Discussion Class Notes

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Discussion Class Notes"

Transcription

1 Department of Economics University of Minnesota Macroeconomic Theory Varadarajan V. Chari Spring 2015 Discussion Class Notes Keyvan Eslami The following notes are prepared as a complement to V.V. Chari s Macroeconomic Theory course, taught as the third part of Macroeconomics Sequence to first year graduate students, based on the requirements of the course, and under his supervision. Stokey et al. 1989) and Ljungqvist and Sargent 2012) has been used as the major references.

2 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming We extensively considered sequential problems in the context of neoclassical growth models, in the deterministic settings, previous mini. We also considered the recursive counterparts of these problems, and established the relationship between these two formulations; this was done under the topic of principle of optimality. We start this mini by moving into the world of uncertainty; consider the same old neoclassical growth model, with a single type of infinitely lived consumer, and a single composite good, that can be consumed or invested. The only difference is that, now, instead of a certain amount of output for a given amount of capital stock, output is affected by an exogenous random shock. In this new setting, the functional equation we have to consider takes the following form: v k, z) = { } sup u [zf k) k ] + β v k, z ) Q z, dz ). 1) k [0,zfk)] Z Here, k is an endogenous state variable, and z is an exogenous state variable, that follows a known stochastic process, namely, a stationary Markov process. As you might expect, our first step would be, like the deterministic case, to establish the relation between the solution to this functional equation and the policy associated with it) and the corresponding value of a sequence problem. To do so, we need a little bit of preliminaries. 1.1 Measure Spaces and Measure Functions Let X be a set and X a σ-algebra over X; X is simply a collection of subsets of X that is closed under countable complement and intersection operations. The pair, X, X ) is called a measurable space. A measure is a function, µ : X R +, that satisfies the following conditions: null set has measure zero; µ ) = 0, 1

3 µ ) is countably additive; ) µ E i = i I i I µ E i ), for every disjoint countable collection of sets, I, in X. It is important to bear in mind that µ ) is not defined on a general sub-collection of X. The triple X, X, µ) is called a measure space. Given two measurable spaces, X 1, X 1 ) and X 2, X 2 ), X = X 1 X 2, together with X, the smallest σ-algebra containing all the rectangles of the form E 1 E 2 where E 1 X 1 and E 2 X 2 ), constitutes a measurable space. X, X ) is called the product space of X 1, X 1 ) and X 2, X 2 ). µ ) is called a probability measure if µ X) = 1. Then, we call the triple X, X, µ) a probability space. The introduction of measure theory in real analysis opened a whole new door to the study of probability; what became modern probability theory. Intuitively, X can be thought of as a set of possible outcomes. Then, elements of X can be viewed as events. Then, µ E), for any E X gives the probability of an event. Note that, naturally, if {E i } i I is a countable collection of disjoint events in X, we expect the probability of one of these events happening to be the sum of the probability of each of these events.) Given this concise introduction into measure spaces, we can now define a transition function, as follows: Definition 1 Let X, X ) be a measurable space. A transition function is a function Q : X X [0, 1], such that: 1. for each x X, Q x, ) is a probability measure on X, X ), 2. and, for each E X, Q, E) is a X -measurable function. Using the definition of transition functions, we can describe a stationary Markov process by means of a transition function, Q ); Q x, E) gives the probability that next period s state lies in E, given that this period s state is x; i.e. Q x, E) = P r {x t+1 E x t = x}. 2

4 Now, consider an exogenous random shock, z, that can take values in a set Z. Suppose Z, Z ) is the corresponding measurable space. Moreover, assume the transition of z is given by the transition function Q ), and g : Z R is a Z -measurable function. Then, we can write the expectation of g ), conditioned on this periods realization of z as: E [g z ) z] = g z ) Q z, dz ), where the integral is Lebesgue integral. Z 1.2 Principle of Optimality Let us get back to our stochastic dynamic program, and define each element precisely. 1 To do so, we consider the general case of 1, in which k and z need not be scalars, but general vectors. To this end, suppose X, X ) and Z, Z ) are measurable spaces, and S, S ) = X Z, X Z ) is the product space. S is the set of states for this system, whose elements consist of an exogenous state, z Z, and an endogenous state, x X. We will assume that the exogenous state follows a stationary Markov process, whit transition function Q ), defined on Z, Z ). Given today s state, s, let us denote the set of feasible next period states by Γ s); Γ : S X is the feasibility correspondence. Let A be the graph of Γ ): A = {x, y, z) X X Z y Γ x, z)}. Suppose F : A R is one-period payoff function, and β 0 is the discount factor. Recall from the last mini that, in a sequential setting, a planner s problem in each period is to choose a sequence of contingent plans that maximize the discounted expected value of utility. These contingent plans can be viewed as functions of the history of shocks up to a 1 What follows is based on Chapter 9 of Stokey et al. 1989). 3

5 given date t, namely, z t : max {k t+1 z t )} zt Z t t 0 E 0 t=0 β t u [ z t f [ k t z t 1 )] k t+1 zt, z t 1)] 2) s.t. 0 k t+1 zt, z t 1) z t f [ k t z t 1 )] for all z t 1 and z t, given k 0 and z 0. To generalize this problem, to a setting where z is a Markov process instead of a Markov chain, let Z t, Z t ) be the product space up to period t 1, and z t Z t be the partial history of shocks up to date t. Then, we can define a plan as follows: Definition 2 A plan is a value π 0 X and a sequence of measurable functions π t : Z t X, for t = 1, 2,.... A plan π is feasible from s 0 S, if: 1. π 0 Γ s 0 ), 2. and, π t z t ) Γ [π t 1 z t 1 ), z t ], for all z t Z t and t = 1, 2,.... Let us denote the set of all feasible plans from s 0 by Π s 0 ). Recall from the deterministic case that, our first requirement for the sequence problem to be well defined was for Γ ) to be a non-empty correspondence. Here, we need a stronger assumption that ensures the existence of measurable functions. This is done in the following assumptions. Assumption 1 Γ ) is non-empty valued, and A is X X Z )-measurable. Moreover, Γ ) has a measurable selection; i.e. there exists a measurable function h : S X such that h s) Γ s) for all s S. It is straightforward to show that, under Assumption 1, Π s 0 ) is non-empty for all s 0 S. Next, we have to specify how the planner calculates the expectations in 2. To do so, given the transition function of the Markov process governing z, it is straightforward at least intuitively) to construct a probability measure explaining the evolution of history up to date t, namely µ t z 0, ) : Z t [0, 1]. Now, if we define a σ-algebra, A as: A = {C X X Z C A}, 4

6 for the discounted expected payoff to be well-defined a the general version of 2, we can impose the following assumption: Assumption 2 F : A R is A -measurable, and one of the followings holds: 1. F 0 or F For each s 0 = x 0, z 0 ) S and each plan π Π s 0 ), F [π t 1 z t 1 ), π t z t ), z t ] is µ t z 0, )-integrable, for t = 1, 2,..., and the limit F x 0, π 0, z 0 ) + lim n n t=1 exists although it might not be bounded). Z t β t F [ π t 1 z t 1 ), π t z t ), z t ] µ t z 0, dz t) Notice that, under Assumptions 1 and 2, discounted expected payoff in a planner s problem) is well-defined, and we can define the value of a planner as: v s) = sup {F x 0, π 0, z 0 ) π Πs) + lim n n β t F [ π ) t 1 z t 1, π ) ] t z t, z } t µ t z 0, dz t). 3) Z t t=1 The recursive counterpart of this optimization problem can be written in therms of the following functional equation: { } v s) = v x, z) = sup F x, y, z) + β v y, z ) Q z, dz ). 4) y Γs) Z If there exists a function v ) that solves this functional equation, then, we can define the associated policy correspondence as: G x, z) = { } y Γ x, z) v x, z) = F x, y, z) + β v y, z ) Q z, dz ). 5) Z How can we generate a plan from this correspondence? Notice that, now, G x, z) being non-empty is not enough to ensure the existence of a feasible plan; now we need existence 5

7 of a measurable selection from G ). If such a measurable selection exists, say g 0, g 1,... is a sequence of measurable selections from G ), then we can generate a plane as: π 0 = g 0 s 0 ), π t z t ) = g t [ πt 1 z t 1 ), z t ], for all z t Z t and t 1. Now, we are ready to present a partial counterpart of the principle of optimality for the stochastic setting: Theorem 1 Principle of Optimality) Suppose X, X ), Z, Z ), Q, Γ, F, and β satisfy Assumptions 1 and 2. Let v ) be the solution to 3, and v ) the solution to 4, so that: lim β t v [ π ) ] t 1 z t 1, z t µ t z 0, dz t) = 0, t Z t for all π Π s 0 ), and all s 0 S. Let G ) be the correspondence defined by 5, which is non-empty and permits a measurable selection. Then v = v, and the plan generated by G ) attains the supremum in Solution to the Functional Equation Next step, is to ensure the existence of a solution to the functional equation. Like the deterministic case, when the return function is bounded, there is a good chance that this is the case. In this section, we consider the fairly general assumptions under which, this is the case, by focusing on the case of bounded returns. Assumption 3 X is a convex Borel set in R l, and X is its Borel subsets. Assumption 4 One of the followings holds: 1. Z is a countable set, and Z is the σ-algebra containing all of its subsets. 2. Z is a compact Borel set in R k, with its Borel subsets Z, and the transition function Q ) has the Feller property. 6

8 The key role of Assumption 4 is to ensure that the integral in 4, Mf y, z) = Z v y, z ) Q z, dz ), for all y, z) X Z, 6) maps a bounded continuous function v : X Z R into the space of bounded continuous functions over X Z. Moreover, this assumption ensures that, if v ) is increasing or concave, then the integral would be an increasing or concave function of y, z). Given this property, the rest is quite similar to the stochastic case; first, we may use Blackwell s sufficient conditions to ensure that the mapping defined by 4 is a contraction, and then use the Contraction Mapping Theorem to ensure the existence of a fixed point. First we need the following two assumptions: Assumption 5 The correspondence Γ : X Z X is non-empty, compact-valued, and continuous. Assumption 6 The function F : A R is bounded and continuous, and β 0, 1). Now, we have the following theorem: Theorem 2 Under Assumptions 3-6, the operator T, defined by { } T f x, z) = sup F x, y, z) + β f y, z ) Q z, dz ), 7) y Γs) Z maps the set of bounded continuous functions, C S), into itself, and has a unique fixed point in this set, v ) C S). Moreover, for all v 0 ) C S): T n v 0 v β n v 0 v, n = 1, 2,.... In addition, the correspondence G ) defined by 5 is non-empty, compact-valued, and upper hemi-continuous. 1.4 Inheritance Properties of the Value Function If the operator M in 6 preserves the monotonicity and concavity of the integrand, it is natural to expect that the value function inherits these properties from the payoff function; 7

9 what we had in the deterministic case, as well. To formalize this idea, let us introduce the following assumptions. Note that, A i denotes the i-section of the set A, in what follows. Assumption 7 For each y, z) X Z, F, y, z) : A yz R is strictly increasing. Assumption 8 For each z Z, x x implies Γ x, z) Γ x, z). Now, we have our first inheritance property of the value function: Theorem 3 Under Assumptions 3-8, the fixed point of operator T in 7 is strictly increasing in x, for each z Z. The value function inherits the concavity of the payoff function as well: Assumption 9 For each z Z, F,, z) : A z R is strictly concave in x, y). Assumption 10 The set A z is convex. Theorem 4 Under Assumptions 3-6 and 9-10, the fixed point of operator T in 7 is strictly concave in x, for each z Z, and the corresponding policy correspondence is a continuous function. Finally, v ) inherits the differentiability of the payoff function, too: Assumption 11 For a fixed z Z, F,, z) is continuously differentiable in x, y), in the interior of A z. Theorem 5 Suppose Assumptions 3-6 and 9-11 hold, v ) C S) is the fixed point of operator T in 7, and g : S X is the corresponding value function. If x 0 intx, and g x 0, z 0 ) intγ x 0, z 0 ), then v, z 0 ) is continuously differentiable in x at x 0, and we have: v i x 0, z 0 ) = F i [x 0, g x 0, z 0 ), z 0 ], for i = 1, 2,..., l. 2 Weak Convergence of Markov Processes When dealing with competitive equilibrium concept in the deterministic case, the allocations are usually thought of sequences of real numbers in the appropriate commodity space). We often are interested in the asymptotic properties of these allocations; if they converge to a finite limit, and, if so, what is this limit. 8

10 As we saw last class, the competitive equilibrium allocations in the stochastic environment are not in general sequences of numbers, but sequences of measurable) functions; in other words, random variables. So, the asymptotic properties of these allocations can not be stated in terms of convergence of a real sequence in Euclidean norm. Instead, we have to consider the asymptotic behavior of the random variables that represent the allocations. This, first of all, calls for some appropriate definition of convergence of random variables, and, next, theorems that ensure the convergence in this new sense. When the random shocks in the economy follow a Markov process, we are able to write the sequence problem of a planner in particular, and the equilibrium in general, as a stationary dynamic programming problem. Moreover, as you have seen in the class, when the stochastic process governing the exogenous shocks is Markov, we can describe the transition of the endogenous states as a Markov process as well. This, in turns, enables us to focus on the definition of convergence of random variables that are defined over a Markov space. More importantly, there are theorems that guarantee this type of convergence for Markov processes, under justifiable assumptions. In this session, we are going to define a notion of convergence for Markov processes, and state the theorems that ensure their convergence. 2.1 Some Definitions Weak Convergence of Probability Measures There are different notions of convergence of probability measures. But, what we really are interested in is weak convergence. Let S, ρ) be a metric space, and S be its Borel subsets; i.e. S is the σ-algebra generated by the family of open sets in S. We usually think of S as a subset of k-dimensional Euclidean space.) Let C S) be the set of continuous functions defined on S, and Λ S, S ) the set of probability measures defined on S, S ). Definition 1 A sequence of probability measures {λ n } n 1 Λ S, S ) is said to converge weakly to λ Λ S, S ), written λ n λ, if lim f s) λ n ds) = f s) λ ds), f C S). n S S 9

11 Note that, when f ) is a continuous function on S, and λ ) is a probability measure on S, S ), fdλ is the expectation of f ) with respect to λ ). Therefore, we say a sequence of probability measures converges to a probability measure if the expectation of a all the continuous functions converges. A more intuitive definition of the weak convergence of probability measures is provided in the following theorem. Theorem 1 Suppose {λ n } n 1 and λ are probability measures in Λ S, S ). Then λ n λ if and only if for all A S with λ A) = 0. lim λ n A) = λ A), n This theorem says a sequence of probability measures converges weakly to a probability measure if and only if, in the limit, they assign the same probability to the sets that do not have dense boundaries i.e. boundaries with positive probability under the latter) Transition Functions, and Markov and Adjoint Operators We talked about a Markov process on S, S ) last class, and how we can characterize it by means of transition function, Q ). For any s S and A S, Q s, A) gives the probability of event A happening in next period, given this period s shock is s. For a transition function Q ), the probability of event A happening after N periods, given this period s realization of shock is s, can be derived as: Q N s, A) = = where Q 1 s, A) = Q s, A). S S S... Q s N 1, A) Q s N 2, ds N 1 )... Q s, ds 1 ) S Q N 1 s, A) Q s, ds ), There are two important operators associated with every Markov process and transition function, in general). Definition 2 Given Q ), a transition function on S, S ), the Markov operator associated 10

12 with Q ) is defined as: T f s) = f s ) Q s, ds ), s S, S where f ) is a S -measurable function defined on S. The adjoint operator of T is defined as: T λ A) = Q s, A) λ ds), A S, S where λ ) is a probability measure over S, S ). Intuitively, given a Markov process, Markov operator determines the expected value of function f ) in the next period, given the realization of shock in this period. On the other hand, the adjoint operator of T given the unconditional) probability of an event next period, given the unconditional probability of the shock this period. Question What can you say about the relation between T and T? The following equation gives the relation between the two: T f s) λ ds) = f s ) T λ ds ). S S Each side of this equation gives the unconditional expectation of f ) next period, given the probability measure of shocks this period. Given a Markov process, characterized by a transition function, we can use the associated Markov operator to calculate next period s expected value of a measurable) function, as a function of this period s realization of shock. Feller property and monotonicity of the transition function determine if the Markov operator preserves properties of the function whose expected value we are interested in. Definition 3 A transition function Q ) is said to have Feller property on S, S ) if the associated Markov operator maps the space of bounded continuous functions into itself. It is said to be monotone if for every non-decreasing function f ) on S, T f ) is also non-decreasing. Feller property and monotonicity of the Markov operator have counterparts in terms of adjoint operators. The following theorem states these counterparts. 11

13 Theorem 2 A transition function Q ) on S, S ) is monotone if and only if for all λ, µ Λ S, S ), T µ first order stochastically dominates T µ, if µfirst order stochastically dominates λ. Moreover, Q ) has the Feller property if and only if λ n λ implies T λ n T λ. Remark Now you can observe why we talked about monotonicity in class in terms of stochastic dominance of probability measures. 2.2 Monotone Markov Processes As we mentioned before, when the exogenous shocks follow a Markov process, solving a stationary dynamic program and finding the associated policy functions enable us to write the endogenous states themselves as Markov processes, by finding the appropriate transition function. Suppose P ) represents such a transition function on the space S, S ); here, S is the set of possible states of the economy, not just endogenous states. Assume T and T are the associated Markov and adjoint operators for this transition function, respectively. We can use these operators to construct a probability measure that characterizes the state of the economy endogenous and exogenous states) in each period. Recall again, that the states in this setting are random variables.) One question of particular interest is what are the asymptotic properties of the state? Given the probability measure over the state in a given period, say period t = 0, λ 0 ), according to the definition of adjoint operator, the probability measure for the next period s state is given by λ 1 = T λ. Similarly, the probability measure of the state in t = 2 is given by λ 2 = T λ 1 = T 2 λ 0. This way, we can construct a sequence of probability measures, {λ n } n 0. The question is, under what conditions, does this sequence converges to a limit in the weak convergence sense? A probability measure λ ) is called the invariant measure of the Markov process P ) if T λ = λ ; i.e. if λ ) is the unconditional probability of the state in period t, it will be the unconditional probability of the next period s state, as well. If we let λ 0 = λ, it is clear that λ n = λ for all n, and hence the sequence {λ n } n 0 converges to a limiting probability measure, λ. The important question is, if such an invariant measure exists, will {λ n } converge to it for 12

14 every initial distribution of the state, λ 0, in at least the weak convergence sense? If S is a compact subset of k-dimensional Euclidean space, by a powerful theorem in probability theory, Helly s Theorem, we can be sure that any transition function defined on S, S ) that has the Feller property, has an invariant measure. This invariant measure looks like a good candidate for the asymptotic distribution of the sequence of probability measures {λ n } n 0, constructed above. However, there is a major problem; the invariant measure might not be unique, and, hence, we cannot be sure in which one of these distributions we might end up in the limit. Figure 1, from Stokey et al. 1989), illustrates this problem; let S = [a, b] a compact subset of R), and let the transition function be defined as follows: for a given state s in period t, next period s state is a draw from the uniform distribution on the interval [h s), H s)]. You can check and see that the transition function corresponding to this process satisfies the Feller property. However, if we start at s = a with probability one, we will get stuck in the set E 1 forever, and, if we start from s = b with probability one, we end up in set E 2. To avoid this type of multiplicity of the asymptotic distribution, we impose the following assumption. Assumption 1 There exists c S, ε > 0, and N 1 such that P N a, [c, b]) ε and P N b, [a, c]) ε. Assumption 1 is know as mixing property; it says, if we give the process enough time, there is always a positive possibility of going from one tail of distribution to the other. Now, we are ready to state the main result of this class. Theorem 3 Let S = [a, b] R l. If P ) is monotone, has the Feller property, and satisfies Assumption 1, then P ) has a unique invariant probability measure λ ), and for all λ 0 Λ S, S ), T n λ 0 λ. 3 The Risk-Free Rate in Incomplete Economies You saw that, in the framework of Arrow-Debreu economies with a full set of securities, agents can perfectly insure themselves against idiosyncratic shocks. Huggett 1993) describes an economy in which the set of insurance instruments is not complete. Therefore, 13

15 Figure 1. Multiple Ergodic Sets 14

16 agents face the risk of fluctuations in their consumption. In the absence of complete insurance instruments, agents have an incentive to over-accumulate assets. Thus, to discourage this over-saving and attain the equilibrium, the interest rate on the risk-free bonds must be lower than what it would be in a complete market. Our purpose is not to discuss the importance of the model, its relevance, or the intuition behind this; you would see and hear more about this in class. Instead, we want to prove a technical result that will have an important role in its implications. To this end, we will try to give a rough outline of the model. After that, we will jump immediately to the result we want to prove. 3.1 The Model Consider an exchange economy with a continuum of agents of measure one. In each period, agents receive an endowment of a non-storable consumption good, in the set E = {e l, e h }, where e h > e l. The stochastic process governing the endowments of each agent follows a Markov chain, that is characterized by transition function π ), and is independent across agents. We will assume π e e) > 0, for all e, e E. Agents maximize the expected value of their lifetime utility, which is represented by the following utility function: [ E t=0 β t c1 σ) 1 σ) where β 0, 1), and σ > 1. Agents budget constrains is given by c + qa a + e, ], where c 0, and a ā. Here, q is the constant price of the assets, and ā is the lower bound on agents credit balances. If we let X = A E be the state-space, for A = [ā, ), for an agent with individual state x X, the functional equation describing agent s decision problem is then given by v x; q) = max a Γx;q) { c 1 σ) 1 σ) + β } v a, e ; q) π e e), 8) e 15

17 where Γ x; q) = {c, a ) c + qa a + e, c 0, a ā}. We will denote the policy functions associated with this functional equation by c x; q) and a x; q). Naturally, this equation describes a mapping of the form T v x; q) = max a Γx;q) { c 1 σ) 1 σ) + β } v a, e ; q) π e e). e It is straightforward to infer, from what we have seen so far, that if q > 0 and ā+el āq > 0, then, T ) defines a contraction mapping and there is a unique bounded continuous function defined over X, v ) C X), that solves the functional equation in 8). Moreover, v ) is strictly increasing, strictly concave, and continuously differentiable in a. Moreover, c ) and a ) are continuous functions, and a ) is non-decreasing in a, and strictly increasing in a for x; q) so that a x; q) > ā. In addition, c a, e) is strictly increasing in a. Exercise 1 Prove the statements of last paragraph. 3.2 Theorem 2 in Huggett 1993) We do not intend to discuss the importance of Huggett 1993) s model, or its implications. Our goal is to prove a rather technical theorem that drives these implications. To be able to state and quite understand) Theorem 2 in Huggett 1993), we first have to prove the following lemma. Lemma 1 Suppose q > 0, ā + el āq > 0, β < q, and π eh e h ) π π h e l ). Then, there is a subset of the state-space, S = [ā, ā] E X, with the property that, if an agent starts out in S, then he in fact, his state) will remain in S. To prove this result, we will follow the following steps. Lemma 2 Under the conditions of Lemma 1, a a, e l ) < a, for a > ā. Proof. To prove this, we follow a variation argument as follows; suppose this was not the case, and there exists some a A so that a a, e l ) a. In particular, assume a a, e l ) = a > ā the argument for a a, e l ) > a follows a similar argument, so, this assumption will not 16

18 cause any loss in generality). Suppose the agent increases this period s consumption by qɛ, by decreasing her savings by ɛ. This change will increase this periods utility by q e l + a qa) σ ɛ = q e l + 1 q) a) σ ɛ, while having a discounted expected utility cost of β [π e h e l ) v a, e h ; q) + π e l e l ) v a, e l ; q)] ɛ. By envelope condition, we can write this as β [ π e h e l ) e h + a qa ) σ + π e l e l ) e l + a qa) σ] ɛ, where a = a a, e h ). Note that, e + a qa ) σ = c a, e) σ. So, if we could show c a, e) is non-decreasing in its second argument, then β [ π e h e l ) e h + a qa ) σ + π e l e l ) e l + a qa) σ] β e l + a qa) σ. Then, since q/β > 1, by assumption, we could write: q e l + a qa) σ ɛ β [π e h e l ) v a, e h ; q) + π e l e l ) v a, e l ; q)] ɛ. This means, a decrease of savings by ɛ would increase the expected utility of the agent, and hence a a, e l ) = a would not be an optimal decision. It remains to show c a, e) is non-decreasing in e. Exercise 2 Prove that c a, e) is non-decreasing in e. Lemma 3 If v a, e) > β/q) E [v a, e ) e] for a a > ā, then a a, e) < a for a a. Proof. If a a, e) = ā, we are done. The first order condition for an agent s problem, when a a, e) > ā, is q e + a qa a, e)) σ = β [π e h e) v a a, e), e h ; q) + π e l e) v a a, e), e l ; q)]. 9) 17

19 By envelope condition: e + a qa a, e)) σ = v a, e). Since v ) is concave, for the equality in 9) to hold when a a, we must have a a, e) < a. Lemma 4 Under the conditions of Lemma 1, there exists a A so that a a, e h ) = a. Proof. Suppose this was not the case, so that a a, e h ) > a, for all a A. By Lemma 2, we know that a a, e l ) < a. Therefore, a a, e h ) > a a, e l ), for all a. Thus: a + e l qa a, e h ) a + e l qa a, e l ), c a, e h ) e h e l ) c a, e l ), c a, e l) c a, e h ) 1 e h e l ) c a, e h ). Concavity and monotonicity of v implies that v a 1, e) v a 2, e) > 0, for all a 2 a 1. As mentioned above, c a, e) is strictly increasing in a. But, v ) is bounded and strictly increasing. Therefore, lim a v a, e) must be zero. By envelope condition, v a, e) = u c a, e)) = c a, e) σ. Therefore, as a, c a, e) must tend to infinity. As a result, as a, we have: v a, e h ) v a, e l ) = [ ] σ [ c a, el ) 1 e ] σ h e l ) = 1. c a, e h ) c a, e h ) This means, since β/q < 1, there is some a, large enough, so that v a, e h ) v a, e l ) β q, for a a. As we proved in Lemma 2, v a, e h ) v a, e l ). Therefore, the hypothesis of Lemma 3 will hold, and this is a contradiction. Lemma 2 and 4 imply that the policy function a a, e), looks like the one depicted in Figure 2. As it is apparent in this figure, there is an interval in A, which we denote by S = [ā, ā], so that, when the agent s asset holdings is in S, it will stay in the same set. This proves our claim in Lemma 1. 18

20 Figure 2. Existence of an Ergodic Set 19

21 Now that we know we can restrict our attention to a compact subset of R, as the space of endogenous state, we can check as see whether the hypothesis of convergence theorem of the Markov processes that we stated last class are satisfies or not. 4 A Shopping Time Monetary Economy In a complete market model, fiat currency i.e. money that has no intrinsic value and is not convertible into goods that do) would be valueless. To see why this is the case, consider an agent that holds positive amount of money. A necessary condition for this decision to be optimal is transversality: lim t [ t 1 s=0 ] 1 m t+1 = r s ) p t A no arbitrage argument implies that the real return on money, p t /p t+1, has to be equal to 1 + r t in order for the agents to hold money. Thus: t 1 s=0 t r s ) = s=0 = p t p 0. p s+1 p s If we substitute this into the transversality condition, we have: m t+1 lim = 0. t p 0 Thus, if we consider the inconvertible money one for which lim t m t+1 > 0), p 0 = ; i.e. money must have no value. Therefore, to assign positive value to money, we have to alter the complete market structure in some way. Today, we do this by means of introducing a shopping technology to the economy, so that buying consumption goods requires time and effort, and this effort is decreasing in the real balances an agent holds. You are going to see how we can do this in the context of cash-in-advance models, in class. 20

22 4.1 The Model Consider an endowment economy with a single type of representative households. Household is endowed with one unit of time, and y units of consumption good in each period. Its preferences are represented by the following utility function over consumption and leisure: β t u c t, l t ). t=0 To acquire the consumption good, household has to spend some shopping time; specifically, purchasing c t units of consumption good, when household is holding m t+1 /p t units of real balances, calls for s t units of shopping time. s t, c t, and m t+1 /p t are related according to the following shopping technology: < 0. An example of such a func- where we assume H, H c, H c,c, H m p, m p tion is s t = H c t, m ) t+1, p t > 0, and H m p, H c, m p s t = c t m t+1 /p t ɛ. Even though this is not quite intuitive, you can think of s t as the effort, when an individual pays for his purchases in cash, and he does not want to carry around more than m t+1 of it. Therefore, to purchase c t, he has to go p t c t /m t+1 times to the bank. If each time takes ɛ of effort, the total effort would be s t. Given that an individual has to allocate his time between leisure and shopping, he faces a constraint of the form l t + s t = 1, every period. The government, in this economy, has to finance a stream of exogenous expenditures, {g t } t=0, through fiscal and monetary policy, characterized by lump-sum taxation, τ, issuing debt, B, and printing money, M. 4.2 General Equilibrium The notion of competitive equilibrium in this economy is exactly what you would expect it to be. 21

23 Definition 1 Given {g t, τ t } t=0, B 0 = b 0, and M 0 = m 0 > 0, an equilibrium in this economy is a price system,{p t, R t } t=0, an allocation for the households, {c t, l t, s t, b t, m t } t=0, a government policy, {M t, B t } t=1, so that: 1. given the price system and taxes, {c t, l t, s t, b t, m t } t=0 solves household s problem, given by max {c t,l t,s t,b t,m t} β t u c t, l t ) 10) t=0 s.t. c t + m t+1 p t + b t+1 R t s t + l t = 1 s t = H c t, m ) t+1, p t y + m t p t + b t τ t 2. government runs a balanced budget; g t + B t = τ t + B t+1 R t + M t+1 M t p t, t 0, 11) 3. and, markets clear in each period t 0; a) c t + g t = y, b) M t = m t, c) and B t = b t. Note that, B t in the definition of equilibrium is the government s debt to the private sector, maturing at the beginning of period t, and M t is the total supply of money. R t is the gross rate of return, therefore 1/R t is the face value of government or private) debt Money Demand Given this solution concept, for the usual functional forms for the utility function that we have seen so far, an equilibrium allocation must satisfy the following first order conditions: 1. u c c t, l t ) = λ t + µ t H c c t, m t+1 p t ), 22

24 2. u c c t, l t ) = µ t, 3. λ t R t = βλ t+1, 4. and, λt p t = β λ t+1 p t+1 µt p t H m p c t, m t+1 p t ), where β t λ t is the Lagrange multiplier on the household s budget constraint, and β t µ t is the multiplier on the shopping technology. If we multiply 4 by p t, we get: Denoting p t /p t+1 by Rt m write this equality as: λ t = βλ t+1 p t p t+1 µ t H m p c t, m ) t+1. p t the real return of money), as we did in the introduction, we can λ t = βλ t+1 R m t After substituting for βλ t+1 from 3, we get: µ t H m p c t, m ) t+1. p t ) 1 Rm t λ t = µ t H m c p t, m ) t+1. 12) R t p t Now, we can substitute for λ t from 1, and for µ t from 2, to get: ) 1 Rm t [u c c t, l t ) u c c t, l t ) H c c t, m )] t+1 = u c c t, l t ) H m c p t, m ) t+1, R t p t p t which can be simplified more into: ) [ 1 Rm t uc c t, l t ) R t u c c t, l t ) H c c t, m )] t+1 + H m c p t, m ) t+1 = 0. 13) p t p t Noting that l t = 1 H c t, m t+1 /p t ), this equation defines a money demand function implicitly of the form m t+1 p t = F ) c t, Rm t. 14) R t 23

25 The important remark about this function is that it is increasing in both its arguments, if we note that the coefficient on the left hand side of 13) is positive. To see why this is the case, consider the equality in 12) once more; since H m < 0, for the agents to hold positive p amounts of both money and government bonds in any given period, we must have ) 1 Rm t 0. R t This, in fact, is a no arbitrage condition; if the real return on money was greater than that of bonds, agents could make arbitrary large amount of profit by accumulating debt and holding money. Not only would this give them the opportunity to decrease their shopping time, but also would give them unbounded profit. Question Why the inverse can still be true? Why can we have Rt m R t in equilibrium? This is due the transaction technology; households want real balances to carry out their transactions. Therefore, even when the real return on money is less than that of bonds, they would choose to hold money in equilibrium, though, money demand is increasing in the return of money. This feature of this economy breaks down the no arbitrage relation between money and bonds, and creates value for money, unlike the complete market economy, discussed at the beginning of this section Equilibrium Determination We will focus on the government policies with g t = g, t 0, τ t = τ, t 1, B t = B, t 1, and τ 0 and B 0 that are potentially different from τ and B. This enables us to study the equilibria in which the economy moves from an initial state at t = 0 short-run equilibrium) to a stationary path from date t = 1 onward long-run equilibrium). Notice that, when g t = g for all t 0, from the good s market clearing condition in the equilibrium, c t = c = y g for all t 0. Seeking a stationary equilibrium from date t = 1, 24

26 we also need I don t know why wee need these in the initial period as well!) p t p t+1 = R m, t 0, R t = R, t 0, s t = s, t 0. Since l t = 1 s t = l for all t 0 in this equilibrium, from conditions 1 and 2 of household s optimization problem: u c c t, l t ) = λ t + u c c t, l t ) H c c t, m ) t+1, p t λ t+1 λ t = 1. If we substitute this result into condition 3, we get: R t = 1 β. Moreover, since c t is constant in all dates, we can write 14) as m t+1 p t = f R m ). 15) As we noted earlier, f R m ) 0. Now, if we substitute this into government s budget constraint for t 1, we have: R 1) g τ + B R = 1 R m ) f R m ). 16) The right hand side of this equation is government s revenue from printing currency know as seigniorage). Since we require R m to be constant at all dates, from the money demand equation, M 1 /p 0 = 25

27 f R m ). Therefore, government s budget constraint at date t = 0 can be written as: g + B 0 = τ 0 + B R + M 1 p 0 M 0 p 0, g + B 0 = τ 0 + B R + f Rm ) M 0 p 0. 17) Equations 15), 16), and 17) completely characterize equilibrium; from 16), given R = β 1, we can calculate R m, and use it to determine p 0. Given p 0, we can pin down the sequence of prices, and money supply that supports this equilibrium through 15) and definition of R m. 4.3 A Few Monetary Doctrines Having a monetary model at our disposal, we can use it to study different government policies. In what follows, we give examples of some monetary doctrines, and address the model implications regarding them Quantity Theory of Money Suppose we increase the initial money supply, M 0, by some factor γ, while leaving all the other variables unchanged. From Equations 16) and 17), we can see that such a change would only increase the initial price level and sequence of money supplies by the same factor, γ, while leaving everything else intact Sustained Deficit Causes Inflation If we draw the graph of 1 R m ) f R m ) for a utility function of the form u c, l) = and a shopping technology of the form c1 δ 1 δ) + l1 α 1 α), H c, m) = c 1 + m, 26

28 it would look like an inverse U-curve for standard parameter values). Thus, for a given level of government deficit, g τ + B R 1) in Equation 16), there are two levels of real R return on money that can be sustained in equilibrium. If we choose the higher level as the favorable policy note that, higher rate of return on money corresponds to lower levels of inflation), then an increase in the government deficit would result in a decrease in R m ; this is in accordance with the classical point of view that sustained deficit would increase inflation Optimality of Friedman Rule What is the optimal level of real balances in this economy? The social value of real balances in this economy is to decrease the shopping time, and leave the households with more leisure time. By increasing the rate of return on money, government can increase the real balances, as shown by Equation 15). On the other hand, government can run a surplus, by financing it trough τ. This implies, through Equation 16), that it can achieve any level of R m 1, β 1 ). This would lead to an increase in welfare, and is in accordance with Friedman s idea of satiating the economy with real balances, as much as possible. 5 A New-Keynesian Model You were introduced to a monopolistic competition model with price rigidities in class where only a constant fraction of firms, the so-called flexible-price firms, could change their prices after the realization of a shock; the rest had to set their prices at the beginning of each period and keep their promise of delivering the demand after the realization of exogenous shocks. Today, we are going to present a similar basic New-Keynesian model in which monopolistic firms can adjust their prices in each period with a constant probability of 1 θ. This is based on the staggered price-setting model of Calvo 1983). Thus, after the price is set, the expected duration of this price being effective is 1/ 1 θ). This creates a so-called!!) micro-founded rigidity in aggregate price level. To make this interesting, imagine there is a fairy in this economy, which we refer to as Calvo fairy! This fictitious being appears at the beginning of each period t, chooses fraction 1 θ) of firms 27

29 randomly and taps them on the shoulder, giving them the permission to change their prices. This story occurs in every period. A more realistic story is that there are small costs of changing prices in this economy, referred to as menu costs. So that, in each period, only a fraction θ of firms find it too costly to adjust their prices to unanticipated shocks in economy. We will invite you to think about the difference of these two settings, in terms of persistence of unanticipated nominal shocks in the economy! For a firm that sets its price in period t, there is a 1 θ) chance of resetting price next period. This means there is a 1 θ) probability of the price in t being in effect only in period t, without experiencing any rigidity in price. With probability θ, the firm has to keep its price fixed in period t + 1. So, the chance of a one-period price rigidity is θ 1 θ). Therefore, the expected length of price rigidity is θ k 1 θ) k, k=0 which is a geometric power series converging to 1 θ) 1. We are going to study the implications of such assumptions for the neutrality of monetary policy and nominal shocks in such an economy. 5.1 Households The economy is inhabited by an infinitely-lived representative household whose preferences over streams of consumption and labor are represented by the following utility function with expected form: E 0 t=0 where C t is a consumption index, given by [ 1 C t := 0 β t U C t, N t ), C t i) ɛ 1 ɛ ] ɛ ɛ 1 di. Here, C t i) is the consumption of a differentiated good indexed by i. We will assume there is an exogenous continuum of such goods in the economy, of unit mass. 28

30 The budget constraint of the household is given by 1 0 P t i) C t i) di + Q t B t B t 1 + W t N t + T t, where p t i) is the price of variety i, B t is a one-period risk free bond with face value price Q t, W t is the wage rate, and T t is the lump-sum transfers to the households possibly in terms of profits, etc.). Thus, we may write the problem of the household as: max E 0 β t U C t, N t ) t=0 [ 1 s.t. C t = C t i) ɛ 1 ɛ ] ɛ ɛ 1 di P t i) C t i) di + Q t B t B t 1 + W t N t + T t lim E t B t ) 0, T where the last condition rules out the possibility of Ponzi schemes in the economy. Exercise 1 What is the difference between condition lim T E t B t ) 0, and the no-ponzi scheme condition you have seen previously e.g. in Tim s course)? Which one is more strict? We can think of a household s problem in period t as consisting of two parts: deciding about the fraction of wealth household wants to allocate to consumption, and dividing this fraction between different varieties of consumption goods. We begin with the latter; i.e. given amount W of wealth dedicated to consumption and price of each differentiated good, how would household divide W between varieties. Given a constant amount of wealth, W, spent on consumption in period t, 1 0 P t i) C t i) di = W, 29

31 we can write the problem of the household as choosing between the different varieties as: max Ci) U C, N) [ 1 s.t. C = C i) ɛ 1 ɛ ] ɛ ɛ 1 di P i) C i) di = W. The first order condition for the optimal consumption of variety i is: U C C, N) C i) ɛ 1 ɛ ɛ [ 1 0 C k) ɛ 1 ɛ ] ɛ ɛ+1 ɛ 1 dk = λp i), i [0, 1], where λ is the Lagrange multiplier on the constraint of the problem. By writing the same condition for variety j, and dividing the two equations, we have: C i) 1/ɛ P i) = 1/ɛ C j) P j), [ ] ɛ P j) C i) = C j). P i) If we substitute this result into the definition of consumption index, we get: and, hence: C = C = [ 1 0 [ 1 0 [[ ] ɛ ɛ 1 ] ɛ ɛ 1 P j) ɛ C j)] di, P i) [ ] ɛ 1 P j) C j) ɛ 1 ɛ di P i) ] ɛ ɛ 1 P j) ɛ C j) = [ ] ɛ C, 1 P 0 i)1 ɛ ɛ 1 di [ ] ɛ P j) C j) = C, 18) P, 30

32 where: [ 1 P := 0 ] 1 1 ɛ P i) 1 ɛ di. 19) We will refer to Equation 18) as the demand function for variety j, as a function of its price P j), aggregate consumption index C, and aggregate price index P. To see the intuition behind the aggregate price index, let us substitute this result back into the constraint of the optimization problem above, to get: W = = P i) C i) di [ ] ɛ P i) P i) Cdi P 0 = P i)1 ɛ di [ 1 P 0 i)1 ɛ di [ 1 = P i) 1 ɛ di 0 =P.C. ] ɛ 1 ɛ C ] 1+ ɛ 1 ɛ C Therefore, we may write the first part of a household s problem simply as: max E 0 β t U C t, N t ) s.t. t=0 P t C t + Q t B t B t 1 + W t N t + T t lim E t B t ) 0, T where P t is defined in 19). The first order conditions for this problem are: 1. β t U C C t, N t ) = P t λ t, 2. β t U N C t, N t ) = W t λ t, 3. and Q t λ t = s t+1 λ t+1 s t+1 ) where s t+1 is an index for next period s state). If we combine conditions 1 and 2, we get the intratemporal optimality condition for labor 31

33 supply: U N C t, N t ) U C C t, N t ) = W t P t. 20) Moreover, we can derive the Euler equation by combining 2 and 3: Q t = βe t UC C t+1, N t+1 ) U C C t, N t ) P t P t+1 ). 21) Remark To see how we can derive this, assume for the moment that next period s state is given by s t. Then: β t U C C t, N t ) Q t = β t+1 U C C t+1 s t+1 ), N t+1 s t+1 )) P t P s t+1 s t+1 ) t+1 21) can be derived using this equality. =β t+1 E t U C C t+1, N t+1 ) P t+1. Now, if we assume that the period utility takes the following separable form, then, we can write 21) as: U C, N) = 1 = E t β 1 Q t C σ t+1 C σ t which can be written in natural log terms as: C1 σ 1 σ) N 1+φ 1 + φ), P t P t+1 ), 1 = E t exp log β + i t σ c t+1 π t+1 )). 22) The lower case letters indicate the logarithm of the variables. i t is defined as log 1/Q t ). Remark i t is the net nominal rate of return. To see why, note that the gross nominal rate of 32

34 return is 1/Q t. If we denote this by 1 + i t, then: ) 1 log 1 + i t ) = log Q t i t. On a balanced growth path, where consumption grows at a constant rate γ, we have: i = log β + σγ + π. A first order Taylor expansion of 22) around the balanced growth path yields: exp log β + i t σ c t+1 π t+1 ) 1 + log β + i t σ c t+1 π t+1. If we substitute this result into Equation 22), we get a first order log-linearization of this condition: log β + i t σe t c t+1 c t ) E t π t+1 ) = 0, c t = E t c t+1 ) 1 σ [log β + i t E t π t+1 )]. 23) On the other hand, under the assumption of separable utility form, we may write Equation 20) as: N φ t C σ t In logarithmic terms, we can rewrite this as: = W t P t. w t p t = σc t + φn t. 24) To introduce money explicitly in the model, we add an ad-hoc log-linear money demand equation to the household side of the economy as well: m t p t = y t ηi t. This equation, determines the path of nominal interest rate i t as a function of exogenous 33

35 money supply M t in the equilibrium. To see the intuition behind this money demand function, consider the following problem faced by a household that values money holdings we have seen how such a utility form may emerge from a monetary economy): max s.t. [ E 0 β t t=0 Ct 1 σ 1 σ) + M t/p t ) 1 ν 1 ν) ] N 1+φ t 1 + φ) P t C t + Q t B t + M t B t 1 + M t 1 + W t N t + T t lim E t B t ) 0. T The first order conditions for the household are: 1. β t C σ t = P t λ t, 2. β t 1 P t Mt P t ) ν = λt λ t+1, 3. and Q t λ t = λ t+1. If we substitute from 3 and 1 into 2, we get: β t 1 ) ν Mt = 1 Q t ) β t 1 P t P t Mt P t ) ν = 1 Q t ) C σ t. P t C σ t, Using our definition of nominal rate of return, we may write this condition as: M t /P t ) ν C σ t = 1 e it i t. Now, if we take the natural logarithm, we may write this equation as follows: m t p t = σ ν c t 1 ν log 1 e it) σ ν c t 1 ν e it 1) i t. 34

36 Assuming unit elasticity of real) money demand with respect to consumption i.e. σ/ν = 1) and incorporating market clearing condition, then, imply: m t p t = y t ηi t. 5.2 Firms There is a continuum of monopolistically competitive firms in the economy that produce a differentiated good according to the same technology, given by: Y t i) = A t N t i). Firm i faces a demand function of the form in 18), and takes the aggregate price index P t and aggregate consumption index C t as given. In each period, fraction 1 θ of the firms have the chance to adjust their prices while fraction θ has to keep their price fixed and meet the demand in the market). Therefore, the average interval between price changes for a firm is 1/ 1 θ). In this sense, θ is an index of price stickiness in this economy. The problem faced by a firm that is chosen in period t to adjust its price can be written as: max p t k=0 s.t. Y t+k t = θ k E t Qt,t+k P t Y t+k t Ψ t+k Yt+k t ))) ) P ɛ t C t+k, P t+k where Ψ is the cost function. Q t,t+k is the stochastic discount factor; it determines how 35

37 future nominal profits are discounted in date t s utility terms, and can be evaluated as: k 1 ) Q t,t+k =E t Q t+s s=0 k 1 UC C t+s+1, N t+s+1 ) =E t βe t+s U s=0 C C t+s, N t+s ) ) =β k UC C t+k, N t+k ) P t E t, U C C t, N t ) P t+k P t+s P t+s+1 where the second equality follows from the Law of Iterated Expectations. It is clear that any firm tapped by the Calvo fairy to adjust its price would face the same problem in period t. Therefore, all the firms adjusting prices in period t would choose If we substitute for Y t+k t into the objective function, we can rewrite the problem of the monopolist as: ) ) max P t k=0 θ k E t Qt,t+k P t ) 1 ɛ P ɛ t+kc t+k Ψ t+k P t ) ɛ P ɛ t+kc t+k ))) The first order condition for this problem, with respect to the control Pt yields:: ))) θ k E t Q t,t+k 1 ɛ) Pt ) ɛ Pt+kC ɛ t+k + ɛ Pt ) ɛ 1 Pt+kC ɛ Ψ t+k Yt+k t t+k = 0. Y t+k t k=0 If we substitute back Y t+k t, we get: ))) θ k E t Q t,t+k 1 ɛ) Y t+k t + ɛ Pt ) 1 Ψ t+k Yt+k t Y t+k t = 0. Y t+k t k=0 If we multiply both sides of the equality by P t / 1 ɛ), we have: k=0 )) θ k E t Q t,t+k Y t+k t Pt ɛ ɛ 1) ψ t+k t = 0, where ψ t+k t := Ψ t+k Yt+k t ) / Yt+k t is the nominal marginal cost of the firm in period t + k. 36

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 47 Introduction Authors:

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Slides II - Dynamic Programming Slides II - Dynamic Programming Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides II - Dynamic Programming Spring 2017 1 / 32 Outline 1. Lagrangian

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí November 2 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí June 28 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination January 2016 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 3 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Chapter 5: The government budget deficit Ben J. Heijdra Department of Economics & Econometrics University of Groningen 1 September 2009 Foundations of

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter 6 1 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 203 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 48 minutes Part B (Prof. Aghion): 48

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Lawrence Christiano and Yuta Takahashi July 26, 2018 Multiple Equilibria Standard NK Model Standard, New Keynesian (NK) Monetary Model: Taylor rule satisfying Taylor

More information

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction The New Keynesian Model: Introduction Vivaldo M. Mendes ISCTE Lisbon University Institute 13 November 2017 (Vivaldo M. Mendes) The New Keynesian Model: Introduction 13 November 2013 1 / 39 Summary 1 What

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession ONLINE APPENDIX INVESTMENT HANGOVER A1 Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession By MATTHEW ROGNLIE, ANDREI SHLEIFER, AND ALP SIMSEK APPENDIX A: CALIBRATION This appendix describes

More information

TheTimeConsistencyof Monetary and Fiscal Policies

TheTimeConsistencyof Monetary and Fiscal Policies Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department TheTimeConsistencyof Monetary and Fiscal Policies Fernando Alvarez, Patrick J. Kehoe, and Pablo Neumeyer Working Paper 616 April 2002 ABSTRACT Are

More information

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) subject to for all t Jonathan Heathcote updated, March 2006 1. The household s problem max E β t u (c t ) t=0 c t + a t+1

More information

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE LECTURE 3. POLICY INTERACTIONS WITH TAX DISTORTIONS Eric M. Leeper Indiana University September 2008 THE MESSAGES Will study three models with distorting taxes First draws

More information

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B Lecture 2 Giulio Fella c Giulio Fella, 2014 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B - Lecture 2 40/197 Aim of consumption theory Consumption theory aims at explaining consumption/saving decisions

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018 Lecture 2 (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings Erick Sager February 6, 2018 Econ 606: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Spring 2018 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (2/6/18)

More information

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics Thomas M. Mertens NYU Stern Risk Economics Lab April 17, 2012 1 / 78 Motivation Many problems in finance and economics are high dimensional. Dynamic Optimization:

More information

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t )

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t ) Eco504, Part II Spring 2006 C. Sims FTPL WITH MONEY 1. FTPL WITH MONEY This model is that of Sims (1994). Agent: [ ] max E β t log C t {C t,m t,b t } t=0 s.t. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) + M t + B t + τ t R t

More information

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Diego Daruich March 28, 2014 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Motivation The objective of these notes will be to develop tools from measure theory and probability to allow

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University March 26, 2012 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg () Stochastic Dynamic Programming March 26, 2012 1 / 31 References

More information

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown September, 2017 Introduction Early heterogeneous-agent models integrated the income-fluctuation problem into general equilibrium models. A key

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, 2017 9:00 am - 2:00 pm INSTRUCTIONS Please place a completed label (from the label sheet provided) on the

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination August 2016 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 4 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

0. Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides Monetary Policy, 7/3 2018 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen "0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic

More information

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016 Christian Groth A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics February 15, 216 (3-hours closed book exam) 1 As formulated in the course description, a score of 12 is

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are: Econ 510a second half Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #5 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, December 8 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Solution 1. a In the Mehra-Prescott

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 1 - Solution Professor Gianluca Violante, TA: Diego Daruich New York University Spring 2014 1 Problem 1 Consider a two-sector version of the neoclassical growth model,

More information

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2 SGZ Macro Week 3, : Suboptimal Equilibria 1 Basic Points Effects of shocks can be magnified (damped) in suboptimal economies Multiple equilibria (stationary states, dynamic paths) in suboptimal economies

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

Thetimeconsistencyoffiscal and monetary policies

Thetimeconsistencyoffiscal and monetary policies Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report November 2001 Thetimeconsistencyoffiscal and monetary policies Fernando Alvarez University of Chicago Patrick J. Kehoe Federal Reserve

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Gerzensee, August 27 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004 Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 5b (Part I), Spring 2004. Consider an exchange economy with two (types of) consumers. Type-A consumers comprise fraction λ of the economy s population and type-b

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-2010 Macroeconomics II Franck Portier Homework 1 Problem I An AD-AS Model Let us consider an economy with three agents (a firm, a household and a government) and four

More information

1 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

1 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Feb 5th, 2007 Let s write the SPP problem in sequence representation: max {c t,k t+1 } t=0 β t u(f(k t ) k t+1 ) t=0 k 0 given Because of the INADA conditions we know that the solution is interior. So

More information

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Ömer Özak SMU Macroeconomics II Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 78 Preliminaries Introduction Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Solow model: constant

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

Housing with overlapping generations

Housing with overlapping generations Housing with overlapping generations Chiara Forlati, Michael Hatcher, Alessandro Mennuni University of Southampton Preliminary and Incomplete May 16, 2015 Abstract We study the distributional and efficiency

More information

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017 Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Econ 50a second half) Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 7 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.. This problem introduces wealth inequality

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set 10. - Solutions Question 1 1. AUTARKY Autarky implies that the agents do not have access to credit or insurance markets. This implies that you cannot trade across

More information

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 4 - Solution

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 4 - Solution Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 4 - olution Professor Gianluca Violante, TA: Diego Daruich New York University pring 2014 Problem 1 Time is discrete and indexed by t {0, 1,..., }. The economy is populated

More information

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Problem Set 4 Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Instructions: You may consult with other members of the class, but please make sure to turn in your own work. Where

More information

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

Gali (2008), Chapter 3 Set 4 - The Basic New Keynesian Model Gali (28), Chapter 3 Introduction There are several key elements of the baseline model that are a departure from the assumptions of the classical monetary economy.

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination August 2015 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 4 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Francisco A. Gallego 05/11 1 Money as a Factor of Production (Dornbusch and Frenkel, 1973) The shortcut used by Dornbusch and Frenkel to introduce money in

More information

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Consumption and Savings Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model Lecture 10 Topics in Macroeconomics November 6, 2007 Lecture 10 1/18 Topics in Macroeconomics Consumption and Savings Outline

More information

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks 14.452. Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks Olivier Blanchard April 2006 Nr. 1 1. What starting point? Want to start with a model with at least two ingredients: Shocks, so uncertainty.

More information

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy Luigi Paciello Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University March 200 Abstract Should the central bank care whether

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Schumpeterian Growth Models Schumpeterian Growth Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch14 Introduction Most process innovations either increase the quality of an existing

More information

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes. 14.452. Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes. Olivier Blanchard May 12, 2007 Nr. 1 Look at three issues: Time consistency. The inflation bias. The trade-off between inflation and activity. Implementation and

More information

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics DSGE-Models Calibration and Introduction to Dynare Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de Summer 2012 Willi Mutschler

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Roberto Robatto March 12, 2014 Abstract I present an irrelevance proposition for some open market operations that exchange money and

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions George-Marios Angeletos Jennifer La O July 2017 How should fiscal and monetary policy respond to business cycles when firms have imperfect information

More information

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM This is a 90-minute exam. Answer all three questions, each of which is worth 30 points. You can get partial credit for partial answers. Do not spend disproportionate

More information

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model Supplemental material for: Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model Fernando Alvarez University of Chicago and NBER Marcelo Veracierto Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago This document

More information

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default, Econometrica 2000 Notes on Alvarez Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000 Jonathan Heathcote November 1st 2005 1 Model Consider a pure exchange economy with I agents one

More information