Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection"

Transcription

1 Math. Financ. Econ. Vol. 11, No. 2, 2017, Research Report No. 14, 2013, Probab. Statist. Grop Manchester 26 pp Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection J. L. Pedersen & G. Peskir Assming that the wealth process X is generated self-financially from the given initial wealth by holding its fraction in a risky stock whose price follows a geometric Brownian motion with drift µ IR and volatility σ > 0 and its remaining fraction 1 in a riskless bond whose price componds exponentially with interest rate r IR, and letting P t,x denote a probability measre nder which X takes vale x at time t, we stdy the dynamic version of the nonlinear mean-variance optimal control problem sp E t,x t XT c Var t,x t XT where t rns from 0 to the given terminal time T > 0, the spremm is taken over admissible controls, and c > 0 is a given constant. By employing the method of Lagrange mltipliers we show that the nonlinear problem can be redced to a family of linear problems. Solving the latter sing a classic Hamilton-Jacobi- Bellman approach we find that the optimal dynamic control is given by t, x = δ 1 2 2cσ x eδ rt t where δ = µ r/σ. The dynamic formlation of the problem and the method of soltion are applied to the constrained problems of maximising/minimising the mean/variance sbject to the pper/lower bond on the variance/mean from which the nonlinear problem above is obtained by optimising the Lagrangian itself. 1. Introdction Imagine an investor who has an initial wealth which he wishes to exchange between a risky stock and a riskless bond in a self-financing manner dynamically in time so as to maximise his retrn and minimise his risk at the given terminal time. In line with the mean-variance analysis of Markowitz 11 where the optimal portfolio selection problem of this kind was solved in a single period model see e.g. Merton 12 and the references therein we will identify the retrn with the expectation of the terminal wealth and the risk with the variance of the terminal wealth. The qadratic nonlinearity of the variance then moves the reslting optimal control problem otside the scope of the standard optimal control theory see e.g. 5 which may be viewed as dynamic programming in the sense of solving the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman HJB eqation and obtaining an optimal control which remains optimal independently from the initial and hence any sbseqent vale of the wealth. Conseqently the reslts and methods Mathematics Sbject Classification Primary 60H30, 60J65. Secondary 49L20, 91G80. Key words and phrases: Nonlinear optimal control, static optimality, dynamic optimality, mean-variance analysis, the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman eqation, martingale, geometric Brownian motion, Markov process. 1

2 of the standard/linear optimal control theory are not directly applicable in this new/nonlinear setting. The prpose of the present paper is to develop a new methodology for solving nonlinear optimal control problems of this kind and demonstrate its se in the optimal mean-variance portfolio selection problem stated above. This is done in parallel to the novel methodology for solving nonlinear optimal stopping problems that was recently developed in 13 when tackling an optimal mean-variance selling problem. Assming that the stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion and the bond price componds exponentially, we first consider the constrained problem in which the investor aims to maximise the expectation of his terminal wealth XT over all admissible controls representing the fraction of the wealth held in the stock sch that the variance of XT is bonded above by a positive constant. Similarly the investor cold aim to minimise the variance of his terminal wealth XT over all admissible controls sch that the expectation of X T is bonded below by a positive constant. A first application of Lagrange mltipliers implies that the Lagrange fnction Lagrangian for either/both constrained problems can be expressed as a linear combination of the expectation of XT and the variance of X T with opposite signs. Optimisation of the Lagrangian over all admissible controls ths yields the central optimal control problem nder consideration. De to the qadratic nonlinearity of the variance we can no longer apply standard/linear reslts of the optimal control theory to solve the problem. Conditioning on the size of the expectation we show that a second application of Lagrange mltipliers redces the nonlinear optimal control problem to a family of linear optimal control problems. Solving the latter sing a classic HJB approach we find that the optimal control depends on the initial point of the controlled wealth process in an essential way. This spatial inconsistency introdces a time inconsistency in the problem that in trn raises the qestion whether the optimality obtained is adeqate for practical prposes. We refer to this optimality as the static optimality Definition 1 to distingish it from the dynamic optimality Definition 2 in which each new position of the controlled wealth process yields a new optimal control problem to be solved pon overrling all the past problems. This in effect corresponds to solving infinitely many optimal control problems dynamically in time with the aim of determining the optimal control in the sense that no other control applied at present time cold prodce a more favorable vale at the terminal time. While the static optimality has been sed in the paper by Strotz 21 nder the name of pre-commitment as far as we know the dynamic optimality has not been stdied in the nonlinear setting of optimal control before. In Section 4 below we give a more detailed accont of the mean-variance reslts and methods on the static optimality starting with the paper by Richardson 19. Optimal controls in all these papers are time inconsistent in the sense described above. This line of papers ends with the paper by Basak and Chabakari 1 where a time-consistent control is derived that corresponds to the Strotz s approach of consistent planning 21 realised as the sbgame-perfect Nash eqilibrim the optimality concept refining Nash eqilibrim proposed by Selten in We show that the dynamic formlation of the nonlinear optimal control problem admits a simple closed-form soltion Theorem 3 in which the optimal control no longer depends on the initial point of the controlled wealth process and hence is time consistent. Remarkably we also verify that this control yields the expected terminal vale which i coincides with the expected terminal vale obtained by the statically optimal control Remark 4 and moreover ii dominates the expected terminal vale obtained by the sbgame-perfect Nash eqilibrim control in the sense of Strotz s consistent planning derived in 1 Section 4. Closed-form 2

3 soltions to the constrained problems are then derived sing the soltion to the nconstrained problem Corollaries 5 and 7. These reslts are of both theoretical and practical interest. In the first problem we note that the optimal wealth exhibits a dynamic compliance effect Remark 6 and in the second problem we observe that the optimal wealth solves a meander type eqation of independent interest Remark 8. In both problems we verify that the expected terminal vale obtained by the dynamically optimal control dominates the expected terminal vale obtained by the statically optimal control. The novel problems and methodology of the present paper sggest a nmber of avenes for frther research. Firstly, we work within the transparent setting of one-dimensional geometric Brownian motion in order to illstrate the main ideas and describe the new methodology withot nnecessary technical complications. Extending the reslts to higher dimensions and more general diffsion/markov processes appears to be worthy of frther consideration. Secondly, for similar tractability reasons we assme that i nlimited short-selling and borrowing are permitted, ii transaction costs are zero, iii the wealth process may take both positive and negative vales of nlimited size. Extending the reslts nder some of these constraints being imposed is also worthy of frther consideration. In both of these settings it is interesting to examine to what extent the reslts and methods laid down in the present paper remain valid nder any of these more general or restrictive hypotheses. 2. Formlation of the problem Assme that the riskless bond price B solves 2.1 db t = rb t dt with B 0 = b for some b > 0 where r IR is the interest rate, and let the risky stock price S follow a geometric Brownian motion solving 2.2 ds t = µs t dt + σs t dw t with S 0 = s for some s > 0 where µ IR is the drift, σ > 0 is the volatility, and W is a standard Brownian motion defined on a probability space Ω, F, P. Note that a niqe soltion to 2.1 is given by B t = be rt and recall that a niqe strong soltion to 2.2 is given by S t = s expσw t +µ σ 2 /2t for t 0. Consider the investor who has an initial wealth x 0 IR which he wishes to exchange between B and S in a self-financing manner with no exogenos infsion or withdrawal of wealth dynamically in time p to the given horizon T > 0. It is then well known see e.g. 2, Chapter 6 that the investor s wealth X solves 2.3 dx t = r1 t +µ t X t dt + σ t X t dw t with X = x 0 where t denotes the fraction of the investor s wealth held in the stock at time t, T for 0, T given and fixed. Note that i t < 0 corresponds to short selling of the stock, ii t > 1 corresponds to borrowing from the bond, and iii t 0, 1 corresponds to a long position in both the stock and the bond. To simplify the exposition we will assme that the control in 2.3 is given by t = t, X t where t, x t, x x is a continos fnction from 0, T IR into IR for which 3

4 the stochastic differential eqation 2.3 nderstood in Itô s sense has a niqe strong soltion X meaning that the soltion X to 2.3 is adapted to the natral filtration of W and if X is another soltion to 2.3 of this kind then X and X are eqal almost srely. We will call controls of this kind admissible in the seqel. Recalling that the natral filtration of S coincides with the natral filtration of W we see that admissible controls have a natral financial interpretation as they are obtained as deterministic measrable fnctionals of the observed stock price. Moreover, adopting the convention that t, 0 0 := lim 0 x 0 t, x x we see that the soltion X to 2.3 cold take both positive and/or negative vales after passing throgh zero when the latter limit is different from zero as is the case in the main reslts below. This convention corresponds to re-expressing 2.3 in terms of the total wealth t Xt held in the stock as opposed to its fraction t which we follow throghot note that the essence of the wealth eqation 2.3 remains the same in both cases. We do always identify t, 0 with t, 0 0 however since x t, x may not be well defined a. Note that the reslts to be presented below also hold if the set of admissible controls is enlarged to inclde discontinos and path dependent controls that are adapted to the natral filtration of W, or even controls which are adapted to a larger filtration still making W a martingale so that 2.3 has a niqe weak soltion X meaning that the soltion X to 2.3 is adapted to the larger filtration and if X is another soltion to 2.3 of this kind then X and X are eqal in law. Since these extensions follow along the same lines and needed modifications of the argments are evident, we will omit frther details in this direction and focs on the set of admissible controls as defined above. For a given admissible control we let P t,x denote the probability measre defined on the canonical space nder which the soltion X to 2.3 takes vale x at time t for t, x 0, T IR. Note that X is a strong Markov process with respect to P t,x for t, x 0, T IR. Consider the optimal control problem 2.4 V t, x = sp Et,x X T c Var t,x X T where the spremm is taken over all admissible controls sch that E t,x XT 2 < for t, x 0, T IR and c > 0 is a given and fixed constant. A sfficient condition for the latter T expectation to be finite is that E t,x t 1+2 sxs 2 ds < and we will assme in the seqel that all admissible controls by definition satisfy that condition as well. De to the qadratic nonlinearity of the second term in the expression Var t,x XT = E t,x XT 2 E t,x XT 2 it is evident that the problem 2.4 falls otside the scope of the standard/linear optimal control theory for Markov processes see e.g. 5. Moreover, we will see below that in addition to the static formlation of the nonlinear problem 2.4 where the maximisation takes place relative to the initial point t, x which is given and fixed, one is also natrally led to consider a dynamic formlation of the nonlinear problem 2.4 in which each new position of the controlled process t, Xt t 0,T yields a new optimal control problem to be solved pon overrling all the past problems. We believe that this dynamic optimality is of general interest in the nonlinear problems of optimal control as well as nonlinear problems of optimal stopping as discssed in 13. The problem 2.4 seeks to maximise the investor s retrn identified with the expectation of XT and minimise the investor s risk identified with the variance of X T pon applying the 4

5 control. This identification is done in line with the mean-variance analysis of Markowitz 11. Moreover, we will see in the proof below that the problem 2.4 is obtained by optimising the Lagrangian of the constrained problems V 1 t, x = V 2 t, x = sp E t,x X : Var t,xxt α T inf Var t,xx : E t,x XT β T respectively, where is any admissible control, and α 0, and β IR are given and fixed constants. Solving 2.4 we will therefore be able to solve 2.5 and 2.6 as well. Note that the constrained problems have transparent interpretations in terms of the investor s retrn and the investor s risk as discssed above. We now formalise definitions of the optimalities allded to above. Recall that all controls throghot refer to admissible controls as defined/discssed above. Definition 1 Static optimality. A control is statically optimal in 2.4 for t, x 0, T IR given and fixed, if there is no other control v sch that 2.7 E t,x X v T c Var t,x X v T > E t,x X T c Var t,xx T. A control is statically optimal in 2.5 for t, x 0, T IR given and fixed, if Var t,x X T α and there is no other control v satisfying Var t,x XT v α sch that 2.8 E t,x X v T > E t,x X T. A control is statically optimal in 2.6 for t, x 0, T IR given and fixed, if E t,x X T β and there is no other control v satisfying E t,x XT v β sch that 2.9 Var t,x X v T < Var t,x X T. Note that the static optimality refers to the optimality relative to the initial point t, x which is given and fixed. Changing the initial point may yield a different optimal control in the nonlinear problems since the statically optimal controls may and generally will depend on the initial point in an essential way cf. 21. This stands in sharp contrast with standard/linear problems of optimal control where in view of dynamic programming the HJB eqation the optimal control does not depend on the initial point explicitly. This is a key difference between the static optimality in nonlinear problems of optimal control and the standard optimality in linear problems of optimal control cf. 5. Definition 2 Dynamic optimality. A control is dynamically optimal in 2.4, if for every given and fixed t, x 0, T IR and every control v sch that vt, x t, x, there exists a control w satisfying wt, x = t, x sch that 2.10 E t,x X w T c Var t,x X w T > E t,x X v T c Var t,x X v T. A control is dynamically optimal in 2.5, if for every given and fixed t, x 0, T IR and every control v sch that vt, x t, x with Var t,x XT v α, there exists a control w satisfying wt, x = t, x with Var t,x XT w α sch that 2.11 E t,x X w T > E t,x X v T. 5

6 A control is dynamically optimal in 2.6, if for every given and fixed t, x 0, T IR and every control v sch that vt, x t, x with E t,x XT v β, there exists a control w satisfying wt, x = t, x with E t,x XT w β sch that 2.12 Var t,x X w T < Var t,x X v T. Dynamic optimality above is nderstood in the strong sense. Replacing the strict ineqalities in by ineqalities wold yield dynamic optimality in the weak sense. Note that the dynamic optimality corresponds to solving infinitely many optimal control problems dynamically in time where each new position of the controlled process t, Xt t 0,T yields a new optimal control problem to be solved pon overrling all the past problems. The optimal decision at each time tells s to exert the best control among all possible controls. While the static optimality remembers the past throgh the initial point the dynamic optimality completely ignores it and only looks ahead. Nonetheless it is clear that there is a strong link between the static and dynamic optimality the latter being formed throgh the beginnings of the former as shown below and this will be exploited in the proof below when searching for the dynamically optimal controls. In the case of standard/linear optimal control problems for Markov processes it is evident that the static and dynamic optimality coincide nder mild reglarity conditions de to the fact that dynamic programming the HJB eqation is applicable. This is not the case for the nonlinear problems of optimal control considered in the present paper as it will be seen below. 3. Soltion to the problem In this section we present soltions to the problems formlated in the previos section. We first focs on the nconstrained problem. Theorem 3. Consider the optimal control problem 2.4 where X solves 2.3 with X = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed. Recall that B solves 2.1, S solves 2.2, and we set δ = µ r/σ for µ IR, r IR and σ > 0. We assme throghot that δ 0 and r 0 the cases δ = 0 or r = 0 follow by passage to the limit when the non-zero δ or r tends to 0. A The statically optimal control is given by 3.1 s t, x = δ σ 1 x x 0 e rt x + 1 2c eδ2 T rt t for t, x, T IR. The statically optimal controlled process is given by Xt s = x 0 e rt t0 + 1 rt t 2c eδ2 e δ2 t t e δwt W δ2 2 t = x 0 B t B t c Bt 1 δ2/r Bt δ2/r Bt δ1/σ+δ σ/2r St δ/σ B T B t0 B t0 S t0 for t, T. The static vale fnction V s := EXT s c VarXs T is given by 3.3 V s, x 0 = x 0 e rt t0 + 1 e δ2 T 1 4c 6

7 for, x 0 0, T IR. B The dynamically optimal control is given by 3.4 d t, x = δ 2cσ 1 x eδ2 rt t for t, x, T IR. The dynamically optimal controlled process is given by Xt d = x 0 e rt t0 + 1 t rt t 2c eδ2 e δ2 t t δ e δ2 t s dw s B t = x 0 + δ Bt 1 δ2/r σ 2 2r Bt δ2/r 1 B t0 2cσ B T 2δ 2 B t0 St + log S t0 + δ 2 t Bt δ2/r Ss log ds B s S t0 for t, T. The dynamic vale fnction V d := EXT d c VarXd T is given by 3.6 V d, x 0 = x 0 e rt t0 + 1 e δ2 T 1 T 4 2c e2δ2 3 4 for, x 0 0, T IR. Proof. We assme throghot that the process X solves the stochastic differential eqation 2.3 with Xt 0 = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed where is any admissible control as defined/discssed above. To simplify the notation we will drop the sbscript zero from and x 0 in the first part of the proof below. A: Note that the objective fnction in 2.4 reads 3.7 E t,x X T c Var t,x X T = E t,x X T + c E t,x X T 2 c Et,x X T 2 where the key difficlty is the qadratic nonlinearity of the middle term on the right-hand side. To overcome this difficlty we will condition on the size of E t,x XT. This yields 3.8 V t, x = sp M IR = sp sp Et,x X : E t,xxt =M T c Var t,x XT sp M IR : E t,xxt =M = sp M IR E t,x X T + c E t,x X T 2 c Et,x X T 2 M + cm 2 c inf E t,x X T 2. : E t,x XT =M Hence to solve 3.8 and ths 2.4 we need to solve the constrained problem 3.9 V M t, x = inf E : E t,x XT =M t,x X T 2 for M IR given and fixed where is any admissible control. 7

8 1. To tackle the problem 3.9 we will apply the method of Lagrange mltipliers. For this, define the Lagrangian as follows 3.10 L t,x, λ = E t,x X T 2 λ E t,x X T M for λ IR and let λ denote the optimal control in the nconstrained problem 3.11 L t,x λ, λ := inf L t,x, λ pon assming that it exists. Sppose moreover that there is λ=λm, t, x IR sch that 3.12 E t,x X λ T = M. It then follows from that 3.13 E t,x X λ 2 T = Lt,x λ, λ E t,x X T 2 for any admissible control sch that E t,x X T = M. This shows that λ satisfying 3.11 and 3.12 is optimal in To tackle the problem 3.11 with 3.12 we consider the optimal control problem 3.14 V λ t, x = inf E t,x X T 2 λxt where is any admissible control. This is a standard/linear problem of optimal control see e.g. 5 that can be solved sing a classic HJB approach. For the sake of completeness we present key steps in the derivation of the soltion. From 3.14 combined with 2.3 we see that the HJB system reads inf IR Vt λ + r1 +µ xvx λ σ2 2 x 2 Vxx λ V λ T, x = x 2 λx = 0 on 0, T IR. Making the ansatz that V λ xx > 0 and minimising the qadratic fnction of over IR in 3.15 we find that 3.17 = δ σ 1 x Inserting 3.17 back into 3.15 yields 3.18 V λ t Vx λ. Vxx λ + rxv λ x δ2 2 Seeking the soltion to 3.18 of the form V λ x 2 V λ xx = V λ t, x = atx 2 + btx + ct 8

9 and making se of 3.16 we find that 3.20 a t = δ 2 2rat & b t = δ 2 rbt & c t = δ2 4 b 2 t at on 0, T with at = 1, bt = λ and ct = 0. Solving 3.20 nder these terminal conditions we obtain at = e δ2 2rT t & bt = λe δ2 rt t & ct = λ2 1 e δ2 T t Inserting 3.21 into 3.19 and calclating 3.17 we find that 3.22 t, x = δ σ 1 x λ x 2 e rt t. Applying Itô s formla to the process Z defined by 3.23 Z t = K e rt X t where we set K := λ/2e rt and making se of 2.3 we find that 3.24 dz t = δ 2 Z t dt δz t dw t with Z t0 = K x 0 nder P t0,x 0. Solving the linear eqation 3.24 explicitly we obtain the following closed form expression 3.25 Xt = e rt K K x 0 e δw t W t0 3δ2 2 t for t, T. The process X defined by 3.25 is a niqe strong soltion to the stochastic differential eqation 2.3 obtained by the control from 3.22 and yielding the vale fnction V λ given in 3.19 combined with 3.21 above. It is then a matter of rotine to apply Itô s formla to V λ composed with t, Xt v for any admissible control v and sing verify that the candidate control from 3.22 is optimal in 3.14 as envisaged these argments are displayed more explicitly in below. 3. Having solved the problem 3.14 we still need to meet the condition For this, we find from 3.25 that 3.26 E t0,x 0 X T = x0 e δ2 rt + λ 2 1 e δ2 T. To realise 3.12 we need to identify 3.26 with M. This yields 3.27 λ = 2 M x 0e δ2 rt 1 e δ2 T for δ 0. Note that the case δ = 0 is evident since in this case λ = 0 is optimal in 3.14 for every λ IR and hence the ineqality in 3.13 holds for every admissible control while from 2.3 we also easily see that 3.26 with δ = 0 holds for every admissible control so 9

10 that we only have one M possible in 3.8 and that is the one given by 3.26 with δ = 0. This shows that are valid when δ = 0 and we will therefore assme in the seqel that δ 0. Moreover, from 3.25 we also find that 3.28 E t0,x 0 X T 2 = x 2 0 e δ2 2rT + λ2 1 e δ2 T. 4 Note that this expression can also be obtained from 3.14 and 3.26 pon recalling 3.19 with 3.21 above. Inserting 3.27 into 3.28 and recalling 3.13 we see that 3.9 is given by 3.29 V M, x 0 = x 2 0 e δ2 2rT + for δ 0. Inserting 3.29 into 3.8 we get M x0 e δ2 rt 2 1 e δ2 T 3.30 V, x 0 = sp M + cm 2 c x 2 0 e δ2 2rT M x0 e δ2 rt 2 + M IR 1 e δ2 T for δ 0. Note that the fnction of M to be maximised on the right-hand side is qadratic with the coefficient in front of M 2 strictly negative when δ 0. This shows that there exists a niqe maximm point in 3.30 that is easily fond to be given by 3.31 M = x 0 e rt + 1 2c Inserting 3.31 into 3.27 we find that e δ2 T λ = 2x 0 e rt + 1 c eδ2 T. Inserting 3.32 into 3.22 we establish the existence of the optimal control in 2.4 that is given by 3.1 above. Moreover, inserting 3.32 into 3.25 we obtain the first identity in 3.2. The second identity in 3.2 then follows pon recalling the closed form expressions for B and S stated following 2.2 above. Finally, inserting 3.31 into 3.30 we obtain 3.3 and this completes the first part of the proof. B: Identifying with t and x 0 with x in the statically optimal control s from 3.1 we obtain the control d from 3.4. We claim that this control is dynamically optimal in 2.4. For this, take any other admissible control v sch that v, x 0 d, x 0 and set w = s. Then w, x 0 = d, x 0 and we claim that 3.33 V w, x 0 := E t0,x 0 X w T c Var t0,x 0 X w T > E t0,x 0 X v T c Var t0,x 0 X v T =: V v, x 0 pon noting that V w, x 0 eqals V, x 0 since w is statically optimal in 2.4. M 4. To verify 3.33 set M v := E t0,x 0 XT v and first consider the case when M v M where is given by 3.31 above. Using and we then find that 3.34 V v, x 0 = M v + cm 2 v c E t0,x 0 X v T 2 M v + cm 2 v cv Mv, x 0 10

11 M v + cmv 2 c x 2 0 e δ2 2rT Mv x 0 e δ2 rt e δ2 T < M + cm 2 c x 2 0 e δ2 2rT M x 0 e δ2 rt e δ2 T = V w, x 0 for δ 0 where the strict ineqality follows since M is the niqe maximm point of the qadratic fnction as pointed ot following 3.30 above. The case δ = 0 is exclded since then as pointed ot following 3.27 above we only have M possible in 3.8 so that M v wold be eqal to M. This shows that 3.33 is satisfied when M v M as claimed. Next consider the case when M v = M. We then claim that 3.35 V λ v t, x := E t0,x 0 X v T 2 λ X v T > V λ, x 0 where V λ is defined in 3.14 and λ is given by 3.32 above. For this, note that sing 3.16 and applying Itô s formla we get 3.36 XT v 2 λ XT v = V λ T, XT v = V λ, x 0 T + Vt λ s, Xs v + r 1 vs, Xs v +µvs, Xs v Xs v Vx λ s, Xs v σ2 v 2 s, Xs v Xs v 2 Vxx λ s, Xs v ds + M T where M t := t σ vs, Xs v Xs v Vx λ s, Xs v dw s is a continos local martingale nder P t0,x 0 T for t, T. Using that E t0,x 0 1+vt 2 Xt v 2 dt < it is easily seen from 2.3 by means of Jensen s and Brkholder-Davis-Gndy s ineqalities that E t0,x 0 max t0 t T Xt v 2 < and hence pon recalling above with λ in place of λ it follows by Hölder s ineqality that E t0,x 0 M, M T < so that M is a martingale. Taking E t0,x 0 on both sides of 3.36 we therefore get 3.37 V λ v t, x = V λ, x 0 T + E t0,x 0 V λ t s, Xs v + r 1 vs, Xs v +µvs, Xs v Xs v Vx λ s, Xs v ds σ2 v 2 s, X v s X v s 2 V λ xx s, X v s where the integrand is non-negative de to 3.15 with λ in place of λ. Since d, x 0 = s, x 0 and v, x 0 d, x 0 we see that v, x 0 w, x 0. Assming x 0 0 by the continity of v and w it then follows that vs, x ws, x for all s, x R ε :=, +ε x 0 ε, x 0 +ε for some ε > 0 small enogh sch that +ε T as well. Moreover, since wt, x is the niqe minimm point of the continos fnction on the left-hand side of 3.15 with λ in place of λ evalated at t, x for every t, x 0, T IR, we see that this ε > 0 can be chosen small enogh so that 3.38 V λ t + r1 v+µv xv λ x σ2 v 2 x 2 V λ xx β > 0 11

12 on R ε for some β > 0 given and fixed. Setting τ ε := inf { s, +ε s, Xs v / R ε } we see by 3.37 and 3.38 that 3.39 V λ v t, x V λ, x 0 + β E t0,x 0 τ ε > V λ, x 0 where in the first ineqality we se that the integrand in 3.37 is non-negative as pointed ot above and in the final strict ineqality we se that τ ε > with P t0,x 0 -probability one de to the continity of X v. The argments remain also valid when x 0 = 0 pon recalling that v, 0 and w, 0 are identified with v, 0 0 and w, 0 0 in this case. From 3.39 we see that 3.35 holds as claimed. Recalling from that V λ, x 0 = V M, x 0 λ M as well as that M v = M by hypothesis we see from 3.35 that 3.40 E t0,x 0 X v T 2 > V M, x 0. It follows therefore from 3.8 that 3.41 V w, x 0 = M + cm 2 cv M, x 0 > M + cm 2 c E t0,x 0 X v T 2 = E t0,x 0 X v T c Var t0,x 0 X v T = V v, x 0. This shows that 3.33 holds when M v = M as well and hence we can conclde that the control d from 3.4 is dynamically optimal as claimed. 5. Applying Itô s formla to e rt t X d t where we set X d := X d and making se of 2.3 we easily find that the first identity in 3.5 is satisfied. Integrating by parts and recalling the closed form expressions for B and S stated following 2.2 above we then establish that the second identity in 3.5 also holds. From the first identity in 3.5 we get E t0,x 0 X d T = x0 e rt t0 + 1 e δ2 T 1 2c Var t0,x 0 XT d = 1 e 2δ2 T 1. 8c 2 From 3.42 and 3.43 we obtain 3.6 and this completes the proof. Remark 4. The dynamically optimal control d from 3.4 by its natre rejects any past point, x 0 to measre its performance so that althogh the static vale V s, x 0 by its definition dominates the dynamic vale V d, x 0 this comparison is meaningless from the standpoint of the dynamic optimality. Another isse with a plain comparison of the vales V s t, x and V d t, x for t, x, T IR is that the optimally controlled processes X s and X d may never come to the same point x at the same time t so that the comparison itself may be nreal. A more dynamic way that also makes more sense in general is to compare the vale fnctions composed with the controlled processes. This amonts to look at V s t, Xt s and V d t, Xt d for t, T and pay particlar attention to t becoming the terminal vale T. Note that V s T, XT s = Xs T and V dt, XT d = Xd T so that to compare E,x 0 Vs T, XT s and E t0,x 0 Vd T, XT d is the same as to compare E t0,x 0 XT s and E,x 0 XT d. It is easily seen from 3.2 and 3.5 that the latter two expectations coincide. We can therefore conclde that 12

13 3.44 E t0,x 0 Vs T, X s T = E t0,x 0 X s T = E t0,x 0 X d T = E t0,x 0 Vd T, X d T for all, x 0 0, T IR. This shows that the dynamically optimal control d is as good as the statically optimal control s from this static standpoint as well with respect to any past point, x 0 given and fixed. In addition to that however the dynamically optimal control d is time consistent while the statically optimal control s is not. Note also from 3.4 that the amont of the dynamically optimal wealth d t, x x held in the stock at time t does not depend on the amont of the total wealth x. This is consistent with the fact that the risk/cost in 2.4 is measred by the variance applied at a constant rate c which is a qadratic fnction of the terminal wealth while the retrn/gain is measred by the expectation applied at a constant rate too which is a linear fnction of the terminal wealth. The former therefore penalises stochastic movements of the large wealth more severely than what the latter is able to compensate for and the investor is discoraged to hold larger amonts of his wealth in the stock. Ths even if the total wealth is large in modls it is still dynamically optimal to hold the same amont of wealth d t, x x in the stock at time t as when the total wealth is small in modls. The same optimality behavior has been also observed for the sbgame-perfect Nash eqilibrim controls cf. Section 4. We now trn to the constrained problems. Note in the proofs below that the nconstrained problem above is obtained by optimising the Lagrangian of the constrained problems. Corollary 5. Consider the optimal control problem 2.5 where X solves 2.3 with X = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed. Recall that B solves 2.1, S solves 2.2, and we set δ = µ r/σ for µ IR, r IR and σ > 0. We assme throghot that δ 0 and r 0 the cases δ = 0 or r = 0 follow by passage to the limit when the non-zero δ or r tends to 0. A The statically optimal control is given by 3.45 s t, x = δ σ 1 x x 0 e rt t0 x + T rt t α eδ2 e δ 2 T 1 for t, x, T IR. The statically optimal controlled process is given by 3.46 X s t = x 0 e rt + α = x 0 B t B t0 + rt t eδ2 e δ2 t e δw t W t0 δ2 2 t e δ 2 T 1 α BT δ 2 /r B t0 1 for t, T. The static vale fnction V 1 s 3.47 V 1 s, x 0 = x 0 e rt + α for, x 0 0, T IR. Bt 1 δ2/r Bt δ2/r Bt δ1/σ+δ σ/2r St δ/σ B T B t0 B t0 S t0 := EXT s is given by 13 e δ2 T 1

14 B The dynamically optimal control is given by 3.48 d t, x = α δ σ 1 x e δ2 rt t e δ 2 T t 1 for t, x, T IR. The dynamically optimal controlled process is given by 3.49 X d t = x 0 e rt t0 + 2 α e rt t e δ2 T 1 e δ2 T t 1 + δ 2 = x 0 B t B t0 + δ α B t 2r+δ1 σ σ 2 BT σ B T δ 2 BT δ 2 /r B + t St t BT log + δ2 BT δ 2 /r S B t 1 t0 2 t e δ2t s e δ 2 T s 1 dw s B t δ2/r 1 B s δ2/r BT δ2/r 1 B t0 BT B s δ 2 /r 2 BT B s δ 2 /r 1 3/2 log Ss S t0 ds for t, T. The dynamic vale fnction V 1 d 3.50 V 1 d, x 0 = x 0 e rt + 2 α for, x 0 0, T IR. := lim t T EXt d is given by e δ2 T 1 Proof. We assme throghot that the process X solves the stochastic differential eqation 2.3 with Xt 0 = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed where is any admissible control as defined/discssed above. To simplify the notation we will drop the sbscript zero from and x 0 in the first part of the proof below. A: Note that we can think of 3.7 as the essential part of the Lagrangian for the constrained problem 2.5 defined by 3.51 L t,x, c = E t,x X T c Var t,x X T α for c > 0. By the reslt of Theorem 3 we know that the control s in nconstrained problem given in 3.1 is optimal 3.52 L t,x c, c := sp L t,x, c for c > 0. Sppose moreover that there exists c = cα, t, x > 0 sch that 3.53 Var t,x X c T = α. It then follows that 3.54 E t,x X c T = L t,x c, c E t,x X T c Var t,x X T α E t,x X T for any admissible control sch that Var t,x XT α. This shows that the control c 3.1 with c = cα, t, x > 0 is statically optimal in 2.5. from 14

15 To realise 3.53 note that taking E t0,x 0 in 3.2 and making se of 3.3 we find that 3.55 Var t0,x 0 X c 1 T = e δ2 T 1. 4c 2 Setting this expression eqal to α yields 3.56 c = 1 2 e α δ2 T 1. By 3.53 and 3.54 we can then conclde that the control c is statically optimal in 2.5. Inserting 3.56 into 3.1 and 3.2 we obtain 3.45 and 3.46 respectively. Taking E t0,x 0 in 3.46 we obtain 3.47 and this completes the first part of the proof. B: Identifying with t and x 0 with x in the statically optimal control s from 3.45 we obtain the control d from We claim that this control is dynamically optimal in 2.5. For this, take any other admissible control v sch that v, x 0 d, x 0 and set w = s. Then w, x 0 = d, x 0 and 3.33 holds with c from Using that Var t0,x 0 XT w = α by 3.55 and 3.56 we see that 3.33 yields 3.57 E t0,x 0 X w T > E t0,x 0 X v T + c α Var t0,x 0 X v T E t0,x 0 X v T whenever Var t0,x 0 XT v α. This shows that the control d from 3.48 is dynamically optimal in 2.5 as claimed. Applying Itô s formla to e rt t Xt d where we set X d := X d and making se of 2.3 we easily find that the first identity in 3.49 is satisfied. Integrating by parts and recalling the closed form expressions for B and S stated following 2.2 above we then establish that the second identity in 3.49 also holds. From the first identity in 3.49 we get E t0,x 0 X d t = x0 e rt t α e e rt t δ2 T 1 e δ2 T t 1 for t, T. Letting t T in 3.58 we obtain 3.50 and this completes the proof. Remark 6 A dynamic compliance effect. From 3.47 and 3.50 we see that the dynamic vale Vd 1t 0, x 0 strictly dominates the static vale Vs 1, x 0. To see why this is possible note that sing 3.49 we find that 3.59 Var t0,x 0 X d t = α e 2rT t e δ2 T e δ2 T t +log e δ 2 T 1 e δ2 T t 1 for t, T with δ 0. This shows that Var t0,x 0 Xt d as t T so that the static vale Vs 1, x 0 can indeed be exceeded by the dynamic vale Vd 1t 0, x 0 since the set of admissible controls is virtally larger in the dynamic case. It amonts to what we refer to as a dynamic compliance effect where the investor follows a niformly bonded risk variance strategy at each time and ths complies with the adopted reglation rle imposed internally/externally while the reslting static strategy exhibits an nbonded risk variance. Denoting the stochastic integral martingale in 3.49 by M t we see that M, M t = t e 2δ2 T s /e 2δ2 T s 1 ds as t T. It follows therefore that M t oscillates from to with P t0,x 0 -probability one 15

16 as t T and hence the same is tre for Xt d whenever δ 0 for similar behavior arising from the continos-time analoge of a dobling strategy see 9, Example 2.3. We also see from 3.46 and 3.49 that nlike in 3.44 we have the strict ineqality 3.60 lim E t0,x 0 V 1 s t, Xt s = lim E t0,x 0 Xt s < lim E t0,x 0 Xt d = lim E t0,x 0 V 1 d t, Xt d t T t T t T t T satisfied for all, x 0 0, T IR. This shows that the dynamic control d from 3.48 otperforms the static control s from 3.45 in the constrained problem 2.5. Corollary 7. Consider the optimal control problem 2.6 where X solves 2.3 with X = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed. Recall that B solves 2.1, S solves 2.2, and we set δ = µ r/σ for µ IR, r IR and σ > 0. We assme throghot that δ 0 and r 0 the cases δ = 0 or r = 0 follow by passage to the limit when the non-zero δ or r tends to 0. A The statically optimal control is given by 3.61 s t, x = δ σ 1 x x 0 e rt t0 x + β x 0 e rt t e 0 δ2 T rt t e δ2 T 1 if x 0 e rt < β and s t, x = 0 if x 0 e rt β for t, x, T IR. The statically optimal controlled process is given by 3.62 X s t = x 0 e rt + β x 0 e rt e δ2 rt t e δ2 T 1 e δ2 t e δwt W δ2 2 t B t B Bt 1 δ 2 /r T B = x 0 + β x T Bt δ2/r Bt δ1/σ+δ σ/2r St δ/σ 0 B t0 B BT δ 2 /r t0 B t0 1 B t0 B t0 S t0 if x 0 e rt t0 < β and Xt s = x 0 e rt if x 0 e rt t0 β for t, T see Figre 1 below. The static vale fnction Vs 2 := VarXT s is given by β x0 e rt V 2 s, x 0 = e δ2 T 1 if x 0 e rt < β and V 2 s, x 0 = 0 if x 0 e rt β for, x 0 0, T IR. B The dynamically optimal control is given by 3.64 d t, x = δ σ 1 β xe rt t e δ2 rt t x e δ2 T t 1 if x 0 e rt < β and d t, x = 0 if x 0 e rt β for t, x, T IR. The dynamically optimal controlled process is given by 3.65 X d t = e rt t β β x 0 e rt e δ2 T t 1 e δ2 T 1 16

17 = B t B T + δ3 σ t e δ2t s exp δ e δ2 T s 1 dw s δ2 2 β β x 0 B T B t0 t BT B t δ 2 /r 1 BT B t0 δ 2 /r 1 BT δ 2 /r B s Ss BT δ 2 /r 2 log ds 1 B s 1 S t0 2 t e 2δ2T s e δ2 T s 1 ds 2 1/2+σ/2δ r/σδ exp δ σ BT δ 2 /r B t0 BT δ 2 /r B t BT δ 2 /r B t 1 BT δ 2 /r B t0 1 BT δ 2 /r B t St BT δ log 2 /r B t 1 S t0 with Xt d e rt t < β for t, T and XT d := lim t T Xt d = β with P t0,x 0 -probability one if x 0 e rt t0 < β, and Xt d = x 0 e rt for t, T if x 0 e rt t0 β see Figre 1 below. The dynamic vale fnction Vd 2 := VarXd T is given by 3.66 V 2 d, x 0 = 0 for, x 0 0, T IR. Proof. We assme throghot that the process X solves the stochastic differential eqation 2.3 with Xt 0 = x 0 nder P t0,x 0 for, x 0 0, T IR given and fixed where is any admissible control as defined/discssed above. To simplify the notation we will drop the sbscript zero from and x 0 in the first part of the proof below. A: Note that the Lagrangian for the constrained problem 2.6 is defined by 3.67 L t,x, c = Var t,x X T c E t,x X T β for c > 0. To connect to the reslts of Theorem 3 observe that 3.68 inf Var t,x XT c E t,x XT β = c sp E t,x XT 1 c Var t,xxt + cβ which shows that the control 1/c given in 3.1 is optimal in the nconstrained problem 3.69 L t,x 1/c, c := inf L t,x, c for c > 0. Sppose moreover that there exists c = cβ, t, x > 0 sch that 3.70 E t,x X 1/c T = β. It then follows that 3.71 Var t,x X T = L t,x 1/c, c Var t,x X T c E t,x X T β Var t,x X T for any admissible control sch that E t,x XT 3.1 with c = cβ, t, x > 0 is statically optimal in 2.6. To realise 3.70 note that taking E t0,x 0 in 3.2 we find that 3.72 E t0,x 0 X 1/c T = x0 e rt t0 + c e δ2 T 1. 2 β. This shows that the control 1/c from 17

18 Setting this expression eqal to β yields 3.73 c = 2β x 0e rt e δ2 T 1 From 3.73 we see that c > 0 if and only if x 0 e rt t0 < β. If x 0 e rt t0 β then clearly we can invest all the wealth in B and receive zero variance at T. This shows that the control s t, x = 0 for t, x, T IR is statically optimal in this case with Vs 2, x 0 = 0 as claimed. Let s therefore assme that x 0 e rt t0 < β in the seqel. Then by 3.70 and 3.71 we can conclde that the control 1/c is statically optimal in 2.6. Inserting 3.73 into 3.1 and 3.2 we obtain 3.61 and 3.62 respectively. Inserting 3.73 into 3.55 we obtain 3.63 and this completes the first part of the proof. B: Identifying with t and x 0 with x in the statically optimal control s from 3.61 we obtain the control d from We claim that this control is dynamically optimal in 2.6 when x 0 e rt t0 < β. For this, take any other admissible control v sch that v, x 0 d, x 0 and set w = s. Then w, x 0 = d, x 0 and 3.33 holds with c from Using that E t0,x 0 XT w = β by 3.72 and 3.73 we see that 3.33 yields 3.74 Var t0,x 0 XT w < 1 β E t0,x c 0 XT v + c Var t0,x 0 XT v Var t0,x 0 XT v whenever E t0,x 0 XT v β. This shows that the control d from 3.64 is dynamically optimal in 2.6 when x 0 e rt t0 < β as claimed. If x 0 e rt t0 β then both s t, x = 0 and d t, x = 0 so that by 2.3 we see that Xt d := X d t = x 0 e rt for t, T as claimed. Dynamic optimality then follows from the fact singled ot in Remark 9 below that zero control is the only possible admissible control that can move a given deterministic wealth x 0 at time 0, T to another deterministic wealth of zero variance at time T. Let s therefore assme that x 0 e rt t0 < β in the seqel. Applying Itô s formla to the process Z defined by 3.75 Z t = β e rt t X d t where we set X d := X d and making se of 2.3 we easily find that 3.76 dz t = δ 2 Z t 1 e dt δ Z t δ2 T t 1 e dw δ2 T t t with Z t0 = β e rt t0 x 0 nder P t0,x 0. Solving the linear eqation 3.76 explicitly we obtain the closed form expression t δ t 3.77 Z t = Z t0 exp 1 e dw δ 2 δ2 T s s 1 e + 1 δ 2 ds δ2 T s 2 1 e δ2 T s 2 for t, T nder P t0,x 0. Inserting 3.77 into 3.75 we easily find that the first identity in 3.65 is satisfied. Integrating by parts and recalling the closed form expressions for B and S stated following 2.2 above we then establish that the second identity in 3.65 also holds. From 3.75 and 3.77 we see that Z t = β e rt t Xt d > 0 so that Xt d e rt t < β for t, T as claimed. Moreover, by the Dambis-Dbins-Schwarz theorem see e.g. 18, p

19 Figre 1. The dynamically optimal wealth t Xt d and the statically optimal wealth t Xt s in the constrained problem 2.6 of Corollary 7 obtained from the stock price t S t when = 0, x 0 = 1, S 0 = 1, β = 2, r = 0.1, µ = 0.5, σ = 0.4 and T = 1. Note that the expected vale of S T eqals e µt 1.64 which is strictly smaller than β. we know that the continos martingale M defined by M t = δ t e δ2 T s /e δ2 T s 1 dw s for t, T is a time-changed Brownian motion W in the sense that M t = W M,M t for t, T where we note that M, M t = δ 2 t e 2δ2 T s /e δ2 T s 1 2 ds as t T. It follows therefore by the well-known sample path properties of W that Mt 1 2 M, M t = W M,M t 1 2 M, M t as t T with P t0,x 0 -probability one. Making se of this fact in 3.65 we see that Xt d β with P t0,x 0 -probability one as t T if x 0 e rt t0 < β as claimed. From the preceding facts we also see that 3.66 holds and the proof is complete. Remark 8. Note from the proof above that Xt d < β with P t0,x 0 -probability one for all t, T if x 0 e rt t0 < β so that X d is not a bridge process bt a time-reversed meander process. The reslt of Corollary 7 shows that it is dynamically optimal to keep the wealth Xt d strictly below β for t, T with achieving XT d = β. This behavior is different 19

20 from the statically optimal wealth Xt s which can go above β on, T and end p either above or below β at T see Figre 1 above. Moreover, it is easily seen from 3.62 that P t0,x 0 XT s < β > 0 from where we find that 3.78 E t0,x 0 V 2 s T, XT s = > 0 = E t0,x 0 V 2 d T, XT d if x 0 e rt < β sing 3.63 and 3.66 respectively. This shows that the dynamic control d from 3.64 otperforms the static control s from 3.61 in the constrained problem 2.6. Remark 9. Note that no admissible control can move a given deterministic wealth x 0 at time 0, T to any other deterministic wealth at time T apart from x 0 e rt in which case eqals zero. This is important since otherwise the optimal control problem 2.6 wold not be well posed. Indeed, this can be seen by a standard martingale measre change d P t0,x 0 = exp δw T W t0 δ 2 /2t dp t0,x 0 making W t := W t W t0 +δt a standard Brownian motion for t, T. It then follows from 2.3 sing integration by parts that 3.79 e rt X t = x 0 + t σ e rs s X s d W s where M t := t σ e rs s X s d W s is a continos local martingale nder P t0,x 0 for t, T. Moreover, by Hölder s ineqality we see that 3.80 T Ẽ t0,x 0 M, M T = E t0,x 0 e δw T W t0 δ2 2 T 1/2 σ 2 e 2rt t0 2 t Xt 2 dt E t0,x0 e 2δW T W t0 δ 2 1/2 T 1/2 T E t0,x0 σ 2 e 2rt t0 2 t Xt 2 dt < T since E t0,x t X t 2 dt < by admissibility of. This shows that M is a martingale nder P t0,x 0. Hence if X T is constant then it follows from 3.79 and the martingale property of M that M t = 0 for all t, T. Bt this means that Xt = x 0 e rt for t, T with being eqal to zero as claimed. Remark 10. Note from 3.65 that E t0,x 0 Xt d β as t T if x 0 e rt t0 < β, however, this convergence fails to extend to the variance. Indeed, sing 3.65 it can be verified that Var t0,x 0 Xt d = e 2rT t β x 0 e rt e δ 2 T t 1 e δ2 T 1 e δ 2 T 1 e δ2 T t 1 exp 2 e δ2 T e δ2 T t e δ2 T t 1e δ2 T 1 1 for t, T from where we see that Var t0,x 0 Xt d as t T if x 0 e rt t0 < β. To connect to the comments on the sample path behavior made in Remark 6 note that t Xt d is not bonded from below on, T. Both of these conseqences are de partly to the fact that we allow the wealth process to take both positive and negative vales of nlimited size recall the end of Section 1 above. Another reason is that the dynamic optimality by its natre pshes the optimal controls to their limits so that breakdown points are possible. 20

21 4. Static vs dynamic optimality In this section we address the rationale for introdcing the static and dynamic optimality in the nonlinear optimal control problems nder consideration and explain their relevance for applications of both theoretical and practical interest. We also discss relation of these reslts with the existing approaches to similar problems in the literatre. 1. To simplify the exposition we focs on the nconstrained problem 2.4 and similar argments apply to the constrained problems 2.5 and 2.6 as well. Recall that 2.4 represents the optimal portfolio selection problem for an investor who has an initial wealth x 0 IR which he wishes to exchange between a risky stock S and a riskless bond B in a self-financing manner dynamically in time so as to maximise his retrn identified with the expectation of his wealth and minimise his risk identified with the variance of his wealth at the given terminal time T. De to the qadratic nonlinearity of the variance as a fnction of the expectation the optimal portfolio strategy 3.1 depends on the initial wealth x 0 in an essential way. This spatial inconsistency not present in the standard/linear optimal control problems introdces the time inconsistency in the problem becase the investor s wealth process moves from the initial vale x 0 in t nits of time to a new vale x 1 different from x 0 with probability one which in trn yields a new optimal portfolio strategy that is different from the initial strategy. This time inconsistency repeats itself between any two points in time and the investor may be in dobt which optimal portfolio strategy to se nless already made p his mind. To tackle these inconsistencies we are natrally led to consider two types of investors and conseqently introdce the two notions of optimality as stated in Definitions 1 and 2 respectively. The first investor is a static investor who stays pre-committed to the optimal portfolio strategy evalated initially and does not re-evalate the optimality criterion 2.4 at later times. This investor will determine the optimal portfolio strategy at time and follow it blindly to the terminal time T. The second investor is a dynamic investor who remains non-committed to the optimal portfolio strategy evalated initially as well as sbseqently and continosly re-evalates the optimality criterion 2.4 at each new time. This investor will determine the optimal portfolio strategy at time and contine doing so at each new time ntil the terminal time T. Clearly both the static investor and the dynamic investor embody realistic economic behavior see below for a more detailed accont coming from economics and Theorem 3 discloses their optimal portfolio selection strategies in the nconstrained problem 2.4. Similarly Corollary 5 and Corollary 7 disclose their optimal portfolio selection strategies in the constrained problems 2.5 and 2.6. Given that the financial interpretations of these reslts are easy to draw directly and somewhat lengthy to state explicitly we will omit frther details. It needs to be noted that althogh closely related the three problems are still different and hence it is to be expected that their soltions are also different for some vales of the parameters. Difference between the static and dynamic optimality is best nderstood by analysing each problem on its own first as in this case the complexity of the overall comparison is greatly redced. 2. Apart from the paper 13 where the dynamic optimality was sed in a nonlinear problem of optimal stopping, we are not aware of any other paper on optimal control where nonlinear problems were stdied sing this methodology. The dynamic optimality Definition 2 appears therefore to be original to the present paper in the context of nonlinear problems of optimal control. There are two streams of papers on optimal control however where the static opti- 21

22 mality Definition 1 has been sed. The first one belongs to the economics literatre and dates back to the paper by Strotz 21. The second one belongs to the finance literatre and dates back to the paper by Richardson 19. We present a brief review of these papers to highlight similarities/differences and indicate the applicability of the present methodology in these settings. 3. The stream of papers in the economics literatre starts with the paper by Strotz 21 who points ot a time inconsistency arising from the presence of the initial point in the time domain when the exponential disconting in the tility model of Samelson 20 is replaced by a non-exponential disconting. For an illminating exposition of the problem of intertemporal choices decisions involving tradeoffs among costs and benefits occrring at different times lasting over hndred years and leading to the Samelson s simplifying model containing a single parameter discont rate see 7 and the references therein. To tackle the isse of the time inconsistency Strotz proposed two strategies in his paper: i the strategy of pre-commitment where the individal commits to the optimal strategy derived initially and ii the strategy of consistent planning where the individal rejects any strategy which he will not follow throgh and aims to find the optimal strategy among those that he will actally follow. Note in particlar that Strotz coins the term pre-committed strategy in his paper and this term has since been sed in the literatre inclding most recent papers too. Althogh his setting is deterministic and his time is discrete on closer look one sees that or financial analysis of the static investor above is flly consistent with his economic reasoning and moreover the statically optimal portfolio strategy derived in the present paper may be viewed as the strategy of precommitment in Strotz s sense as already indicated above. The dynamically optimal portfolio strategy derived in the present paper is different however from the strategy of consistent planning in Strotz s sense. The difference is sbtle still sbstantial and it will become clearer throgh the exposition of the sbseqent development that contines to the present time. The next to point ot is the paper by Pollak 16 who showed that the derivation of the strategy of consistent planning in the Strotz paper 21 was incorrect one cannot replace the individal s non-exponential discont fnction by the exponential discont fnction having the same slope as the non-exponential discont fnction at zero. Peleg and Yaari 14 then attempted to find the strategy of consistent planning by backward recrsion and conclded that the strategy cold exist only nder too restrictive hypotheses to be sefl. They sggested to look at what we now refer to as a sbgame-perfect Nash eqilibrim the optimality concept refining Nash eqilibrim proposed by Selten in Goldman 8 then pointed ot that the failre of backward recrsion does not disprove the existence as sggested in 14 and showed that the strategy of consistent planning does exist nder qite general conditions. All these papers deal with problems in discrete time. A continos-time extension of these reslts appear more recently in the paper by Ekeland and Pirv 6 and the paper by Björk and Mrgoci 3 see also the references therein for other npblished work. The Strotz s strategy of consistent planning is being nderstood as a sbgame-perfect Nash eqilibrim in this context satisfying the natral consmption constraint at present time. 4. The stream of papers in the finance literatre starting with the paper by Richardson 19 deals with optimal portfolio selection problems nder mean-variance criteria similar/analogos to above. Richardson s paper 19 derives a statically optimal control in the constrained problem 2.6 sing the martingale method sggested by Pliska 15 who makes se of 22

Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection

Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection Research Report No. 14, 2013, Probab. Statist. Grop Manchester 25 pp Optimal Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection J. L. Pedersen & G. Peskir Assming that the wealth process X is generated self-financially

More information

Optimal mean-variance portfolio selection

Optimal mean-variance portfolio selection Math Finan Econ 2017) 11:137 160 DOI 10.1007/s11579-016-0174-8 Optimal mean-variance portfolio selection Jesper Lnd Pedersen 1 Goran Peskir 2 Received: 26 November 2015 / Accepted: 20 May 2016 / Pblished

More information

Optimal Mean-Variance Selling Strategies

Optimal Mean-Variance Selling Strategies Math. Financ. Econ. Vol. 10, No. 2, 2016, (203 220) Research Report No. 12, 2012, Probab. Statist. Group Manchester (20 pp) Optimal Mean-Variance Selling Strategies J. L. Pedersen & G. Peskir Assuming

More information

The Linear Quadratic Regulator

The Linear Quadratic Regulator 10 The Linear Qadratic Reglator 10.1 Problem formlation This chapter concerns optimal control of dynamical systems. Most of this development concerns linear models with a particlarly simple notion of optimality.

More information

A Theory of Markovian Time Inconsistent Stochastic Control in Discrete Time

A Theory of Markovian Time Inconsistent Stochastic Control in Discrete Time A Theory of Markovian Time Inconsistent Stochastic Control in Discrete Time Tomas Björk Department of Finance, Stockholm School of Economics tomas.bjork@hhs.se Agatha Mrgoci Department of Economics Aarhs

More information

Essentials of optimal control theory in ECON 4140

Essentials of optimal control theory in ECON 4140 Essentials of optimal control theory in ECON 4140 Things yo need to know (and a detail yo need not care abot). A few words abot dynamic optimization in general. Dynamic optimization can be thoght of as

More information

Constrained Dynamic Optimality and Binomial Terminal Wealth

Constrained Dynamic Optimality and Binomial Terminal Wealth To appear in SIAM J. Control Optim. Constrained Dynamic Optimality and Binomial Terminal Wealth J. L. Pedersen & G. Peskir This version: 13 March 018 First version: 31 December 015 Research Report No.

More information

ECON3120/4120 Mathematics 2, spring 2009

ECON3120/4120 Mathematics 2, spring 2009 University of Oslo Department of Economics Arne Strøm ECON3/4 Mathematics, spring 9 Problem soltions for Seminar 4, 6 Febrary 9 (For practical reasons some of the soltions may inclde problem parts that

More information

Optimization via the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Method: Theory and Applications

Optimization via the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Method: Theory and Applications Optimization via the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Method: Theory and Applications Navin Khaneja lectre notes taken by Christiane Koch Jne 24, 29 1 Variation yields a classical Hamiltonian system Sppose that

More information

ρ u = u. (1) w z will become certain time, and at a certain point in space, the value of

ρ u = u. (1) w z will become certain time, and at a certain point in space, the value of THE CONDITIONS NECESSARY FOR DISCONTINUOUS MOTION IN GASES G I Taylor Proceedings of the Royal Society A vol LXXXIV (90) pp 37-377 The possibility of the propagation of a srface of discontinity in a gas

More information

Krauskopf, B., Lee, CM., & Osinga, HM. (2008). Codimension-one tangency bifurcations of global Poincaré maps of four-dimensional vector fields.

Krauskopf, B., Lee, CM., & Osinga, HM. (2008). Codimension-one tangency bifurcations of global Poincaré maps of four-dimensional vector fields. Kraskopf, B, Lee,, & Osinga, H (28) odimension-one tangency bifrcations of global Poincaré maps of for-dimensional vector fields Early version, also known as pre-print Link to pblication record in Explore

More information

Optimal Control of a Heterogeneous Two Server System with Consideration for Power and Performance

Optimal Control of a Heterogeneous Two Server System with Consideration for Power and Performance Optimal Control of a Heterogeneos Two Server System with Consideration for Power and Performance by Jiazheng Li A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in flfilment of the thesis reqirement for

More information

1 Undiscounted Problem (Deterministic)

1 Undiscounted Problem (Deterministic) Lectre 9: Linear Qadratic Control Problems 1 Undisconted Problem (Deterministic) Choose ( t ) 0 to Minimize (x trx t + tq t ) t=0 sbject to x t+1 = Ax t + B t, x 0 given. x t is an n-vector state, t a

More information

ON THE SHAPES OF BILATERAL GAMMA DENSITIES

ON THE SHAPES OF BILATERAL GAMMA DENSITIES ON THE SHAPES OF BILATERAL GAMMA DENSITIES UWE KÜCHLER, STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. We investigate the for parameter family of bilateral Gamma distribtions. The goal of this paper is to provide a thorogh treatment

More information

Gradient Projection Anti-windup Scheme on Constrained Planar LTI Systems. Justin Teo and Jonathan P. How

Gradient Projection Anti-windup Scheme on Constrained Planar LTI Systems. Justin Teo and Jonathan P. How 1 Gradient Projection Anti-windp Scheme on Constrained Planar LTI Systems Jstin Teo and Jonathan P. How Technical Report ACL1 1 Aerospace Controls Laboratory Department of Aeronatics and Astronatics Massachsetts

More information

Formulas for stopped diffusion processes with stopping times based on drawdowns and drawups

Formulas for stopped diffusion processes with stopping times based on drawdowns and drawups Stochastic Processes and their Applications 119 (009) 563 578 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Formlas for stopped diffsion processes with stopping times based on drawdowns and drawps Libor Pospisil, Jan Vecer,

More information

Lecture Notes On THEORY OF COMPUTATION MODULE - 2 UNIT - 2

Lecture Notes On THEORY OF COMPUTATION MODULE - 2 UNIT - 2 BIJU PATNAIK UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY, ODISHA Lectre Notes On THEORY OF COMPUTATION MODULE - 2 UNIT - 2 Prepared by, Dr. Sbhend Kmar Rath, BPUT, Odisha. Tring Machine- Miscellany UNIT 2 TURING MACHINE

More information

Sufficient Optimality Condition for a Risk-Sensitive Control Problem for Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and an Application

Sufficient Optimality Condition for a Risk-Sensitive Control Problem for Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and an Application Jornal of Nmerical Mathematics and Stochastics, 9(1) : 48-6, 17 http://www.jnmas.org/jnmas9-4.pdf JNM@S Eclidean Press, LLC Online: ISSN 151-3 Sfficient Optimality Condition for a Risk-Sensitive Control

More information

L 1 -smoothing for the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck semigroup

L 1 -smoothing for the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck semigroup L -smoothing for the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck semigrop K. Ball, F. Barthe, W. Bednorz, K. Oleszkiewicz and P. Wolff September, 00 Abstract Given a probability density, we estimate the rate of decay of the measre

More information

Part II. Martingale measres and their constrctions 1. The \First" and the \Second" fndamental theorems show clearly how \mar tingale measres" are impo

Part II. Martingale measres and their constrctions 1. The \First and the \Second fndamental theorems show clearly how \mar tingale measres are impo Albert N. Shiryaev (Stelov Mathematical Institte and Moscow State University) ESSENTIALS of the ARBITRAGE THEORY Part I. Basic notions and theorems of the \Arbitrage Theory" Part II. Martingale measres

More information

Characterizations of probability distributions via bivariate regression of record values

Characterizations of probability distributions via bivariate regression of record values Metrika (2008) 68:51 64 DOI 10.1007/s00184-007-0142-7 Characterizations of probability distribtions via bivariate regression of record vales George P. Yanev M. Ahsanllah M. I. Beg Received: 4 October 2006

More information

Nonlinear parametric optimization using cylindrical algebraic decomposition

Nonlinear parametric optimization using cylindrical algebraic decomposition Proceedings of the 44th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, and the Eropean Control Conference 2005 Seville, Spain, December 12-15, 2005 TC08.5 Nonlinear parametric optimization sing cylindrical algebraic

More information

MAXIMUM AND ANTI-MAXIMUM PRINCIPLES FOR THE P-LAPLACIAN WITH A NONLINEAR BOUNDARY CONDITION. 1. Introduction. ν = λ u p 2 u.

MAXIMUM AND ANTI-MAXIMUM PRINCIPLES FOR THE P-LAPLACIAN WITH A NONLINEAR BOUNDARY CONDITION. 1. Introduction. ν = λ u p 2 u. 2005-Ojda International Conference on Nonlinear Analysis. Electronic Jornal of Differential Eqations, Conference 14, 2006, pp. 95 107. ISSN: 1072-6691. URL: http://ejde.math.txstate.ed or http://ejde.math.nt.ed

More information

On Multiobjective Duality For Variational Problems

On Multiobjective Duality For Variational Problems The Open Operational Research Jornal, 202, 6, -8 On Mltiobjective Dality For Variational Problems. Hsain *,, Bilal Ahmad 2 and Z. Jabeen 3 Open Access Department of Mathematics, Jaypee University of Engineering

More information

Math 263 Assignment #3 Solutions. 1. A function z = f(x, y) is called harmonic if it satisfies Laplace s equation:

Math 263 Assignment #3 Solutions. 1. A function z = f(x, y) is called harmonic if it satisfies Laplace s equation: Math 263 Assignment #3 Soltions 1. A fnction z f(x, ) is called harmonic if it satisfies Laplace s eqation: 2 + 2 z 2 0 Determine whether or not the following are harmonic. (a) z x 2 + 2. We se the one-variable

More information

EOQ Problem Well-Posedness: an Alternative Approach Establishing Sufficient Conditions

EOQ Problem Well-Posedness: an Alternative Approach Establishing Sufficient Conditions pplied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 4, 2, no. 25, 23-29 EOQ Problem Well-Posedness: an lternative pproach Establishing Sfficient Conditions Giovanni Mingari Scarpello via Negroli, 6, 226 Milano Italy Daniele

More information

Subcritical bifurcation to innitely many rotating waves. Arnd Scheel. Freie Universitat Berlin. Arnimallee Berlin, Germany

Subcritical bifurcation to innitely many rotating waves. Arnd Scheel. Freie Universitat Berlin. Arnimallee Berlin, Germany Sbcritical bifrcation to innitely many rotating waves Arnd Scheel Institt fr Mathematik I Freie Universitat Berlin Arnimallee 2-6 14195 Berlin, Germany 1 Abstract We consider the eqation 00 + 1 r 0 k2

More information

B-469 Simplified Copositive and Lagrangian Relaxations for Linearly Constrained Quadratic Optimization Problems in Continuous and Binary Variables

B-469 Simplified Copositive and Lagrangian Relaxations for Linearly Constrained Quadratic Optimization Problems in Continuous and Binary Variables B-469 Simplified Copositive and Lagrangian Relaxations for Linearly Constrained Qadratic Optimization Problems in Continos and Binary Variables Naohiko Arima, Snyong Kim and Masakaz Kojima October 2012,

More information

Hedge Funds Performance Fees and Investments

Hedge Funds Performance Fees and Investments Hedge Fnds Performance Fees and Investments A Thesis Sbmitted to the Faclty of the WORCESTER POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE In partial flfillment of the reqirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Financial

More information

Exercise 4. An optional time which is not a stopping time

Exercise 4. An optional time which is not a stopping time M5MF6, EXERCICE SET 1 We shall here consider a gien filtered probability space Ω, F, P, spporting a standard rownian motion W t t, with natral filtration F t t. Exercise 1 Proe Proposition 1.1.3, Theorem

More information

Second-Order Wave Equation

Second-Order Wave Equation Second-Order Wave Eqation A. Salih Department of Aerospace Engineering Indian Institte of Space Science and Technology, Thirvananthapram 3 December 016 1 Introdction The classical wave eqation is a second-order

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

CHARACTERIZATIONS OF EXPONENTIAL DISTRIBUTION VIA CONDITIONAL EXPECTATIONS OF RECORD VALUES. George P. Yanev

CHARACTERIZATIONS OF EXPONENTIAL DISTRIBUTION VIA CONDITIONAL EXPECTATIONS OF RECORD VALUES. George P. Yanev Pliska Std. Math. Blgar. 2 (211), 233 242 STUDIA MATHEMATICA BULGARICA CHARACTERIZATIONS OF EXPONENTIAL DISTRIBUTION VIA CONDITIONAL EXPECTATIONS OF RECORD VALUES George P. Yanev We prove that the exponential

More information

Classify by number of ports and examine the possible structures that result. Using only one-port elements, no more than two elements can be assembled.

Classify by number of ports and examine the possible structures that result. Using only one-port elements, no more than two elements can be assembled. Jnction elements in network models. Classify by nmber of ports and examine the possible strctres that reslt. Using only one-port elements, no more than two elements can be assembled. Combining two two-ports

More information

Setting The K Value And Polarization Mode Of The Delta Undulator

Setting The K Value And Polarization Mode Of The Delta Undulator LCLS-TN-4- Setting The Vale And Polarization Mode Of The Delta Undlator Zachary Wolf, Heinz-Dieter Nhn SLAC September 4, 04 Abstract This note provides the details for setting the longitdinal positions

More information

CHANNEL SELECTION WITH RAYLEIGH FADING: A MULTI-ARMED BANDIT FRAMEWORK. Wassim Jouini and Christophe Moy

CHANNEL SELECTION WITH RAYLEIGH FADING: A MULTI-ARMED BANDIT FRAMEWORK. Wassim Jouini and Christophe Moy CHANNEL SELECTION WITH RAYLEIGH FADING: A MULTI-ARMED BANDIT FRAMEWORK Wassim Joini and Christophe Moy SUPELEC, IETR, SCEE, Avene de la Bolaie, CS 47601, 5576 Cesson Sévigné, France. INSERM U96 - IFR140-

More information

Stability of Model Predictive Control using Markov Chain Monte Carlo Optimisation

Stability of Model Predictive Control using Markov Chain Monte Carlo Optimisation Stability of Model Predictive Control sing Markov Chain Monte Carlo Optimisation Elilini Siva, Pal Golart, Jan Maciejowski and Nikolas Kantas Abstract We apply stochastic Lyapnov theory to perform stability

More information

Research Article Permanence of a Discrete Predator-Prey Systems with Beddington-DeAngelis Functional Response and Feedback Controls

Research Article Permanence of a Discrete Predator-Prey Systems with Beddington-DeAngelis Functional Response and Feedback Controls Hindawi Pblishing Corporation Discrete Dynamics in Natre and Society Volme 2008 Article ID 149267 8 pages doi:101155/2008/149267 Research Article Permanence of a Discrete Predator-Prey Systems with Beddington-DeAngelis

More information

Move Blocking Strategies in Receding Horizon Control

Move Blocking Strategies in Receding Horizon Control Move Blocking Strategies in Receding Horizon Control Raphael Cagienard, Pascal Grieder, Eric C. Kerrigan and Manfred Morari Abstract In order to deal with the comptational brden of optimal control, it

More information

Conditions for Approaching the Origin without Intersecting the x-axis in the Liénard Plane

Conditions for Approaching the Origin without Intersecting the x-axis in the Liénard Plane Filomat 3:2 (27), 376 377 https://doi.org/.2298/fil7276a Pblished by Faclty of Sciences and Mathematics, University of Niš, Serbia Available at: http://www.pmf.ni.ac.rs/filomat Conditions for Approaching

More information

Admissibility under the LINEX loss function in non-regular case. Hidekazu Tanaka. Received November 5, 2009; revised September 2, 2010

Admissibility under the LINEX loss function in non-regular case. Hidekazu Tanaka. Received November 5, 2009; revised September 2, 2010 Scientiae Mathematicae Japonicae Online, e-2012, 427 434 427 Admissibility nder the LINEX loss fnction in non-reglar case Hidekaz Tanaka Received November 5, 2009; revised September 2, 2010 Abstract. In

More information

Pulses on a Struck String

Pulses on a Struck String 8.03 at ESG Spplemental Notes Plses on a Strck String These notes investigate specific eamples of transverse motion on a stretched string in cases where the string is at some time ndisplaced, bt with a

More information

Lecture 8: September 26

Lecture 8: September 26 10-704: Information Processing and Learning Fall 2016 Lectrer: Aarti Singh Lectre 8: September 26 Note: These notes are based on scribed notes from Spring15 offering of this corse. LaTeX template cortesy

More information

Imprecise Continuous-Time Markov Chains

Imprecise Continuous-Time Markov Chains Imprecise Continos-Time Markov Chains Thomas Krak *, Jasper De Bock, and Arno Siebes t.e.krak@.nl, a.p.j.m.siebes@.nl Utrecht University, Department of Information and Compting Sciences, Princetonplein

More information

Sources of Non Stationarity in the Semivariogram

Sources of Non Stationarity in the Semivariogram Sorces of Non Stationarity in the Semivariogram Migel A. Cba and Oy Leangthong Traditional ncertainty characterization techniqes sch as Simple Kriging or Seqential Gassian Simlation rely on stationary

More information

THE HOHENBERG-KOHN THEOREM FOR MARKOV SEMIGROUPS

THE HOHENBERG-KOHN THEOREM FOR MARKOV SEMIGROUPS THE HOHENBERG-KOHN THEOREM FOR MARKOV SEMIGROUPS OMAR HIJAB Abstract. At the basis of mch of comptational chemistry is density fnctional theory, as initiated by the Hohenberg-Kohn theorem. The theorem

More information

A Single Species in One Spatial Dimension

A Single Species in One Spatial Dimension Lectre 6 A Single Species in One Spatial Dimension Reading: Material similar to that in this section of the corse appears in Sections 1. and 13.5 of James D. Mrray (), Mathematical Biology I: An introction,

More information

Section 7.4: Integration of Rational Functions by Partial Fractions

Section 7.4: Integration of Rational Functions by Partial Fractions Section 7.4: Integration of Rational Fnctions by Partial Fractions This is abot as complicated as it gets. The Method of Partial Fractions Ecept for a few very special cases, crrently we have no way to

More information

HADAMARD-PERRON THEOREM

HADAMARD-PERRON THEOREM HADAMARD-PERRON THEOREM CARLANGELO LIVERANI. Invariant manifold of a fixed point He we will discss the simplest possible case in which the existence of invariant manifolds arises: the Hadamard-Perron theorem.

More information

E ect Of Quadrant Bow On Delta Undulator Phase Errors

E ect Of Quadrant Bow On Delta Undulator Phase Errors LCLS-TN-15-1 E ect Of Qadrant Bow On Delta Undlator Phase Errors Zachary Wolf SLAC Febrary 18, 015 Abstract The Delta ndlator qadrants are tned individally and are then assembled to make the tned ndlator.

More information

Math 116 First Midterm October 14, 2009

Math 116 First Midterm October 14, 2009 Math 116 First Midterm October 14, 9 Name: EXAM SOLUTIONS Instrctor: Section: 1. Do not open this exam ntil yo are told to do so.. This exam has 1 pages inclding this cover. There are 9 problems. Note

More information

Maximum Process Problems in Optimal Control Theory

Maximum Process Problems in Optimal Control Theory J. Appl. Math. Stochastic Anal. Vol. 25, No., 25, (77-88) Research Report No. 423, 2, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus (2 pp) Maximum Process Problems in Optimal Control Theory GORAN PESKIR 3 Given a standard

More information

An Investigation into Estimating Type B Degrees of Freedom

An Investigation into Estimating Type B Degrees of Freedom An Investigation into Estimating Type B Degrees of H. Castrp President, Integrated Sciences Grop Jne, 00 Backgrond The degrees of freedom associated with an ncertainty estimate qantifies the amont of information

More information

The Replenishment Policy for an Inventory System with a Fixed Ordering Cost and a Proportional Penalty Cost under Poisson Arrival Demands

The Replenishment Policy for an Inventory System with a Fixed Ordering Cost and a Proportional Penalty Cost under Poisson Arrival Demands Scientiae Mathematicae Japonicae Online, e-211, 161 167 161 The Replenishment Policy for an Inventory System with a Fixed Ordering Cost and a Proportional Penalty Cost nder Poisson Arrival Demands Hitoshi

More information

PhysicsAndMathsTutor.com

PhysicsAndMathsTutor.com . Two smooth niform spheres S and T have eqal radii. The mass of S is 0. kg and the mass of T is 0.6 kg. The spheres are moving on a smooth horizontal plane and collide obliqely. Immediately before the

More information

Home Range Formation in Wolves Due to Scent Marking

Home Range Formation in Wolves Due to Scent Marking Blletin of Mathematical Biology () 64, 61 84 doi:1.16/blm.1.73 Available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on Home Range Formation in Wolves De to Scent Marking BRIAN K. BRISCOE, MARK A. LEWIS AND STEPHEN

More information

Discussion of The Forward Search: Theory and Data Analysis by Anthony C. Atkinson, Marco Riani, and Andrea Ceroli

Discussion of The Forward Search: Theory and Data Analysis by Anthony C. Atkinson, Marco Riani, and Andrea Ceroli 1 Introdction Discssion of The Forward Search: Theory and Data Analysis by Anthony C. Atkinson, Marco Riani, and Andrea Ceroli Søren Johansen Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen and CREATES,

More information

Information Source Detection in the SIR Model: A Sample Path Based Approach

Information Source Detection in the SIR Model: A Sample Path Based Approach Information Sorce Detection in the SIR Model: A Sample Path Based Approach Kai Zh and Lei Ying School of Electrical, Compter and Energy Engineering Arizona State University Tempe, AZ, United States, 85287

More information

Remarks on strongly convex stochastic processes

Remarks on strongly convex stochastic processes Aeqat. Math. 86 (01), 91 98 c The Athor(s) 01. This article is pblished with open access at Springerlink.com 0001-9054/1/010091-8 pblished online November 7, 01 DOI 10.1007/s00010-01-016-9 Aeqationes Mathematicae

More information

UNCERTAINTY FOCUSED STRENGTH ANALYSIS MODEL

UNCERTAINTY FOCUSED STRENGTH ANALYSIS MODEL 8th International DAAAM Baltic Conference "INDUSTRIAL ENGINEERING - 19-1 April 01, Tallinn, Estonia UNCERTAINTY FOCUSED STRENGTH ANALYSIS MODEL Põdra, P. & Laaneots, R. Abstract: Strength analysis is a

More information

Chapter 2 Difficulties associated with corners

Chapter 2 Difficulties associated with corners Chapter Difficlties associated with corners This chapter is aimed at resolving the problems revealed in Chapter, which are cased b corners and/or discontinos bondar conditions. The first section introdces

More information

Analytical Value-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall under Regime Switching *

Analytical Value-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall under Regime Switching * Working Paper 9-4 Departamento de Economía Economic Series 14) Universidad Carlos III de Madrid March 9 Calle Madrid, 16 893 Getafe Spain) Fax 34) 91649875 Analytical Vale-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall

More information

Technical Note. ODiSI-B Sensor Strain Gage Factor Uncertainty

Technical Note. ODiSI-B Sensor Strain Gage Factor Uncertainty Technical Note EN-FY160 Revision November 30, 016 ODiSI-B Sensor Strain Gage Factor Uncertainty Abstract Lna has pdated or strain sensor calibration tool to spport NIST-traceable measrements, to compte

More information

A Survey of the Implementation of Numerical Schemes for Linear Advection Equation

A Survey of the Implementation of Numerical Schemes for Linear Advection Equation Advances in Pre Mathematics, 4, 4, 467-479 Pblished Online Agst 4 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/jornal/apm http://dx.doi.org/.436/apm.4.485 A Srvey of the Implementation of Nmerical Schemes for Linear

More information

Chapter 3. Preferences and Utility

Chapter 3. Preferences and Utility Chapter 3 Preferences and Utilit Microeconomics stdies how individals make choices; different individals make different choices n important factor in making choices is individal s tastes or preferences

More information

1 The space of linear transformations from R n to R m :

1 The space of linear transformations from R n to R m : Math 540 Spring 20 Notes #4 Higher deriaties, Taylor s theorem The space of linear transformations from R n to R m We hae discssed linear transformations mapping R n to R m We can add sch linear transformations

More information

Elements of Coordinate System Transformations

Elements of Coordinate System Transformations B Elements of Coordinate System Transformations Coordinate system transformation is a powerfl tool for solving many geometrical and kinematic problems that pertain to the design of gear ctting tools and

More information

Dynamic Optimization of First-Order Systems via Static Parametric Programming: Application to Electrical Discharge Machining

Dynamic Optimization of First-Order Systems via Static Parametric Programming: Application to Electrical Discharge Machining Dynamic Optimization of First-Order Systems via Static Parametric Programming: Application to Electrical Discharge Machining P. Hgenin*, B. Srinivasan*, F. Altpeter**, R. Longchamp* * Laboratoire d Atomatiqe,

More information

RELIABILITY ASPECTS OF PROPORTIONAL MEAN RESIDUAL LIFE MODEL USING QUANTILE FUNC- TIONS

RELIABILITY ASPECTS OF PROPORTIONAL MEAN RESIDUAL LIFE MODEL USING QUANTILE FUNC- TIONS RELIABILITY ASPECTS OF PROPORTIONAL MEAN RESIDUAL LIFE MODEL USING QUANTILE FUNC- TIONS Athors: N.UNNIKRISHNAN NAIR Department of Statistics, Cochin University of Science Technology, Cochin, Kerala, INDIA

More information

Formules relatives aux probabilités qui dépendent de très grands nombers

Formules relatives aux probabilités qui dépendent de très grands nombers Formles relatives ax probabilités qi dépendent de très grands nombers M. Poisson Comptes rends II (836) pp. 603-63 In the most important applications of the theory of probabilities, the chances of events

More information

arxiv:quant-ph/ v4 14 May 2003

arxiv:quant-ph/ v4 14 May 2003 Phase-transition-like Behavior of Qantm Games arxiv:qant-ph/0111138v4 14 May 2003 Jiangfeng D Department of Modern Physics, University of Science and Technology of China, Hefei, 230027, People s Repblic

More information

Rationally Expected Externalities: The Implications for Optimal Waste Discharge and Recycling. R.A. Somerville. TEP Working Paper No.

Rationally Expected Externalities: The Implications for Optimal Waste Discharge and Recycling. R.A. Somerville. TEP Working Paper No. Rationally Expected Externalities: The Implications for Optimal Waste Discharge and Recycling R.A. Somerville TEP Working Paper No. 02 Janary 202 Trinity Economics Papers Department of Economics Trinity

More information

Partial Differential Equations with Applications

Partial Differential Equations with Applications Universit of Leeds MATH 33 Partial Differential Eqations with Applications Eamples to spplement Chapter on First Order PDEs Eample (Simple linear eqation, k + = 0, (, 0) = ϕ(), k a constant.) The characteristic

More information

The Dual of the Maximum Likelihood Method

The Dual of the Maximum Likelihood Method Department of Agricltral and Resorce Economics University of California, Davis The Dal of the Maximm Likelihood Method by Qirino Paris Working Paper No. 12-002 2012 Copyright @ 2012 by Qirino Paris All

More information

4.2 First-Order Logic

4.2 First-Order Logic 64 First-Order Logic and Type Theory The problem can be seen in the two qestionable rles In the existential introdction, the term a has not yet been introdced into the derivation and its se can therefore

More information

PhysicsAndMathsTutor.com

PhysicsAndMathsTutor.com C Integration - By sbstittion PhysicsAndMathsTtor.com. Using the sbstittion cos +, or otherwise, show that e cos + sin d e(e ) (Total marks). (a) Using the sbstittion cos, or otherwise, find the eact vale

More information

Mathematical Analysis of Nipah Virus Infections Using Optimal Control Theory

Mathematical Analysis of Nipah Virus Infections Using Optimal Control Theory Jornal of Applied Mathematics and Physics, 06, 4, 099- Pblished Online Jne 06 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/jornal/jamp http://dx.doi.org/0.436/jamp.06.464 Mathematical Analysis of Nipah Virs nfections

More information

4 Exact laminar boundary layer solutions

4 Exact laminar boundary layer solutions 4 Eact laminar bondary layer soltions 4.1 Bondary layer on a flat plate (Blasis 1908 In Sec. 3, we derived the bondary layer eqations for 2D incompressible flow of constant viscosity past a weakly crved

More information

CRITERIA FOR TOEPLITZ OPERATORS ON THE SPHERE. Jingbo Xia

CRITERIA FOR TOEPLITZ OPERATORS ON THE SPHERE. Jingbo Xia CRITERIA FOR TOEPLITZ OPERATORS ON THE SPHERE Jingbo Xia Abstract. Let H 2 (S) be the Hardy space on the nit sphere S in C n. We show that a set of inner fnctions Λ is sfficient for the prpose of determining

More information

Integration of Basic Functions. Session 7 : 9/23 1

Integration of Basic Functions. Session 7 : 9/23 1 Integration o Basic Fnctions Session 7 : 9/3 Antiderivation Integration Deinition: Taking the antiderivative, or integral, o some nction F(), reslts in the nction () i ()F() Pt simply: i yo take the integral

More information

Modelling by Differential Equations from Properties of Phenomenon to its Investigation

Modelling by Differential Equations from Properties of Phenomenon to its Investigation Modelling by Differential Eqations from Properties of Phenomenon to its Investigation V. Kleiza and O. Prvinis Kanas University of Technology, Lithania Abstract The Panevezys camps of Kanas University

More information

Typed Kleene Algebra with Products and Iteration Theories

Typed Kleene Algebra with Products and Iteration Theories Typed Kleene Algebra with Prodcts and Iteration Theories Dexter Kozen and Konstantinos Mamoras Compter Science Department Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853-7501, USA {kozen,mamoras}@cs.cornell.ed Abstract

More information

Using Lagrangian relaxation in optimisation of unit commitment and planning- Part2

Using Lagrangian relaxation in optimisation of unit commitment and planning- Part2 Faklteta za Elektrotehniko Eva horin, Heike Brand, Christoph Weber Using Lagrangian relaxation in optimisation of nit commitment and planning- art2 OSCOGEN Discssion aper No. Contract No. ENK5-C-2-94 roject

More information

Decision Oriented Bayesian Design of Experiments

Decision Oriented Bayesian Design of Experiments Decision Oriented Bayesian Design of Experiments Farminder S. Anand*, Jay H. Lee**, Matthew J. Realff*** *School of Chemical & Biomoleclar Engineering Georgia Institte of echnology, Atlanta, GA 3332 USA

More information

1. State-Space Linear Systems 2. Block Diagrams 3. Exercises

1. State-Space Linear Systems 2. Block Diagrams 3. Exercises LECTURE 1 State-Space Linear Sstems This lectre introdces state-space linear sstems, which are the main focs of this book. Contents 1. State-Space Linear Sstems 2. Block Diagrams 3. Exercises 1.1 State-Space

More information

Affine Invariant Total Variation Models

Affine Invariant Total Variation Models Affine Invariant Total Variation Models Helen Balinsky, Alexander Balinsky Media Technologies aboratory HP aboratories Bristol HP-7-94 Jne 6, 7* Total Variation, affine restoration, Sobolev ineqality,

More information

STURM-LIOUVILLE PROBLEMS

STURM-LIOUVILLE PROBLEMS STURM-LIOUVILLE PROBLEMS ANTON ZETTL Mathematics Department, Northern Illinois University, DeKalb, Illinois 60115. Dedicated to the memory of John Barrett. ABSTRACT. Reglar and singlar Strm-Lioville problems

More information

QUANTILE ESTIMATION IN SUCCESSIVE SAMPLING

QUANTILE ESTIMATION IN SUCCESSIVE SAMPLING Jornal of the Korean Statistical Society 2007, 36: 4, pp 543 556 QUANTILE ESTIMATION IN SUCCESSIVE SAMPLING Hosila P. Singh 1, Ritesh Tailor 2, Sarjinder Singh 3 and Jong-Min Kim 4 Abstract In sccessive

More information

Lecture: Corporate Income Tax

Lecture: Corporate Income Tax Lectre: Corporate Income Tax Ltz Krschwitz & Andreas Löffler Disconted Cash Flow, Section 2.1, Otline 2.1 Unlevered firms Similar companies Notation 2.1.1 Valation eqation 2.1.2 Weak atoregressive cash

More information

Cubic graphs have bounded slope parameter

Cubic graphs have bounded slope parameter Cbic graphs have bonded slope parameter B. Keszegh, J. Pach, D. Pálvölgyi, and G. Tóth Agst 25, 2009 Abstract We show that every finite connected graph G with maximm degree three and with at least one

More information

A Regulator for Continuous Sedimentation in Ideal Clarifier-Thickener Units

A Regulator for Continuous Sedimentation in Ideal Clarifier-Thickener Units A Reglator for Continos Sedimentation in Ideal Clarifier-Thickener Units STEFAN DIEHL Centre for Mathematical Sciences, Lnd University, P.O. Box, SE- Lnd, Sweden e-mail: diehl@maths.lth.se) Abstract. The

More information

On averaged expected cost control as reliability for 1D ergodic diffusions

On averaged expected cost control as reliability for 1D ergodic diffusions On averaged expected cost control as reliability for 1D ergodic diffsions S.V. Anlova 5 6, H. Mai 7 8, A.Y. Veretennikov 9 10 Mon Nov 27 10:24:42 2017 Abstract For a Markov model described by a one-dimensional

More information

Two-media boundary layer on a flat plate

Two-media boundary layer on a flat plate Two-media bondary layer on a flat plate Nikolay Ilyich Klyev, Asgat Gatyatovich Gimadiev, Yriy Alekseevich Krykov Samara State University, Samara,, Rssia Samara State Aerospace University named after academician

More information

Lab Manual for Engrd 202, Virtual Torsion Experiment. Aluminum module

Lab Manual for Engrd 202, Virtual Torsion Experiment. Aluminum module Lab Manal for Engrd 202, Virtal Torsion Experiment Alminm modle Introdction In this modle, o will perform data redction and analsis for circlar cross section alminm samples. B plotting the torqe vs. twist

More information

Chapter 4 Supervised learning:

Chapter 4 Supervised learning: Chapter 4 Spervised learning: Mltilayer Networks II Madaline Other Feedforward Networks Mltiple adalines of a sort as hidden nodes Weight change follows minimm distrbance principle Adaptive mlti-layer

More information

AN ISOGEOMETRIC SOLID-SHELL FORMULATION OF THE KOITER METHOD FOR BUCKLING AND INITIAL POST-BUCKLING ANALYSIS OF COMPOSITE SHELLS

AN ISOGEOMETRIC SOLID-SHELL FORMULATION OF THE KOITER METHOD FOR BUCKLING AND INITIAL POST-BUCKLING ANALYSIS OF COMPOSITE SHELLS th Eropean Conference on Comptational Mechanics (ECCM ) 7th Eropean Conference on Comptational Flid Dynamics (ECFD 7) 5 Jne 28, Glasgow, UK AN ISOGEOMETRIC SOLID-SHELL FORMULATION OF THE KOITER METHOD

More information

Prediction of Transmission Distortion for Wireless Video Communication: Analysis

Prediction of Transmission Distortion for Wireless Video Communication: Analysis Prediction of Transmission Distortion for Wireless Video Commnication: Analysis Zhifeng Chen and Dapeng W Department of Electrical and Compter Engineering, University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida 326

More information

BLOOM S TAXONOMY. Following Bloom s Taxonomy to Assess Students

BLOOM S TAXONOMY. Following Bloom s Taxonomy to Assess Students BLOOM S TAXONOMY Topic Following Bloom s Taonomy to Assess Stdents Smmary A handot for stdents to eplain Bloom s taonomy that is sed for item writing and test constrction to test stdents to see if they

More information

Predicting the Time of the Ultimate Maximum for Brownian Motion with Drift

Predicting the Time of the Ultimate Maximum for Brownian Motion with Drift Proc. Math. Control Theory Finance Lisbon 27, Springer, 28, 95-112 Research Report No. 4, 27, Probab. Statist. Group Manchester 16 pp Predicting the Time of the Ultimate Maximum for Brownian Motion with

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information