows that the rate n + g x and W i,t = W i e g x+nt. Since interest rate and wage rate are constant over time, q t q, and by 4, q is determined by: 0 = r g x q ē. 18 The value functions in 7 become vt, i v i, where v i satisfies ρ + λ v i = max c,k,b H ic, k, b; v i + λ i, i v i v i 19 where uc + 1 σvr i ēk + r b c when σ = 1 H i c, k, b; v = logc + 1 ρ+ λ R iēk + r b c when σ = 1 and the maximization is subject to the constraints 9. The dynamics of aggregate wealth, 12, simplifies to 20 g x + n W i = k i R iē + b i r c i W i + qm i λ i, i W i + λ i,i W i + λ M i ψdγ i ψ W i M i ψdγ i ψ W i g x qm i. 21 The markets clearing conditions 10 and 11 become ψ ψ b H X + b L 1 X = q W + q, 22 17

18 and ēs H ē k H X + ēs L ē k L 1 X = ē W + q, 23 where X = W H +M H q W H + W L + q. The following theorem characterizes the BGP in the economy. Theorem 1 Stationary Balanced Growth Path. Assume Assumption 1 holds. Depending on the parameters of the model, a stationary BGP is characterized by six equations: two HJB equations 19 for H- and L-agents, the two equations determining W H and W L, 21, the two market clearing conditions, 22 and 23. However, the unknowns differ in three different cases: Case 1: r = R L ē. Then k H, b H = 1 1 m, 1 m m and b L = 1 k L. The six unknowns are v H, v L, k L, ē, W H, W L. Case 2: R L ē < r < R H ē. Then k H, b H = 1 1 m, 1 m m and k L, b L = 0, 1.The six unknowns are v H, v L, r, ē, W H, W L. Case 3: r = R H ē. Then k L, b L = 0, 1 and b H = 1 k H. The six unknowns are v H, v L, k H, ē, W H, W L. Lastly, in Case 1 and Case 2: R H ē k H + r b H c H > R Lē k L + r b L c L. Proof. Appendix A. In Case 1, given that r = R L ē, L-agents are indifferent between producing using their production function and lending to the H-agents at interest rate r. In equilibrium, they do both, i.e. 0 k L 1 and k L, b L are determined by the equilibrium conditions. The same logic applies to Case 3. One important implication of this theorem is that in Case 1 and Case 2, the agents with the higher rate of returns on investment H-agents save more. While consumption can be higher or lower due to the opposite income and substitution effects, the effect to higher rates of returns on saving is unambiguous. 14 This result is consistent with Saez and Zucman 2016 who find that saving rates tend to rise with wealth The proof of this property is not straightforward due to the switching probability between the two rates of returns. When σ < 1, we can show that the substitution effect on consumption dominates the income effects, therefore c H < c L so the result on saving rate is immediate. It is more difficult to prove the result when σ > 1, so that c H > c L. 15 We also find some empirical evidence for higher saving rates conditional on higher returns to wealth in PSID. 18

19 Theorem 1 does not tell us the conditions under which the equilibrium belongs to Case 1, 2, or 3. For a special case of this model, the AK model in Section 3 and with log utility, Proposition 1 provides a complete characterization. We show that Case 1 happens when m is low, Case 2 when m is intermediate, and Case 3 when m is high. We have verified numerically that the same pattern holds for the current model with production. In the BGP characterized by Theorem 1, the PDEs for stationary wealth distribution, 17, become 0 = p iω ω ω ḡ i + n λ i, i + λ + n p i ω + λ i, i p i ω + λ + n ω W H + W L + q q J i, W H + W L λ λ+n where J i is defined in Lemma 4 with Γ i,t Γ i. W H + W L λ λ+n The following theorem characterizes the stationary wealth distribution., 24 Theorem 2 Pareto Tail. Assume that the supports of Φ and Γ i,t are bounded above, then in a stationary BGP, we obtain the following properties of the stationary distributions. 1 The stationary distribution of total wealth financial plus human wealth has right Pareto tail. More specifically, p H ω = Ψ Hω θ p L ω = Ψ Lω θ for all ω ω for some Ψ H, Ψ L > 0 and ω > 0, and θ is the negative root of the following quadratic equation: λhl + λ + n ḡ H + n λlh + λ + n λ + η ḡ L + n + η HL λ LH ḡ H + n ḡ = L + n 2 The distribution of financial wealth follows an approximate power law with the same tail index as the one for the distribution of total wealth, i.e. there exist d > d > 0 such that dw θ Pr when w, where θ is determined in Part 1. Proof. Appendix A. w h t W t /N t w dw θ, 19

20 Similar results still hold if the supports of Φ and Γ i are unbounded but the distributions have thin tails, or Pareto tail with the tail index strictly higher than θ. However, we need to relax the definition of Pareto tail to asymptotic Pareto tail as in Acemoglu and Cao Following Piketty 2014, we define top end wealth inequality as the upper tail index, θ in Theorem 2. Lower θ corresponds to fatter tail of the wealth distribution, i.e. higher degree of wealth inequality. The results in Theorem 2 deserve some discussion. Homogenous Rates of Returns First of all, in the special case without heterogeneous investment risk, ḡ H = ḡ L = n q W+ q and λ HL = λ LH = 0, by 25, the tail index is given by θ = 1 + λ 1 + q W. 26 n In the AK model presented in Section 3, q = 0, we recover the formula for the tail index given in Jones 2015 θ = 1 + λ n. As noted by Jones 2015, this formula contradicts the intuition put forth in Piketty 2014: in general equilibrium, lower population growth leads to lower top end wealth inequality. With concave production functions, using 18 and the observation that ē W = KY EY, 26 implies that 17 θ = ˆθ 1a EY, KY, r; gx, λ, n := 1 + λ 1 + EY n KY 1 r g x. 27 In Online Appendix F, we present a direct derivation of 27 in the standard neoclassical growth model a la Ramsey-Cass-Koopman with labor productivity growth. 18 We show that θ = λ + n r c g x. After solving out for consumption rate c using equilibrium conditions, we arrive at 27. Using the standard values for parameters λ, n, g x and the historical values of EY and 16 A distribution density ϕ has asymptotic Pareto tail χ if for any ξ > 0 there exists B, B and x such that Bx χ 1+ξx < ϕx < Bx χ 1 ξx for all x x. 17 Notice that the tail index depends on r g x and n separately, unlike what is conjectured by Piketty 2014, i.e. θ = ˆθ 0 r g where g = g x + n. 18 In a companion note Online Appendix II, we also present an equivalent formulation with exogenous labor augmenting technological progress. 20

21 KY in the U.S. data see Table 1, 27 implies a tail index of which is too high compared to those observed in the U.S. data which are between 1.4 and 2 over the years. We will show below that allowing for heterogenous returns in the model can help match the empirical tail index. Heterogeneous Rates of Returns Returning to the general model with heterogenous returns, equation 25 also tells us how θ depends on ḡ H, ḡ L and the transitional probabilities λ HL, λ LH and population growth. We obtain sharper characterizations of how θ varies if we assume that there is no population growth and that wealth redistribution is type preserving. Theorem 3 Sufficient Statistics I. Assume n = 0 and Assumption 2 holds. In a stationary BGP with k L > 0, i.e. Case 1 in Theorem 1, top end wealth inequality is a function of the relative growth rate of the high type and the persistent parameters: θ = ˆθ 2 ḡ H ; λ HL, λ LH, λ. In addition, top end wealth inequality increases in ḡ H, i.e. ˆθ 2 ḡ H Proof. Appendix A. This is a generalization of the now famous result from Piketty 2014 that top end wealth inequality depends on r g, which corresponds to formula 27 above. With heterogenous investment returns, top end inequality depends on the relative growth rate of wealth of the high type agents, which in turn depends on their investment returns, equilibrium interest rate and endogenous consumption and portfolio choice decisions: < 0. ḡ H = R Hē k H + r b H c H ḡ. The first two terms in the right hand side capture the rate of returns on the optimal portfolio of the H-type. The third term captures the fact that a fraction of the returns is consumed. This term is implicitly ignored by Piketty 2014 when he focuses on the gap r g as the sole determinant of wealth inequality. This implicit assumption is criticized by Mankiw 2015 and Ray In a BGP, the aggregate labor income share and capital to output ratio are given by: EY ē F H 1, S H ē + δ k H W H + M H Q + F L 1, S L ē + δ k L W L + M L Q, 21

22 and KY W H + W L F H 1, S H ē + δ k H W H + M H Q + F L 1, S L ē + δ k L W L + M L Q. How are KY and EY related to each other? By looking at the distribution of output between wages and returns to capital, we obtain k H X k H X + k L 1 X R k L Hē + δ + 1 X k H X + k L 1 X R Lē + δ KY = 1 } {{ EY }. }{{} captital income share average rate of return to capital 28 Notice that this identity is a generalization of the Piketty 2014 s First Fundamental Law of Capitalism: rβ = α, in his model with homogeneous returns. In our model with heterogenous returns, capital income share is equal to the product of the weighted average of the rates of return to capital of the two types of agents and the capital to output ratio. 19 The following theorem links the top end inequality to the two aggregate statistics. Theorem 4 Sufficient Statistics II. Assume n = 0 and Assumption 2 holds and uc = log c. In a stationary BGP with k L > 0, top end inequality θ is a function of the aggregate labor income share, capital to output ratio, interest rate, together with the primitive parameters g x, δ, λ HL, λ LH, λ: In addition, ˆθ 1b KY > 0, ˆθ 1b EY > 0 and ˆθ 1b g x > 0. Proof. Appendix A. θ = ˆθ 1b EY, KY, r; gx, δ, λ HL, λ LH, λ. Because k L > 0, we are in Case 1 of Theorem 1 which implies that R H > R L, i.e. returns are strictly heterogenous. Therefore, formula 27 for homogenous returns does not apply. Consequently, the comparative statics with respect to KY also differ in the two cases: ˆθ 1a KY < 0, while ˆθ 1b KY > 0. The last two comparative statics in this theorem are consistent with Piketty 2014 s discussion: higher labor income share, or higher growth rate of the economy since n = 0, 19 The production functions F i implicitly incorporate depreciation. So to measure total output - gross output - we add back depreciation to the net output given by F i. This practice is more consistent with the modern formulation of the neoclassical growth models such as Cass Krusell and Smith 2015 show that the distinctions between gross output versus net output and gross saving rate versus net saving rate are important for the predictions of the neoclassical growth models. 22

23 g = g x, corresponds to higher Pareto tail index and thus lowers top end wealth inequality. However, the first comparative statics differ from Piketty 2014 s prediction that higher capital to output ratio is associated with higher wealth inequality. 20 Theorem 4 makes restrictive assumptions such as no population growth and log utility, however it is still fairly general since it allows for any production function as well as any degree of financial friction. For example, changing m certainly changes the equilibrium stationary BGP, as shown in Proposition 1 below. However, top end inequality only changes to the extent that EY, KY, and r change because of the change in m. Theorem 4 shows that in general top end inequality depends on factors other than the simple gap r g suggested by Piketty If the assumptions of Theorem 4 are not satisfied, one should expect that the determinants of the top end wealth inequality are fairly complex, and might not be summarized in a simple formula with simple aggregate statistics as inputs. 3 AK Growth Model In this section we assume that uc log c and F i k, l = A i k where A H > A L > 0. We further assume type-preserving wealth redistribution, i.e. Assumption 2 holds, and no population growth. These assumptions allow us to sharply characterize the balance growth paths as well as transitional dynamics. In Online Appendix G, we also characterize the dynamics of the economy under both idiosyncratic and aggregate shocks to investment returns. We show that the aggregate dynamics depend crucially on the process of idiosyncratic shocks. Although this section helps grasp some qualitative properties of the general model, impatient readers can skip directly to Section 4 in the first reading of the paper. 3.1 Stationary Equilibrium Theorem 1 does not tell us which case happens depending on the exogenous parameters of the model. Under log utility, the following proposition completely characterizes the 20 A casual observation of cross-country data on capital to income ratio and top end wealth inequality from Piketty 2014, Piketty and Zucman 2014, Alvaredo and Saez 2009, and Saez and Zucman 2016 suggests that countries with higher top end wealth inequality might have lower capital to income ratio. For example the U.S. has the highest level of top end wealth inequality, but has lower capital to income ratio, compared to France, Spain, and the U.K. Our preliminary cross-country regression of top 1% wealth share on KY, controlling for other factors, shows that the coefficient on KY is negative and significant. 23

24 equilibrium. 21 Proposition 1. In a stationary BGP, one of the following three cases happens: Case 1: Low m If then r = A L and X < 1 m. Case 2: Intermediate m If M L 1 + A H A L λ HL +λ LH > m > 0, 29 M L > m > M L 1 + A H A L λ HL +λ LH, 30 then and X = 1 m. Case 3: High m If r = A H 1 mλ HL mλ LH m A L, A H 1 > m > M L, 31 then r = A H and X > 1 m Proof. Appendix B.1. The case of log utility also allows us to determine in closed forms the Pareto tail index of the stationary wealth distribution which is a solution to a quadratic equation similar to 25. Therefore, we can also characterize how the degree of financial friction affects the tail index, or equivalently top end wealth inequality. Proposition 2 Financial Kutznet s Curve. In stationary BGPs, top end wealth inequality varies in m differently depending on which case in Proposition 1 the equilibrium belongs to: Case 1 Low m: Top end wealth inequality is increasing in m. Case 2 Intermediate m: Top end wealth inequality is decreasing in m. Case 3 High m: Top end wealth inequality is independent of m. Proof. Appendix B.1. Numerically, Moll 2012 finds a similar result in a production economy with a continuum of investment productivity types and we borrow the term Financial Kutznet s Curve from his analysis. As he explains, in Case 1, top end inequality is increasing in 21 One minor difference relative to Theorem 1 is that the growth rate of the economy is now totally endogenous, instead of being determined exogenously by g x and n. 24

25 m because of the leverage effect, i.e. higher m allows the more productive agents to borrow more at an interest rate determined by the rate of returns to the less productive agents, this magnifies the differences in returns and increases wealth inequality. However, at higher m, i.e., in Case 2, top end wealth inequality is decreasing because of the return equalization effect, i.e. higher m increases the demand to borrow by the more productive agents which pushes up the interest rate earned by the less productive agents which is strictly higher than their own rate of return. This increase in interest rate reduces the differences in returns and decreases wealth inequality. If m is even higher, one reaches Case 3 in which the interest rate earned by the less productive agents is pushed up to the rate of return of the more productive agents. There is essentially no wealth inequality in a stationary BGP in this case. As Piketty 2014 suggests, a powerful tool to reduce wealth inequality is wealth tax. In the following proposition, we consider a proportional wealth tax, τ > 0. We assume that the proceed from taxing wealth is distributed among the new borns. To simplify the analysis, we assume that the redistribution of wealth tax proceeds is distributed within the same type, i.e. tax proceeds from the high-type agents is distributed to the new borns of high type and similarly for low type. 22 The advantage of this assumption is that the aggregate dynamics do not change. However, the following result should not depend on the precise redistribution scheme. Proposition 3 Wealth Tax. Assume uc = log c. There exists τ > 0, such that the Pareto tail index is decreasing in τ for τ 0, τ. Proof. Appendix B.1. As also shown in the appendix, the effectiveness of the wealth tax in reducing wealth inequality depends on the fundamental of the model, such as m, λ HL, λ LH and λ. At first sight, this appears to be a trivial result. However, as shown in Jones 2015, under homogenous returns, wealth taxes do not affect top end wealth inequality because of the general equilibrium effect. Therefore, this proposition shows that heterogenous returns are important for the effectiveness of wealth taxes in reducing top end wealth inequality. 3.2 Transitional Path In this subsection, we investigate the dynamics of the economy over transitional paths. The initial conditions are such that the economy does not start out at a stationary equilib- 22 The formulation of the model with wealth tax is similar to the one with corporate tax presented in Online Appendix D. 25

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model Dan Cao Georgetown University Wenlan Luo Georgetown University July 2016 The textbook Ramsey-Cass-Koopman neoclassical growth

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

Wealth Inequality, or r-g, in the Economic Growth Model

Wealth Inequality, or r-g, in the Economic Growth Model RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-117 Wealth Inequality, or r-g, in the Economic Growth Model HIRAGUCHI Ryoji Chiba University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Benjamin Moll G Online Appendix: The Model in Discrete Time and with iid Shocks This Appendix presents a version

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown September, 2017 Introduction Early heterogeneous-agent models integrated the income-fluctuation problem into general equilibrium models. A key

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

The Dynamics of Inequality

The Dynamics of Inequality The Dynamics of Inequality Preliminary Xavier Gabaix NYU Stern Pierre-Louis Lions Collège de France Jean-Michel Lasry Dauphine Benjamin Moll Princeton JRCPPF Fourth Annual Conference February 19, 2015

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Endogenous Growth: AK Model Endogenous Growth: AK Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 October 24, 2017 1 / 35 Endogenous Growth Why do countries grow? A question with large welfare consequences. We need models where growth is endogenous.

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Handling Non-Convexities: Entrepreneurship and Financial Frictions

Handling Non-Convexities: Entrepreneurship and Financial Frictions Handling Non-Convexities: Entrepreneurship and Financial Frictions Benjamin Moll Model Setup This note describes a model of entrepreneurship and financial frictions, similar to that in Buera and Shin ()

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty Constantine Angyridis Brennan S. Thompson Department of Economics Ryerson University July 8, 2011 Overview We use a dynamic heterogeneous agents general equilibrium

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination August 2015 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 4 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination January 2016 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 3 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 47 Introduction Authors:

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I Name: Students ID: ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I I. Short Questions (21/2 points each) Mark the following statements as True (T) or False (F) and give a brief explanation of your answer in each case. 1. 2.

More information

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1 Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1 Zheng Liu 1 Pengfei Wang 2 Zhiwei Xu 3 1 Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 2 Hong Kong University of Science and Technology 3 Shanghai Jiao

More information

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Consumption and Savings Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Lecture 10 Topics in Macroeconomics November 6, 2007 Lecture 10 1/18 Topics in Macroeconomics Consumption and Savings Outline

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Economics 522 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University Spring 2014 ERH (Princeton University ) Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Spring 2014 1 / 34 Restuccia and Rogerson

More information

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Kjetil Storesletten Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Gianluca Violante

More information

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations Seong-Hoon Kim* Seongman Moon** *Centre for Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis, St Andrews, UK **Korea Institute for International Economic Policy, Seoul, Korea

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4 14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4 Daron Acemoglu Due date: December 5, 12pm noon Please only hand in Question 3, which will be graded. The rest will be reviewed in the recitation but

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change Daron Acemoglu MIT December 13, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 13, 2011. 1 / 71 Directed Technological

More information

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Readings Acemoglu, Chapter 9. Motivation Neoclassical growth model relies on the representative household. OLG models allow for

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017 Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived

More information

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model. Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model. January 8, 2018 1 Introduction This document describes the equilibrium conditions of Kaplan,

More information

Inequality and Financial Development: A Power-Law Kuznets Curve

Inequality and Financial Development: A Power-Law Kuznets Curve Inequality and Financial Development: A Power-Law Kuznets Curve Benjamin Moll August 12, 2012 This note extends the environment in Moll (2012) to feature a stationary wealth distribution. 1 Thisisachievedbyintroducing

More information

Bequest Motives, Estate Taxes, and Wealth Distributions in Becker-Tomes Models with Investment Risk

Bequest Motives, Estate Taxes, and Wealth Distributions in Becker-Tomes Models with Investment Risk Bequest Motives, Estate Taxes, and Wealth Distributions in Becker-Tomes Models with Investment Risk Shenghao Zhu Department of Economics, NUS This draft: June 2013 Abstract I introduce investment risk

More information

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are: Econ 510a second half Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #5 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, December 8 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Solution 1. a In the Mehra-Prescott

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell IIES, University of Göteborg, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER March 2014 WORK-IN-PROGRESS!!! Overall goals

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change

Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture12 December 6, 2018 1 / 62 Directed Technological Change

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: Practice Questions for Mid-Term I Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: y f(k) = k α ; α (0, 1) (1) where y and k are output per worker and capital per worker respectively.

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Constrained Efficiency in a Risky Human Capital Model

Constrained Efficiency in a Risky Human Capital Model Constrained Efficiency in a Risky Human Capital Model Yena Park University of Rochester September 15, 2014 Abstract This paper revisits the question whether capital in a competitive equilibrium is overaccumulated

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) subject to for all t Jonathan Heathcote updated, March 2006 1. The household s problem max E β t u (c t ) t=0 c t + a t+1

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession ONLINE APPENDIX INVESTMENT HANGOVER A1 Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession By MATTHEW ROGNLIE, ANDREI SHLEIFER, AND ALP SIMSEK APPENDIX A: CALIBRATION This appendix describes

More information

Lecture 12. Estimation of Heterogeneous Agent Models. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall

Lecture 12. Estimation of Heterogeneous Agent Models. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall Lecture 12 Estimation of Heterogeneous Agent Models ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I Benjamin Moll Princeton University, Fall 216 1 Plan 1. Background: bringing heterogeneous agent models to data the

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu) ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 21 Consider the neoclassical economy without population growth and technological progress. The optimal growth

More information

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and Economics 210B Due: September 16, 2010 Problem 1: Constant returns to saving Consider the following problem. c0,k1,c1,k2,... β t Problem Set 10 1 α c1 α t s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations Banque de France Martin Guzman (Columbia-UBA) Joseph Stiglitz (Columbia) April 4, 2017 Motivation 1 Analytical puzzle from the perspective of DSGE models: Physical

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

1 With state-contingent debt

1 With state-contingent debt STOCKHOLM DOCTORAL PROGRAM IN ECONOMICS Helshögskolan i Stockholm Stockholms universitet Paul Klein Email: paul.klein@iies.su.se URL: http://paulklein.se/makro2.html Macroeconomics II Spring 2010 Lecture

More information

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley July 2013 1 1. MOTIVATION Controversy about proper level of inheritance taxation 1) Public

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market Daron Acemoglu MIT September 20, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Technology and the Labor Market September 20, 2016. 1 / 51 Technology

More information

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016 Christian Groth A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics February 15, 216 (3-hours closed book exam) 1 As formulated in the course description, a score of 12 is

More information

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) D(S)GE and Growth Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 43 Macroeconomics is Dynamic

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics Endogenous Growth Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Endogenous growth 1 / 18 Introduction The Solow and Ramsey models are exogenous growth

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 5, 2014 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 5, 2014 1 / 56 Growth

More information

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework Online Appendix to the paper Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework October 5, 2015 Part I: Maturity specific shocks in affine and equilibrium models This Appendix present

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Some Microfoundations for the Gatsby Curve. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin. Ananth Seshadri University of Wisconsin

Some Microfoundations for the Gatsby Curve. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin. Ananth Seshadri University of Wisconsin Some Microfoundations for the Gatsby Curve Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin Ananth Seshadri University of Wisconsin November 4, 2014 Presentation 1 changes have taken place in ghetto neighborhoods,

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Lecture 8. The Workhorse Model of Income and Wealth Distribution in Macroeconomics. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I.

Lecture 8. The Workhorse Model of Income and Wealth Distribution in Macroeconomics. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Lecture 8 The Workhorse Model of Income and Wealth Distribution in Macroeconomics ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I Benjamin Moll Princeton University, Fall 2016 1 Plan for rest of my part of course Only

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II)

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) ECO 503: Macroeconomic Theory I Benjamin Moll Princeton University Fall 204 /6 Plan of Lecture Sequence of markets CE 2 The growth model and

More information

B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication

B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication B.1 Derivation Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman This appendix proves that if v() is given by: v() = R(

More information

Housing with overlapping generations

Housing with overlapping generations Housing with overlapping generations Chiara Forlati, Michael Hatcher, Alessandro Mennuni University of Southampton Preliminary and Incomplete May 16, 2015 Abstract We study the distributional and efficiency

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Econ 50a second half) Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 7 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.. This problem introduces wealth inequality

More information

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Intertemporal equilibrium with production: bubbles and efficiency Stefano BOSI, Cuong LE VAN, Ngoc-Sang PHAM 2014.43 Maison des Sciences Économiques,

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Daron Acemoglu MIT September 12, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 3 September 12, 2007 1 / 40 Introduction

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information