Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) Norm: Stochastic Case

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) Norm: Stochastic Case"

Transcription

1 Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) Norm: Stochastic Case Alexander Mafusalov, Stan Uryasev RESEARCH REPORT 03-5 Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering 303 Weil Hall, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL 36. s: First draft: April 03, This draft: August 04 Correspondence should be addressed to: Stan Uryasev Abstract The concept of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) is used in various applications in uncertain environment. This paper introduces CVaR norm for a random variable, which is by denition CVaR of absolute value of this random variable. It is proved that CVaR norm is indeed a norm in the space of random variables. CVaR norm is dened in two variations: scaled and non-scaled. L- and L-innity norms are limiting cases of the CVaR norm. In continuous case, scaled CVaR norm is a conditional expectation of the random variable. A similar representation of CVaR norm is valid for discrete random variables. Several properties for scaled and non-scaled CVaR norm, as a function of condence level, were proved. Dual norm for CVaR norm is proved to be the maximum of L- and scaled L-innity norms. CVaR norm, as a Measure of Error, generates a Regular Risk Quadrangle. Negative CVaR function, which is a non convex extension for CVaR norm, is introduced analogously to function L-p for p <. Linear regression problems were solved by minimizing CVaR norm of regression residuals. Keywords: CVaR norm, L p norm, Conditional Value-at-Risk, CVaR

2 . Introduction The concept of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) is widely used in risk management and various applications in uncertain environment. This paper introduces a concept of CVaR norm in the space of random variables. CVaR norm in R n was introduced and developed in [7], [5]. This section provides a short introduction in the CVaR norm in R n and shows the relation with the CVaR norm in the space of random variables. Also, we consider special cases of CVaR norm for random variables with discrete and continuous distributions and provide some examples. The negative CVaR function is dened, both in R n and in the space of random variables, which is an extension of CVaR norm (but it is not actually a norm). Section. gives a formal denition of CVaR norm in stochastic case and proves that CVaR norm is indeed a norm. This section also shows an equivalence of denitions for special cases given in the introductory section and the general denition. CVaR norm is a parametric family of norms with respect to the condence parameter α. Section. proves properties of CVaR norm as a function of α. Section.3 denes the dual norm to the CVaR norm and proves several basic statements about normed space generated by the CVaR norm (Banach and reexive space). Section.4 gives a short introduction to the concept of Risk Quadrangle (see [9]). We dene the quadrangle generated by the CVaR norm as a measure of error and we prove that this quadrangle is regular. Section 3 denes the negative CVaR function and proves several basic properties. Section 4 illustrates properties of CVaR norm with a case study. The concept of this paper is motivated by applications of norms in optimization. We consider norms in R n and in the space of random variables. We use symbols x and x i for a vector and an i-th vector component in R n, i.e. x = (x,..., x n ). We use symbol X for a random variable. l p norms are broadly used in R n, and L p norms are considered in the space of random variables. For p [, ] the norms l p and L p are dened as follows : ( ) /p n l p (x) = x i p, L p (X) = (E X p ) /p, n i= where E is the expectation sign. The most popular cases are p =,,, i.e., l (x) = n n i= x i, L (X) = E X ; l (x) = max i=,...,n x i, L (X) = sup X ; l (x) = ( n n i= x i ) /, L (X) = (EX ) / ; It is known that l (x) l (x) l (x) and L (X) L (X) L (X), see []. Also, the following inequalities holds: l p (x) l q (x) and L p (X) L q (X) for p < q, see []. Note that the classic denition for l p norm is l p (x) = ( n i= x i p ) /p, it does not satisfy inequality l p (x) l q (x) for p < q. This paper uses an equivalent scaled version of this norm l p (x) = ( n n i= x i p) /p, which satises that inequality. Lp norm is commonly dened as L p (f) = f p ( S f p dµ ) /p, where S is a considered space. It is known (see, e.g., []) that for p and q norms inequality f p µ(s) p q f q holds for p q, where S is a considered space and µ(s) is the measure of the space S. When S is a probability space, µ(s) = and inequality L p (X) L q (X) holds for p q, where L p (X) = (E X p ) /p and E is an expectation sign.

3 Further we will illustrate the general concept of CVaR norm in R n, as well as in spaces of discrete and continuous random variables. CVaR norm in R n is considered in [7] and [5]. According to [7], the CVaR norm in x R n is dened as follows. Let x (i) be ordered absolute values of components of x R n, i.e. x,..., x n } = x (),..., x (n) }, and x (i) x (i+), for i =,..., n. Then, for j = 0,..., n and α j = j/n, scaled CVaR norm (or just CVaR norm in this paper) is dened by x S α j = ( x (j+) x (n) )/(n j). For j = n we have α j = j/n = and the norm is x S α n = x (i) = max i x i. For α j < α < α j+, the norm x S α equals to the weighted sum, where x S α = µ x S α j + ( µ) x S α j+, µ = (α j+ α)( α j ) (α j+ α j )( α). A similar norm, called D-norm, was introduced in [3] in a dierent way: for p [, n], M =,..., n}, S is cardinality of a set S, p = maxl Z l p} (i.e., p is a maximal integer number which is not greater than p) } x p = max S t}:s M, S p,t M\S} j S x j + (p p ) x t For α [ ] 0, n n, the CVaR norm coinsides with the D-norm x p with parameter p dened by p = n( α), see [7]. The second variant of the norm, called non-scaled CVaR norm, is dened in [7] as follows : ( α) x S x α = α, for 0 α < ; 0, for α =. For example, x j/n = ( x (j+) x (n) )/n. This paper shows that the α norm in R n can be considered as a special case of CVaR norm in the space of discrete random variables, which is dened in the following paragraph. Now, we consider CVaR norm for discretely distributed random variables. Suppose that a random variable X takes values x i } N i= with probabilities p i } N i=, and N i= p i =, where x i R and N N or N = (we use the notation N for the set of natural numbers). Let us denote by the sequence x (i) } N i= an ordered sequence x i } N i=, i.e. x (i) x (i+). Let us denote for discretely distributed X by p (i) } N i= a corresponding to the x (i) } N i= sequence of values from the p i } N i=, i.e. if x (i) corresponds to x j, then p (i) = p j. Let. In [7] it is dened as x α = n( α) x S α, but in this paper we will stick to slightly dierent denition in the sake of consistency with stochastic case, where X α = ( α) X S α. 3

4 us dene α j = j i= p (i). The non-scaled CVaR norm with condence level α j for the discretely distributed random variable X is dened by the following expression: N i=j+ X αj = ( α j )CVaR αj ( X ) = x (i) p (i), for j = 0,..., N ; 0, for j = N, here CV ar α ( X ) denotes conditional value at risk for random variable X, see [8]. If N =, then X αj = x (i) p (i), for j N. i=j+ Similarly to the denition of non-scaled CVaR norm in R n, for α j < α < α j+ the X α equals to the weighted sum X α = ( λ) X αj + λ X αj+, where λ = (α α j )/(α j+ α j ). If N = n, p i = /n and x = (x,..., x n ) R n, then the CVaR norm of X coincides with the deterministic CVaR norm of x: X α = x α. Let us illustrate the denition of non-scaled CVaR norm in stochastic case with the following example. Example. Consider the random variable X taking the values x i = i with the probabilities p i = i for i N. Since x i > 0 and x i < x i+, then x i = x (i). For α = α j, X αj = ( i ) i = i=j+ i=j+ For j, there is convergence α j and i 4 i = (j+) 4 (j+) 4 = j 4 j /3. X αj 0 = ( )CV ar ( X ). For α = 0., which is between α 0 = 0 and α = 0.5, the value X 0. is a weighted sum of X 0 and X 0.5 with coecient λ = (α α 0 )/(α α 0 ) = 0./0.5 = 0.4. We have therefore, X 0 = /3 = /3, X 0.5 = /3 =.5/3, X 0. = ( λ) X 0 + λ 0.5 X 0.5 = 0.6 / /3 =.7/ Figure shows a plot of X α depending upon α. Notice that X α is a non-increasing, concave and piecewise-linear function w.r.t. α. Paper [7] showed these properties for CVaR norm in R n. Section. proves these properties of X α in stochastic case. 4

5 0.7 non scaled CVaR norm X α α Figure : Non-scaled CVaR norm X α of random variable X with atoms x i = i and probabilities p i = i as a function of α. For discrete random variable X, the scaled CVaR norm is dened as follows: X S α α = X α, for α < ; sup X, for α =, where sup X denotes the essential supremum 3 of the random variable. If N = n, p i = /n and x = (x,..., x n ) R n, then X S α = x S α. Example. Consider the random variable X taking the values x i = i with the probabilities p i = i for i N. For α = α j, values of the X S α norm are: X S α j = j 4 j /3 j i= i = j 4 j /3 j = j /3. For j, there is convergence value α j and CVaR norm X S α j = X S = sup X. For α = 0., X S 0. = (./ /3)/ Figure shows a plot of X S α depending upon α. Notice that the norm is an increasing continuous function w.r.t. α. Paper [7] showed these properties for CVaR norm in R n. Section. proves these properties of X S α for stochastic case. 3 By denition, ess sup X = infa R P (X > a) = 0}. 5

6 scaled CVaR norm X α S α Figure : Scaled CVaR norm X α of random variable X with atoms x i = i and probabilities p i = i as a function of α. Furthermore, we consider the space of random variables with continuous distribution functions. This is an important special case. Let F X (x) be a continuous cumulative distribution function of a random variable X, and F X (α) be an inverse function to F X(x) (i.e., F X (F X(x)) = x), and q α (X) be an α-quantile of the random variable X (i.e., P (X q α (X)) = α, q α (X) = F X (α)). CVaR(X), in this case, is a conditional expectation: CV ar α (X) = E(X X > F X (α)), or, equivalently, CVaR α(x) = q α α p(x)dp, see [8]. In continuous case, the CVaR norm is dened as follows: X S α = CVaR α ( X ). We prove in Section. that CVaR norm is indeed a norm. Also, we show that X S 0 = L (X) and X S = L (X). We use the sign as a notation for words ¾distributed by. For example, X N (0, ) means that the random variable X is normally distributed with mean µ = 0 and variance σ =. Let us illustrate the denition of CVaR norm in the space of continuous random variables with the following example. Example 3. Consider an exponentially distributed random variable X Exp(λ) with the probability density function and with cumulative distribution function f X (x) = λe λx, x 0; 0, x < 0 }, F X (x) = e λx, x 0; 0, x < 0 }. () 6

7 Since X is a non negative random variable, then X = X. The expression () for F X (x) implies the following equation for quantile q α (X): e λqα(x) = α. Consequently, λq α (X) = ln( α), q α (X) = ln( α). λ For α =, the quantile q (X) =. Then, for α [0, ] X S α = [ ] xλe λx dx α q [ α(x) = q α (X)( α) + α = [ ln( α)]. λ = α ( λ ) e λx [ ( xe ) λx + q α(x) ] q α(x) = α q α(x) ] λe λx dx = [q α (X)( α) + λ ] ( α) = For α = 0, X S 0 = λ = EX = E X = L (X). For α =, X S = = sup X = sup X = L (X). Figure 3 shows a plot of the probability density function f X (x) of X and Figure 4 shows a plot of the function X S α as a function of α. Similar to the discrete distribution case, we consider the non-scaled CVaR norm: X α = ( α) X S α. CVaR α ( X )). It is easy to see that X α = E(I( X > F X (α)) X ), where I(A) is an indicator function:, if A is true; I(A) = 0, if A is false. Section. shows that the non-scaled CVaR norm is a decreasing concave function of α and changes from L (X) to 0 when α changes from 0 to. Let us illustrate the denition of non-scaled CVaR norm X α in the space of continuous random variables with the following example. Example 4. Consider an exponentially distributed random variable X Exp(λ). For α [0, ), the non-scaled CVaR norm equals X α = α [ ln( α)]. λ 7

8 probability density function f X (x) x Figure 3: Probability density function f X (x) for X Exp(). non scaled CVaR norm X α α Figure 4: Non-scaled CVaR norm X α for X Exp(), as a function of α. 8

9 8 scaled CVaR norm X α S α Figure 5: Scaled CVaR norm X S α for X Exp(), as a function of α. For α = 0, X α = λ = EX = E X = L (X). For α =, X α = 0. Figure 5 shows a plot of the function X α. 9

10 Risk Quadrangle denes risk R(X), deviation D(X), regret V(X), error E(X) and statistic S(X), satisfying some axioms, see [9]. Considered functionals can be regular or non-regular. further work that if R(X) is a regular Measure of Risk, than R( X ) is a norm and a regular Measure of Error. This paper proves that X α is a regular Measure of Error and nds the corresponding functions R(X), D(X), V(X) and S(X) in quadrangle generated by the Measure of Error E(X) = X α (see Section.4). This paper denes also non convex functions closely related to CVaR norm. In deterministic case, by denition, CVaR norm is the average of the biggest by absolute value ( α)n components of a vector. The negative CVaR function is dened as an average of the smallest by absolute value αn components of a vector. We dene nonscaled version of negative CVaR function as the dierence of l and α norms: From the denition of x α follows: r α (x) = l (x) x α. r α j (x) = ( x () x (j) )/n, for α = α j = j/n, r 0 (x) = 0, for α = 0, r (x) = l (x), for α =. We also dene scaled version of negative CVaR function as follows From the denition of x S α follows: rα,s (x) = α (l (x) ( α) x S α). r α j (x) = ( x () x (j) )/j, for α = α j = j/n, r 0 (x) = min i x i, for α = 0, r (x) = l (x), for α =. A general denition of the negative CVaR function, both in deterministic and stochastic cases, is considered in Section 3. Figure 6 shows level-sets of x S α and rα,s (x) in R for dierent values of α. The function rα,s is a natural extension of S α. When α variates from 0 to, the function rα,s (x) changes from min i x i to l (x) = n n i= x i, and the function x S α changes from l (x) to max i x i. 0

11 3.5 x S 0.5 = max( x, x )= x S 0.5 = x S 0 = l (x) = r,s (x)= r,s 0.75 (x)= r,s 0.5 (x) = min( x, x )= x x Figure 6: Level-sets of scaled CVaR norm x S α for α = 0, 0.5, 0.5 and level-sets of scaled negative CVaR function rα,s (x) for α = 0.5, 0.75, in R space. For α [0.5, ] norm x S α = max i x i. For α [0, 0.5] function rα,s (x) = min i x i. Equality x S 0 = l (x) = r,s (x) holds.

12 . CVaR Norm in Stochastic Case This section gives a formal denition of CVaR norm in stochastic case and proves various properties of the norm... CVaR Norm Denition and Properties Let us denote [x] + = max0, x}, [x] = max0, x}. Consider cumulative distribution function F X (x) = P (X x). If, for a probability level α (0, ), there is a unique x such that F X (x) = α, then this x is called the α- quantile q α (X). In general, however, the value x is not unique, or may not even exist any. There are two values to consider as extremes: q + α (X) = infx F X (x) > α}, q α (X) = supx F X (x) < α}. We will call by the quantile the entire interval between the two extreme values, q α (X) = [q α (X), q + α (X)]. () We will use notation q p (X)dp q p (X)dp, which is a reasonable since q + p (X)dp = q p (X)dp. Further we provide two general denitions of CVaR norm, following from the two equivalent general denitions of CVaR (see [8]). We also show that denitions for the discrete case and continuous case, made in introduction, are special cases of these general denitions. Denition. Let X be a random variable with E X <. Then, CVaR norm of X with parameter α [0, ) is dened as follows: X S α = min c + } E[ X c]+. c α If also X is essentially nite (i.e., exists C R : X < C), then for α = X S = sup X. Denition. Let X be a random variable with E X <. Then CVaR norm of X with parameter α [0, ) is dened as follows: X S α = α α q p ( X )dp. If also X is essentially nite (i.e., exists C R : X < C), then for α = X S = sup X. It immediately follows from the denitions of CVaR (see [8]) that the Denitions and are equivalent. Proposition. Let X be a continuous random variable, i.e., its cumulative distribution function is continuous. Then X S α = E ( X X > q α ( X )).

13 Proof. If cumulative distribution function F X of random variable X is continuous, then F X is continuous, q p ( X ) = F X (p) and X S α = α F X (p)dp α = F xdf X (x) X (α) ( ) ( ) = E X X > F P X > F X (α) X (α). Let X be a discrete random variable, i.e., it takes values x i } N i= with positive probabilities p i } N i= (N also can be ). Let us denote by the sequence x (i) } N i= an ordered sequence x i } N i=, i.e., x (i) x (i+). x i } N i= exists, such that if x (i) x j, then x (i) = x j. We also denote by p (i) } N i= a corresponding to the x (i) } N i= sequence of probabilities from the p i } N i=. Note that ordered sequence x (i) } exists only for special sets of x i }. In particular, it exists in following cases: set x i } is nite; sequence x i } i= has no converging subsequences; all converging subsequences of sequence x i } i= converge to x = sup x i }. If ordered sequence x (i) } exists, then the following proposition holds. Proposition. Let X be a discrete random variable, i.e., it takes values x i } N i=, with positive probabilities p i } N i=, where N i= p i = and N N. exists, such that if x (i) x j, then x (i) = x j. Let us denote by p (i) } N i= a corresponding to the x (i) } N i= sequence of values from the p i} N i=, i.e. if x (i) x j, then p (i) = p j. Then for N <, for N =, for N < and j = 0,..., N X S = x (N), X S = lim i x (i). X S α j = α j where α j = j i= p (i), for N = and j Z + N 0}, for α j < α < α j+, X S α j = α j N i=j+ i=j+ x (i) p (i), x (i) p (i), X S α = ( λ) α j α X S α j + λ α j+ α X S α j+, where λ = (α α j )/(α j+ α j ). Proof. Let us proceed with the proof bullet by bullet. 3

14 It follows directly from the denition that CVaR ( X ) = sup x i } N i=. Since x (i) < x (i+), then in case N <, X S = sup x i } N i= = max i x (i) = x (N). Consider the case N =. Since x (i) } i= is a non decreasing sequence, then it has a nite or an innite limit lim i x (i). Since also all probabilities p (i) > 0, then X S = sup x (i) } i= = lim i x (i). If X is a discrete random variable, then F X (x) is a step function. Then, q p ( X ) is a step function of p. Length of a step number i is α i α i = p (i). Height of the step number i is q αi ( X ) = x (i). It implies that the area under the step equals to the following integral: αi α i q p ( X )dp = p (i) x (i). Then, = α j X S α j = q p ( X )dp = α j α j N i=j+ αi α i q p ( X )dp = α j N i=j+ p (i) x (i). Since q p ( X ) is a step function of p, then it is a constant function of α on the interval (α j, α j+ ). Then, the integral q α p( X )dp is a linear function of α for α j < α < α j+. It implies that this integral is the linear combination α q p ( X )dp = ( λ) q p ( X )dp + λ α j q p ( X )dp, α j+ where λ = (α α j )/(α j+ α j ). Then, X S α = ( λ) α j α X S α j + λ α j+ α X S α j+. Denition immediately implies that X S 0 = L (X), X S = L (X). Furthermore, we prove that X S α is a norm for α (0, ). Proposition 3. Let X be a random variable. X S α variables. is a norm in the space of random Proof. By denition, function d(x) is a norm if. d(x) = 0 X 0,. d(λx) = λ d(x), 3. d(x + Y ) d(x) + d(y ). 4

15 Since CVaR α (X) is a regular Measure of Risk (see [9]), then for λ > 0 and CVaR α (λx) = λcvar α (X), CVaR α (X + Y ) CVaR α (X) + CVaR α (Y ). (3) By denition, f(x) is monotonic if X Y implies f(x) f(y ). Since CVaR α (X) is monotonic (see [9]), then for X Y CVaR α (X) CVaR α (Y ). (4) Let us prove the axioms of a norm for X S α = CVaR α ( X ).. CVaR α ( X ) = 0 X 0. The statement X 0 CVaR α ( X ) = 0 is obvious. If X 0, then q p ( X ) > 0 for p (0, ), and CVaR α ( X ) = α α q p ( X )dp > 0. If α = 0 and X 0, then CVaR 0 ( X ) = E X > 0. If α = and X 0, then CVaR ( X ) = sup( X ) > 0.. CVaR α ( λx ) = λ CVaR α ( X ). Since λ > 0, then CVaR α ( λx ) = CVaR α ( λ X ) = λ CVaR α ( X ). 3. CVaR α ( X + Y ) CVaR α ( X ) + CVaR α ( Y ). Since X + Y X + Y, using (4) we have Finally, which follows from (3). CVaR α ( X + Y ) CVaR α ( X + Y ). CVaR α ( X + Y ) CVaR α ( X ) + CVaR α ( Y ), The next proposition provides an alternative way to calculate X S α. Proposition 4. Let X be a random variable. Let Y be a random variable dened as follows X, with probability Y =, X, with probability. Then, X S α = CVaR (+α)/ (Y ). 5

16 Proof. Minimization form denition of CVaR, see [8] or Denition, implies that c + CVaR (+α)/ (Y ) = min c since /( ( + α)/) = /(( α)/). Dene c + c Y = arg min c E[Y c]+ ( α)/ E[Y c]+ ( α)/ }. }, (5) Notice that Y is symmetric, therefore 0 q Y (/). Notice also and (+α)/ /, since α 0. Since optimal solution in CVaR denition (5) is the quantile q (+α)/ (Y ), then c Y 0. Then, } CVaR (+α)/ (Y ) = min c + E[Y c]+ = (6) c ( α)/ = c Y + ( α)/ E[Y c Y ] + = (7) } = min c 0 = min c 0 c + E[Y c]+ ( α)/ ( α)/ E[Y + c] + c + = (8) }, (9) where equality between (6) and (7) follows from denition of c Y ; equality between (7) and (8) follows from c Y 0; equality between (8) and (9) follows from [Y c] + = [Y + c] + for c 0. Note that Y + X, with probability =, 0, with probability. Therefore, CVaR (+α)/ (Y ) = min c 0 = min c 0 } c + E[ X c]+ = ( α)/ c + } E[ X c]+ = X S α α. (0) Last equation in (0) follows from CVaR norm Denition and from arg min c + } E[ X c]+ 0, c α which holds since arg min is a quantile q α ( X ) and X 0, therefore q α ( X ) 0... CVaR Norm Properties With Respect to α Let us remind some general properties of integrals of quantile. Proposition 5. Let X be a random variable. For 0 α, q α p(x)dp is a continuous increasing function of α, α 6

17 lim α q α α p(x)dp = sup X, α q α 0 p(x)dp is a continuous non-decreasing function of α, α 0 q p(x)dp is a convex function of α, α 0 q p(x)dp is a piecewise-linear function of α for discretely distributed X. Proof. We provide references for these statements bullet by bullet. CVaR α is a continuous increasing function of α, see [8]. Then, integral form denition of CVaR α (X) = q α α p(x)dp implies that the integral q α α p(x)dp is a continuous increasing function of α. lim α CVaR α (X) = sup X, see [8]. Therefore, lim α q α α p(x)dp = sup X. Notice that q p ( X) = q p (X), then α α q p ( X)dp = α α q p (X)dp = α α 0 q p (X)dp. The rst bullet of this proposition implies that q α p( X)dp is a decreasing α continuous function of α, therefore, integral q α 0 p(x)dp is a continuous nondecreasing function of α. Integral α 0 q p(x)dp is called the Absolute Lorenz Curve, which is known to be convex w.r.t. α, e.g. [6]. Consider X having an atom x with probability p. If α = F X (x) and α = α + p, then q α (X) = x for α (α, α ). Therefore, α q 0 p(x)dp is linear on α (α, α ). Since α q 0 p(x)dp is also continuous, and X is dicretely distributed, then α q 0 p(x)dp is a piecewise-linear function of α. Let X be a random variable. Take constant C, such that L (X) C L (X). The following corollary assures that there exists a single α such that CVaR α ( X ) = C. Therefore, for any p there is a single α such that CVaR α ( X ) = L p (X). Corollary. Let X be a random variable. The norm X S α function of α. is a continuous increasing Proof. Consider Y = X and apply Proposition 5 to Y. The following proposition establishes properties of non-scaled CVaR norm with respect to parameter α. Denition 3. Let X be a random variable with E X <. Then, CVaR norm of X with parameter α [0, ] is dened as follows: ( α) X S X α = α, for α [0, ), 0, for α =. 7

18 Corollary. Let X be a random variable. The norm X α is a concave and decreasing function of α. Furthermore, if X is discretely distributed, X α is a piecewise-linear function of α. Proof. By denition, If α < α, then X α = ( α)cvar α ( X ) = X α = α q p ( X )dp α q p ( X )dp. α q p ( X )dp = X α. Therefore, X α is a decreasing function of α. To prove that X α is a concave function of α, consider Y = X and apply Proposition 5 to Y. Since α q 0 p( X )dp is convex, then X α = E X α q 0 p( X )dp is a concave function of α. For piecewise-linearity, take Y = X, note that X α = EY α q 0 p(y )dp, and apply Proposition 5. Corollary 3. Let X be a random variable. ( α)cvar α (X) is a concave function of α. Furthermore, it is a piecewise-linear function of α if X is discretely distributed. Proof. ( α)cvar α (X) = q α p(x)dp = EX α q 0 p(x)dp, therefore, it is concave w.r.t. α, and it is piecewise-linear for discretely distributed X, see Proposition Dual Norm to CVaR Norm and CVaR Normed Space Denition 4. Let X be a normed space over R with norm (i.e., X R for X X). Then, the dual (or conjugate) normed space X is dened as the set of all continuous linear functionals from X into R. For f X, the dual norm of f is dened by } f(x) f = sup f(x) : x X, x } = sup x : x X, x 0. The asterisk denotes the dual norm to a norm. Therefore, Y S α denotes the norm dual to the CVaR norm X S α. Proposition 6. Let X be a random variable. The norm Y S α = maxe Y, ( α) sup Y } is dual to the norm X S α for α (0, ). Proof. Paper [9] proved that CVaR α (X) = sup Q Q EXQ, where Q = Q 0 Q } α, EQ =. Then, X S α = CVaR α ( X ) = sup Q Q E X Q. Let us prove that sup E X Q = sup EXY, Q Q Y Y 8

19 where Y = Y Y, E Y }. α First, (I(X > 0) I(X < 0))Q Y sup E X Q sup EXY, Q Q Y Y since X(I(X > 0) I(X < 0))Q = X Q. Second, sup EXY sup E X Y sup E X Q. Y Y Y Y Q Q Finally, sup EXY = sup E X Q = CV ar α ( X ) = X S α. Y Y Q Q Then, Y = Y EXY X S α} must be a convex hull of Y. The set Y is closed: and convex: Y k Y, Y k α Y α, Y k Y, E Y k E Y, Y, Y Y λy + ( λ)y λ Y + ( λ) Y (λ + ( λ)), α E λy + ( λ)y λe Y + ( λ)e Y (λ + ( λ)). Then, Y = Y and Y is a unit ball in the dual norm to the CVaR norm Y S EXY α = sup, X 0 X S α since Y S α EXY X S α for all X. Then, the unit sphere in the dual norm is the set } } Y sup Y = α, E Y Y sup Y α, E Y =. Then, the dual norm equals Y S α = maxe Y, ( α) sup Y }. Denition 5. A Banach space is a vector space X over R, which is equipped with a norm and which is complete with respect to that norm. By denition, completeness means that for every Cauchy sequence x n } n= in X (i.e., for every ε > 0 exists N such that x m x n < ε for all m, n > N), there exists an element x in X such that lim x n = x, i.e., lim x n x = 0. n n The next statement follows directly from Denition 5 of a Banach space. Proposition 7. Let L be a norm, X L = X L(X) < } and space (X L, L) is a Banach space. Let L be a norm such that exist such C, C + > 0 that C L(X) L(X) C + L(X)for all X. Then, X L = X L and (X L, L) is a Banach space. 9

20 Corollary 4. The norm X S α generates a Banach space for α [0, ]. Proof. E X X S α α E X, for α <. E X = L (X) and it is known that L -norm generates a Banach space. X S = sup X = L (X) and it is known that L -norm generates a Banach space..4. Risk Quadrangle With CVaR Norm (CVaR Norm Quadrangle) Risk Quadrangle (see [9]) denes risk R(X), deviation D(X), regret V(X), error E(X) and statistic S(X) related by the following equations: V(X) = EX + E(X), R(X) = EX + D(X), () D(X) = mine(x C)}, R(X) = minc + V(X C)}, () C S(X) = arg mine(x C)} = arg minc + V(X C)}. (3) Measure of risk R(X) is regular if R(X) (, ], R(X) is closed convex, R(C) = C for any constant C, C R(X) > EX for any nonconstant X. Measure of deviation D(X) is regular if D(X) [0, ], D(X) is closed convex, D(C) = 0 for any constant C, D(X) > 0 for any nonconstant X. Measure of error E(X) is regular if E(X) [0, ], E(X) is closed convex, E(0) = 0, E(X) > 0 for any X 0, for sequence of random variables X k } k= lim E(X k) = 0 lim EX k = 0, k k which is equivalent to E(X) ψ(ex) with a convex function ψ on (, ) having ψ(0) = 0 but ψ(t) > 0 for t 0. 0 C C

21 Measure of regret V(X) is regular if V(X) (, ], V(X) is closed convex, V(0) = 0, V(X) > 0 for any X 0, for sequence of random variables X k } k= lim [V(X k) EX k ] = 0 lim EX k = 0. k k The quadrangle (R, D, E, V, S) is regular if axioms 3 are hold and if also R(X) is a regular measure of risk, D(X) is a regular measure of deviation, V(X) is a regular measure of regret, and E(X) is a regular measure of error. Quadrangle Theorem (see [9]) implies that if axioms 3 are hold for functions R, D, E, V, S, and if also E(X) is a regular measure of error, then (R, D, E, V, S) is a regular quadrangle. We will prove that X S α is a regular measure of error (it will imply that the quadrangle, generated by CVaR norm as a measure of error is regular). We also prove that if E(X) = X S α = CVaR α ( X ) and quadrangle axioms 3 hold, then the risk measure ( is R(X) = αcvar (+α)/(x)+ +αcvar ( α)/(x) and the statistic is S(X) = q( α)/ (X) + q (+α)/ (X) ). Proposition 8. E(X) = X S α is a regular measure of error. Proof. We further prove axioms of the regular measure of error. E(X) [0, ], follows from the fact that X S α is a norm. Let us prove that E(X) is closed and convex. X S α is a norm, therefore, it is a convex function. Closeness is equivalent to the following statement. Let us consider a sequence of random variables X k } k= and a random variable X such that expectations µ(x k X) 0 and variances σ(x k X) 0 for k and E(X k ) C for all k. Then, under these conditions, E(X) C. Here is the proof of this statement. E(X k ) E(X) E(X k X) α E X k X E Xk X α = = σ (X k X) µ α (X k X) 0, (4) for k. It implies that E(X) E(X k ) E(X X k ) = E(X k X) 0, (5) for k. Combining (4) and (5) we have E(X) E(X k ) 0 E(X k ) E(X) E(X) C.

22 E(0) = 0, follows from the fact that X S α is a norm. E(X) > 0 for any X 0, follows from the fact that X S α is a norm. Let us prove that E(X) ψ(ex) with a convex function ψ on (, ) having ψ(0) = 0 but ψ(t) > 0 for t 0. Assume ψ(x) = x. Since CVaR α (X) is a regular measure of risk, it satises the following inequality: CVaR α (X) EX. Therefore, X S α = CVaR α ( X ) E X EX = ψ(ex). Proposition 9. Let X be a random variable. arg min X d S α = ( q( α)/ (X) + q (+α)/ (X) ), d min X d S α = ( + α d α CVaR ( α)/ (X) + α CV ar (+α)/ (X) EX ). Proof. According to Denition of X S α: then min d X S α = min c X d S α = min d c + E[ X c]+ α }, min c + } E[ X d c]+. c α Notice that optimal c 0, because c = q α ( X d ) and inf X d 0. The following chain of equalities is valid E[ X d c] + = E( X d c)i( X d c 0) = =E(X d c)i(x > d)i( X d c 0) + E(d X c)i(x d)i( X d c 0) = =E(X (d + c))i(x > d)i(x (d + c)) + E((d c) X)I(X d)i(x (d c)) = =E(X (d + c))i(x (d + c)) E(X (d c))i(x (d c)) = =E[X (d + c)] + E(X (d c)) + E(X (d c))i(x > (d c)) = =(d c) + E[X (d + c)] + + E[X (d c)] + EX. (6) Notice that ( α)c + (d c) = α Combining (6) and (7) we have X d S α = [ α α min min d c + + α ( (d c) + (d + c) + + α (d c). (7) ( (d + c) + E[X (d c)]+ ( + α)/ ) E[X (d + c)]+ + ( α)/ ) ] EX. (8)

23 Notice that if Q(d, c) = G(d + c) + H(d c), then min d min c = min (d+c),(d c) Q(d, c) = min d,c Applying (9) to (8), we have Q(d, c) = min G(d + c) + H(d c) = d,c G(d + c) + H(d c) = min d+c G(d + c) + min H(d c). (9) d c X d S α = [ ( )] α α min (d + c) + E[X (d + c)]+ + (d+c) ( α)/ + [ ( )] + α α min (d c) + E[X (d c)]+ (d c) ( + α)/ α EX = = [ α CVaR (+α)/ (X) + + α ] CVaR ( α)/ (X) EX, α where which implies (d + c) = q (+α)/ (X), (d c) = q ( α)/ (X), d = ( q( α)/ (X) + q (+α)/ (X) ) = arg min d X d S α. Proposition 0. CVaR Norm Quadrangle. Error measure E(X) = X α generates the following regular quadrangle: S(X) = ( q( α)/ (X) + q (+α)/ (X) ), R(X) = α CVaR (+α)/ (X) + + α CVaR ( α)/ (X), D(X) = α CVaR (+α)/ (X EX) + + α CVaR ( α)/ (X EX), V(X) = X α + EX, E(X) = X α. Proof. It was proved in [9] that if E(X) is a regular measure of error, then λe(x) is a regular measure of error for any positive λ. Since X S α is a regular measure of error and X α = ( α) X S α, then X α is a regular measure of error. From Proposition 9 and equality CVaR α (X) EX = CV ar α (X EX) follows that quadrangle axioms 3 hold. Regularity follows from Proposition 8 and Quadrangle Theorem (see [9]). CVaR Norm Quadrangle from Proposition 0 is similar to Mixed-Quantile-Based quadrangle (see [9]) for α = ( + α)/, α = ( α)/, λ = ( α)/, λ = ( + α)/. (0) 3

24 Dene E αk (X) = E [ ] αk X + + X, V αk (X) = EX +. α k α k With parameters from (0) we obtain following Mixed-Quantile-Based quadrangle S(X) = α R(X) = α D(X) = α q (+α)/ (X) + + α q ( α)/ (X), CVaR (+α)/ (X) + + α CVaR ( α)/ (X), CVaR (+α)/ (X EX) + + α CVaR ( α)/ (X EX), V(X) = min λ V α (X B ) + λ V α (X B ) λ B + λ B = 0}, B,B E(X) = min B,B λ E α (X B ) + λ E α (X B ) λ B + λ B = 0}. Note that CVaR Norm Quadrangle and Mixed-Quantile-Based quadrangle have the same deviation and risk measures. Therefore, suppose one is optimizing measure of error over some parametric family X(θ): min θ E i (X(θ)), () where i = for error from CVaR Norm Quadrangle, and i = for error from Mixed- Quantile-Based quadrangle. Assume that X(θ) = θ 0 + Y ( θ), where θ = (θ 0, θ), and θ 0 is a free parameter. Dene θ i = arg min θ E i (X(θ)). Then θ = θ = arg min θ D(Y ( θ)) = θ. Therefore, Y ( θ ) = Y ( θ ) and two optimal points X(θ ) and X(θ ) for problems () can be obtained from each other by adding constant shift X(θ ) = (θ 0) + Y ( θ ), X(θ ) = (θ 0) + Y ( θ ), X(θ ) X(θ ) = (θ 0) (θ 0). 3. Negative CVaR Function Paper [4] considers a class of functions dened similar to L p norms, but for p [0, ). These functions are not norms and they are concave for some regions of the space they are dened 4. Such norms are used in optimization problems to achieve a sparsity of a solution vector. We will dene similar functions in terms of CVaR concept. First, let us consider a classic CVaR α (X) for α < 0 or α >. According to CVaR denition in minimization form (see [8] or denition ), CVaR α (X) = min c c + α E[X c]+ }. () Let us prove that CVaR α (X) = for α (, 0) (, ). Consider c < inf X (c may be ), then expression under minimization in formula () equals to c + α E[X c]+ = c α α + EX. (3) α 4 For p [0, ) there is l p (x) in R n and L p (X) in the space of random variables. Concavity holds, for example, for region x 0 in R n and for region X 0 in the space of random variables. 4

25 If α < 0 or α >, then α > 0 and the expression (3) tends to for c. We α see that denition () for α < 0 and α > makes no sense. Further we dene negative CVaR function. Denition 6. Negative CVaR function R α (X) is dened as follows: for α (0, ], R α (X) = α (E X ( α)cvar α( X )), for α = 0, R 0 (X) = inf X. R α (X) can be interpreted as an expectation of X in left α-tail. Note that R α (X) is then the average quantile of the random variable X. Denition 7. Negative CVaR function Rα (X) is dened as follows: for α (0, ], for α = 0, R α (X) = α α 0 q p ( X )dp, R 0 (X) = inf X. Two denitions are equivalent since E X = q 0 p( X )dp and X α = q α p( X )dp. The following proposition gives an alternative denition of the negative CVaR function, similar to the denition of CVaR norm. Proposition. Proof. Rα (X) = maxc c α E[ X c] }. R α (X) = α (E X ( α)cvar α( X )) = α (E X min( α)c + E[ X c] + } = c = α max E X c + αc E[ X c] + } = maxc c c α E[ X c] }. For p (0, ) the following inequality holds L p (X) L (X), where L p (X) = (E X p ) /p. Since x p is a concave function for 0 < p <, using Jensen's inequality we have E X p (E X ) p, therefore, (E X p ) /p E X. Similar statement is valid for the negative CVaR function. Proposition. 0 R α (X) L (X) = E X. The following proposition establishes the properties of negative CVaR function similar to the properties of CVaR norm. Proposition 3. The negative CVaR function satises the following properties: R α (λx) = λ R α (X), 5

26 R α (0) = 0, but also R α (X) = 0 for some X 0, for X, Y such that XY 0 inequality holds R α (λx + ( λ)y ) λr α (X) + ( λ)r α (Y ), function R α (X) is concave in the subspace of positive random variables X 0. Proof. We prove the properties one by one. R α (λx) = λ R α (X) follows from the fact, that E X and ( α)cvar α ( X ) are norms. Assume X = 0 with probability 0.5 and X = with probability 0.5. Then, for α [0, 0.5] function R α (X) = 0. Notice that if XY 0, then X + Y = X + Y, therefore maxc c α E[ X + Y c] } = maxc α E[ X + Y c] } c c X + c Y α E[ X + Y c X c Y ], where c X = arg min c c α E[ X c] }, c Y = arg min c c α E[ Y c] }. Considering that [x] is a concave function, we obtain R α (X + Y ) c X + c Y α (E[ X c X] + E[ Y c Y ] ) = R α (X) + R α (Y ). If X 0 and Y 0, then XY 0, therefore R α (X + Y ) R α (X) + R α (Y ), i.e., R α (X) is concave in subspace of positive random variables X 0. Proposition 3 states that R α (X) is a concave function for X 0. Notice that this property cannot be strengthened to concavity in the whole space of random variables. Consider a function g(x) such that g(x) 0, g(0) = 0 and g(x) 0. Assume that g(x) is concave in the space of random variables. Since g(x) 0, then exists X such that g(x) > 0. Then g(x) + g( X) > 0 = g(0) = g(x X), which implies that g(x) is not a concave function. Let us prove some properties of CVaR negative function with respect to parameter α. Corollary 5. Let X be a random variable. Then R α (X) is a continuous non-decreasing function w.r.t. α, αr α (X) is a convex non-decreasing function w.r.t. α. Proof. We will prove negative CVaR function properties one by one. 6

27 Consider Y = X and apply Proposition 5 to Y. αr α (X) = L (X) ( α)cvar α ( X ) = L (X) X α. Since X α is a concave, non-increasing function w.r.t. α, then X α is a convex non-decreasing function of α. L (X) does not depend upon α, therefore L (X) X α is also a convex non-decreasing function of α. 4. Case Study We illustrate CVaR Norm Quadrangle, see Proposition 0, with the following case study. The case study results are posted at this link 5. Let us consider a linear regression problem with CVaR norm error. Let X be a n d design matrix, where n is a number of observations, d is a number of explanatory variables. Let y R n be a vector of observations on the dependent variable. Let e R n be a vector of ones. Dene extended matrix X = [e, X], including additional constant term. Let us consider linear regression: ŷ = Xa, where a R d+ is a vector of parameters. We will minimize CVaR norm of vector of residuals y ŷ: min y Xa α. (4) a R d+ We consider the dataset from the case study ¾Estimation of CVaR through Explanatory Factors with Mixed Quantile Regression 6. The data contains returns of the Fidelity Magellan Fund as a dependent variable. Russell Value Index (RUJ), Russell 000 Value Index (RLV), Russell 000 Growth Index (RUO) and Russell 000 Growth Index (RLG) are taken as independent variables. Data include,64 observations. The CVaR norm is minimized with Portfolio Safeguard [] software package. Con- dence level α in CVaR norm equals α = 0.9. We minimized CVaR instead of CVaR norm, according to Proposition 4. Denote ȳ = [y; y] R n and X = [ X; X] R n d. Proposition 4 implies y Xa S α = CVaR (+α)/ (ȳ Xa). Then, problem (4) is equivalently stated as follows min a R d+ CVaR (+α)/ (ȳ Xa). Optimization results for this problem are in Table. CVaR Norm Quadrangle is a regular quadrangle, see Proposition 0. According to the Regression Theorem, see [9], the interceipt, obtained in regression, equals to the Statistic of a modied residuals. In CVaR Norm Quadrangle, Statistic equals S(X) = (q (+α)/ (X)+q ( α)/ (X))/. Denote the optimal vector of parameters obtained in regression by a = [c, b ], where c R is an optimal interceipt. According to the Regression 5 cvar-norm-regression/ 6 estimation-of-cvar-through-explanatory-factors-with-mixed-quantile-regression/ 7

28 rlv rlg ruj ruo intercept objective Table : Optimal vector of parameters and objective for linear regression with CVaR norm. Theorem, c S(y Xb ) (we write because, in general, quantile q p (X) is an interval, see (), therefore S(X) is also an interval). At the optimal point, c = 0.00, q0.05(y Xb ) = 0.03, q0.95(y Xb ) = Therefore, S(y Xb ) (q 0.05(y Xb ) + q 0.95(y Xb ))/ = ( )/ = 0.00 = c. Numerical experiment conrm theoretical results for CVaR Norm Quadrangle. References [] Portfolio Safeguard version., [] Banach, S. Theory of linear operations. North-Holland Sole distributors for the U.S.A. and Canada, Elsevier Science Pub. Co, Amsterdam New York, 987. [3] Bertsimas, D., Pachamanova, D., and Sim, M. Robust linear optimization under general norms. Operations Research Letters 3, 6 (November 004), [4] Ge, D., Jiang, X., and Ye, Y. A note on the complexity of Lp minimization. Math. Program. 9, (0), [5] Gotoh, J.-y., and Uryasev, S. Approximation of Euclidean norm by Lp-representable norms and applications. University of Florida, Research Report 03-3 (May 03). ApproxLwithLinearNorms.pdf. [6] Ogryczak, W., and Ruszczynski, A. Dual stochastic dominance and related mean-risk models. SIAM Journal on Optimization 3, (00), [7] Pavlikov, K., and Uryasev, S. CVaR Norm and Applications in Optimization. University of Florida, Research Report 03- (September 03). ufl.edu/uryasev/files/03/08/cvar_norm_working_paper.pdf. [8] Rockafellar, R. T., and Uryasev, S. Conditional value-at-risk for general loss distributions. Journal of Banking and Finance (00), [9] Rockafellar, R. T., and Uryasev, S. The Fundamental Risk Quadrangle in Risk Management, Optimization and Statistical Estimation. Surveys in Operations Research and Management Science 8 (03). 8

CVaR (Superquantile) Norm: Stochastic Case

CVaR (Superquantile) Norm: Stochastic Case CVaR (Superquantile) Norm: Stochastic Case Alexander Mafusalov, Stan Uryasev Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering 303 Weil Hall, University of

More information

Buered Probability of Exceedance: Mathematical Properties and Optimization

Buered Probability of Exceedance: Mathematical Properties and Optimization Buered Probability of Exceedance: Mathematical Properties and Optimization Alexander Mafusalov, Stan Uryasev RESEARCH REPORT 2014-1 Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab Department of Industrial

More information

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions Nicole Lorenz Gert Wanka In this paper we give subdifferential formulas of some convex deviation measures using their conjugate functions

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Duality in Regret Measures and Risk Measures arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 30 Apr 2017 Qiang Yao, Xinmin Yang and Jie Sun

Duality in Regret Measures and Risk Measures arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 30 Apr 2017 Qiang Yao, Xinmin Yang and Jie Sun Duality in Regret Measures and Risk Measures arxiv:1705.00340v1 [q-fin.mf] 30 Apr 2017 Qiang Yao, Xinmin Yang and Jie Sun May 13, 2018 Abstract Optimization models based on coherent regret measures and

More information

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures Jakub Černý Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance November 10, 2014 1 / 25 Contents CVaR - Dual

More information

COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY

COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY Terry Rockafellar University of Washington, Seattle University of Florida, Gainesville Goal: a coordinated view of recent ideas in risk modeling

More information

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9 MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: FALL 204 Contents. Sets 2 2. Functions 5 3. Countability 7 4. Axiom of choice 8 5. Equivalence relations 9 6. Real numbers 9 7. Extended

More information

Regression and Statistical Inference

Regression and Statistical Inference Regression and Statistical Inference Walid Mnif wmnif@uwo.ca Department of Applied Mathematics The University of Western Ontario, London, Canada 1 Elements of Probability 2 Elements of Probability CDF&PDF

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL QUADRANGLE OF RISK

THE FUNDAMENTAL QUADRANGLE OF RISK THE FUNDAMENTAL QUADRANGLE OF RISK relating quantifications of various aspects of a random variable risk R D deviation optimization S estimation regret V E error Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Lecture 3: optimization,

More information

Introduction to Real Analysis

Introduction to Real Analysis Introduction to Real Analysis Joshua Wilde, revised by Isabel Tecu, Takeshi Suzuki and María José Boccardi August 13, 2013 1 Sets Sets are the basic objects of mathematics. In fact, they are so basic that

More information

MEASURES OF RISK IN STOCHASTIC OPTIMIZATION

MEASURES OF RISK IN STOCHASTIC OPTIMIZATION MEASURES OF RISK IN STOCHASTIC OPTIMIZATION R. T. Rockafellar University of Washington, Seattle University of Florida, Gainesville Insitute for Mathematics and its Applications University of Minnesota

More information

CVaR distance between univariate probability distributions and approximation problems

CVaR distance between univariate probability distributions and approximation problems https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2732-8 S.I.: RISK MANAGEMENT APPROACHES IN ENGINEERING APPLICATIONS CVaR distance between univariate probability distributions and approximation problems Konstantin Pavlikov

More information

It follows from the above inequalities that for c C 1

It follows from the above inequalities that for c C 1 3 Spaces L p 1. In this part we fix a measure space (, A, µ) (we may assume that µ is complete), and consider the A -measurable functions on it. 2. For f L 1 (, µ) set f 1 = f L 1 = f L 1 (,µ) = f dµ.

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures F. Bellini 1, B. Klar 2, A. Müller 3, E. Rosazza Gianin 1 1 Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca 2 Institut für Stochastik,

More information

Introduction to Functional Analysis

Introduction to Functional Analysis Introduction to Functional Analysis Carnegie Mellon University, 21-640, Spring 2014 Acknowledgements These notes are based on the lecture course given by Irene Fonseca but may differ from the exact lecture

More information

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lecture 4: Lebesgue spaces and inequalities 1 of 10 Course: Theory of Probability I Term: Fall 2013 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lebesgue spaces We have seen how

More information

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Jan Dhaene Shaun Wang Virginia Young Marc J. Goovaerts November 8, 1999 Abstract In this paper, we investigate the relationship between comonotonicity and

More information

Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht. The problem of estimating the mean of an observed Gaussian innite-dimensional vector

Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht. The problem of estimating the mean of an observed Gaussian innite-dimensional vector On Minimax Filtering over Ellipsoids Eduard N. Belitser and Boris Y. Levit Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht Budapestlaan 6, 3584 CD Utrecht, The Netherlands The problem of estimating the mean

More information

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Institut de mathématiques de Toulouse 2 juin 2014 Joint work with F. Gamboa, A. Garivier (IMT) and B. Iooss (EDF R&D). 1 Coherent measure of

More information

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS RAIMUND KOVACEVIC Department of Statistics and Decision Support Systems, University of Vienna, Vienna, Austria Abstract. Conditional

More information

RISK AND RELIABILITY IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY

RISK AND RELIABILITY IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY RISK AND RELIABILITY IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY Terry Rockafellar University of Washington, Seattle AMSI Optimise Melbourne, Australia 18 Jun 2018 Decisions in the Face of Uncertain Outcomes = especially

More information

Chapter 3 sections. SKIP: 3.10 Markov Chains. SKIP: pages Chapter 3 - continued

Chapter 3 sections. SKIP: 3.10 Markov Chains. SKIP: pages Chapter 3 - continued Chapter 3 sections Chapter 3 - continued 3.1 Random Variables and Discrete Distributions 3.2 Continuous Distributions 3.3 The Cumulative Distribution Function 3.4 Bivariate Distributions 3.5 Marginal Distributions

More information

On Coarse Geometry and Coarse Embeddability

On Coarse Geometry and Coarse Embeddability On Coarse Geometry and Coarse Embeddability Ilmari Kangasniemi August 10, 2016 Master's Thesis University of Helsinki Faculty of Science Department of Mathematics and Statistics Supervised by Erik Elfving

More information

Linear Regression and Its Applications

Linear Regression and Its Applications Linear Regression and Its Applications Predrag Radivojac October 13, 2014 Given a data set D = {(x i, y i )} n the objective is to learn the relationship between features and the target. We usually start

More information

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation 4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation We consider a discrete-time information structure given by a filtration (F t ) t=0,...,t on our probability space (Ω, F, P ). The time horizon

More information

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous Econ 200 Mathematics for Economists Midterm Question.- Consider the set of functions F C(0, ) dened by { } F = f C(0, ) f(x) = ax b, a A R and b B R That is, F is a subset of the set of continuous functions

More information

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS HAHN-BANACH THEOREM. F (m 2 ) + α m 2 + x 0

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS HAHN-BANACH THEOREM. F (m 2 ) + α m 2 + x 0 FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS HAHN-BANACH THEOREM If M is a linear subspace of a normal linear space X and if F is a bounded linear functional on M then F can be extended to M + [x 0 ] without changing its norm.

More information

Random Variables. Random variables. A numerically valued map X of an outcome ω from a sample space Ω to the real line R

Random Variables. Random variables. A numerically valued map X of an outcome ω from a sample space Ω to the real line R In probabilistic models, a random variable is a variable whose possible values are numerical outcomes of a random phenomenon. As a function or a map, it maps from an element (or an outcome) of a sample

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL RISK QUADRANGLE IN RISK MANAGEMENT, OPTIMIZATION AND STATISTICAL ESTIMATION 1

THE FUNDAMENTAL RISK QUADRANGLE IN RISK MANAGEMENT, OPTIMIZATION AND STATISTICAL ESTIMATION 1 THE FUNDAMENTAL RISK QUADRANGLE IN RISK MANAGEMENT, OPTIMIZATION AND STATISTICAL ESTIMATION 1 R. Tyrrell Rockafellar, 2 Stan Uryasev 3 Abstract Random variables that stand for cost, loss or damage must

More information

Robust linear optimization under general norms

Robust linear optimization under general norms Operations Research Letters 3 (004) 50 56 Operations Research Letters www.elsevier.com/locate/dsw Robust linear optimization under general norms Dimitris Bertsimas a; ;, Dessislava Pachamanova b, Melvyn

More information

Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions

Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions Hyang-Won Lee Dept. of Internet & Multimedia Eng. Konkuk University Lecture 2 Network Optimization, Fall 2015 1 / 22 Optimization Problems Optimization problems are

More information

I teach myself... Hilbert spaces

I teach myself... Hilbert spaces I teach myself... Hilbert spaces by F.J.Sayas, for MATH 806 November 4, 2015 This document will be growing with the semester. Every in red is for you to justify. Even if we start with the basic definition

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Techinical Proofs for Nonlinear Learning using Local Coordinate Coding

Techinical Proofs for Nonlinear Learning using Local Coordinate Coding Techinical Proofs for Nonlinear Learning using Local Coordinate Coding 1 Notations and Main Results Denition 1.1 (Lipschitz Smoothness) A function f(x) on R d is (α, β, p)-lipschitz smooth with respect

More information

1 Inner Product Space

1 Inner Product Space Ch - Hilbert Space 1 4 Hilbert Space 1 Inner Product Space Let E be a complex vector space, a mapping (, ) : E E C is called an inner product on E if i) (x, x) 0 x E and (x, x) = 0 if and only if x = 0;

More information

It follows from the above inequalities that for c C 1

It follows from the above inequalities that for c C 1 3 Spaces L p 1. Appearance of normed spaces. In this part we fix a measure space (, A, µ) (we may assume that µ is complete), and consider the A - measurable functions on it. 2. For f L 1 (, µ) set f 1

More information

L p Spaces and Convexity

L p Spaces and Convexity L p Spaces and Convexity These notes largely follow the treatments in Royden, Real Analysis, and Rudin, Real & Complex Analysis. 1. Convex functions Let I R be an interval. For I open, we say a function

More information

ψ(t) := log E[e tx ] (1) P X j x e Nψ (x) j=1

ψ(t) := log E[e tx ] (1) P X j x e Nψ (x) j=1 Seminars 15/01/018 Ex 1. Exponential estimate Let X be a real valued random variable, and suppose that there exists r > 0 such that E[e rx ]

More information

Chapter 3 sections. SKIP: 3.10 Markov Chains. SKIP: pages Chapter 3 - continued

Chapter 3 sections. SKIP: 3.10 Markov Chains. SKIP: pages Chapter 3 - continued Chapter 3 sections 3.1 Random Variables and Discrete Distributions 3.2 Continuous Distributions 3.3 The Cumulative Distribution Function 3.4 Bivariate Distributions 3.5 Marginal Distributions 3.6 Conditional

More information

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

HW1 solutions. 1. α Ef(x) β, where Ef(x) is the expected value of f(x), i.e., Ef(x) = n. i=1 p if(a i ). (The function f : R R is given.

HW1 solutions. 1. α Ef(x) β, where Ef(x) is the expected value of f(x), i.e., Ef(x) = n. i=1 p if(a i ). (The function f : R R is given. HW1 solutions Exercise 1 (Some sets of probability distributions.) Let x be a real-valued random variable with Prob(x = a i ) = p i, i = 1,..., n, where a 1 < a 2 < < a n. Of course p R n lies in the standard

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Alexander Shapiro Abstract. We discuss in this paper asymptotics of the sample average approximation (SAA) of the optimal value of a minimax stochastic programming

More information

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods Duality and Methods Darinka Dentcheva 1 Andrzej Ruszczyński 2 1 Stevens Institute of Technology Hoboken, New Jersey, USA 2 Rutgers University Piscataway, New Jersey, USA Research supported by NSF awards

More information

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance Definitions and properties of Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance First Part: Convex Marco Frittelli Milano University The Fields Institute, Toronto, April 2010 Definitions and

More information

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW 1: PROBABILITY REVIEW Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 1: Probability Review 1 / 56 Outline We will review the following

More information

IMC 2015, Blagoevgrad, Bulgaria

IMC 2015, Blagoevgrad, Bulgaria IMC 05, Blagoevgrad, Bulgaria Day, July 9, 05 Problem. For any integer n and two n n matrices with real entries, B that satisfy the equation + B ( + B prove that det( det(b. Does the same conclusion follow

More information

REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE

REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE Form Approved OMB No. 0704-0188 Public reporting burden for this collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per response, including the time for reviewing instructions,

More information

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Bregman superquantiles Estimation methods and applications Institut de mathématiques de Toulouse 17 novembre 2014 Joint work with F Gamboa, A Garivier (IMT) and B Iooss (EDF R&D) Bregman superquantiles

More information

RANDOM VARIABLES, MONOTONE RELATIONS AND CONVEX ANALYSIS

RANDOM VARIABLES, MONOTONE RELATIONS AND CONVEX ANALYSIS RANDOM VARIABLES, MONOTONE RELATIONS AND CONVEX ANALYSIS R. Tyrrell Rockafellar, 1 Johannes O. Royset 2 Abstract Random variables can be described by their cumulative distribution functions, a class of

More information

2) Let X be a compact space. Prove that the space C(X) of continuous real-valued functions is a complete metric space.

2) Let X be a compact space. Prove that the space C(X) of continuous real-valued functions is a complete metric space. University of Bergen General Functional Analysis Problems with solutions 6 ) Prove that is unique in any normed space. Solution of ) Let us suppose that there are 2 zeros and 2. Then = + 2 = 2 + = 2. 2)

More information

Lecture Note 1: Probability Theory and Statistics

Lecture Note 1: Probability Theory and Statistics Univ. of Michigan - NAME 568/EECS 568/ROB 530 Winter 2018 Lecture Note 1: Probability Theory and Statistics Lecturer: Maani Ghaffari Jadidi Date: April 6, 2018 For this and all future notes, if you would

More information

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents MATH 3969 - MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Measure Theory 2 1.1. Properties of Measures 3 1.2. Constructing σ-algebras and measures 3 1.3. Properties of the Lebesgue measure

More information

Stochastic dominance with imprecise information

Stochastic dominance with imprecise information Stochastic dominance with imprecise information Ignacio Montes, Enrique Miranda, Susana Montes University of Oviedo, Dep. of Statistics and Operations Research. Abstract Stochastic dominance, which is

More information

Functional Analysis Exercise Class

Functional Analysis Exercise Class Functional Analysis Exercise Class Week 9 November 13 November Deadline to hand in the homeworks: your exercise class on week 16 November 20 November Exercises (1) Show that if T B(X, Y ) and S B(Y, Z)

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

Advanced Statistical Tools for Modelling of Composition and Processing Parameters for Alloy Development

Advanced Statistical Tools for Modelling of Composition and Processing Parameters for Alloy Development Advanced Statistical Tools for Modelling of Composition and Processing Parameters for Alloy Development Greg Zrazhevsky, Alex Golodnikov, Stan Uryasev, and Alex Zrazhevsky Abstract The paper presents new

More information

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints D. Dentcheva and W. Römisch Stevens Institute of Technology, Hoboken Humboldt-University Berlin www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch SIAM

More information

Motivation General concept of CVaR Optimization Comparison. VaR and CVaR. Přemysl Bejda.

Motivation General concept of CVaR Optimization Comparison. VaR and CVaR. Přemysl Bejda. VaR and CVaR Přemysl Bejda premyslbejda@gmail.com 2014 Contents 1 Motivation 2 General concept of CVaR 3 Optimization 4 Comparison Contents 1 Motivation 2 General concept of CVaR 3 Optimization 4 Comparison

More information

Entrance Exam, Real Analysis September 1, 2017 Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems

Entrance Exam, Real Analysis September 1, 2017 Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems September, 27 Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems. Prove by denition (in ɛ δ language) that f(x) = + x 2 is uniformly continuous in (, ). Is f(x) uniformly continuous in (, )? Prove your conclusion.

More information

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Dan Hathaway May 2010 This document is a summary of the theorems and definitions and theorems from Part 1 of the book Real Analysis by Royden. In some areas, such as

More information

Robustness and bootstrap techniques in portfolio efficiency tests

Robustness and bootstrap techniques in portfolio efficiency tests Robustness and bootstrap techniques in portfolio efficiency tests Dept. of Probability and Mathematical Statistics, Charles University, Prague, Czech Republic July 8, 2013 Motivation Portfolio selection

More information

Applied Analysis (APPM 5440): Final exam 1:30pm 4:00pm, Dec. 14, Closed books.

Applied Analysis (APPM 5440): Final exam 1:30pm 4:00pm, Dec. 14, Closed books. Applied Analysis APPM 44: Final exam 1:3pm 4:pm, Dec. 14, 29. Closed books. Problem 1: 2p Set I = [, 1]. Prove that there is a continuous function u on I such that 1 ux 1 x sin ut 2 dt = cosx, x I. Define

More information

Hilbert Spaces. Hilbert space is a vector space with some extra structure. We start with formal (axiomatic) definition of a vector space.

Hilbert Spaces. Hilbert space is a vector space with some extra structure. We start with formal (axiomatic) definition of a vector space. Hilbert Spaces Hilbert space is a vector space with some extra structure. We start with formal (axiomatic) definition of a vector space. Vector Space. Vector space, ν, over the field of complex numbers,

More information

Vector Spaces. Vector space, ν, over the field of complex numbers, C, is a set of elements a, b,..., satisfying the following axioms.

Vector Spaces. Vector space, ν, over the field of complex numbers, C, is a set of elements a, b,..., satisfying the following axioms. Vector Spaces Vector space, ν, over the field of complex numbers, C, is a set of elements a, b,..., satisfying the following axioms. For each two vectors a, b ν there exists a summation procedure: a +

More information

Normed and Banach Spaces

Normed and Banach Spaces (August 30, 2005) Normed and Banach Spaces Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ We have seen that many interesting spaces of functions have natural structures of Banach spaces:

More information

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND CHAPTER A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND POSITIVE OPERATORS In tis capter we give a brief introduction to Banac lattices and positive operators. Most results of tis capter can be found, e.g.,

More information

Solutions and Proofs: Optimizing Portfolios

Solutions and Proofs: Optimizing Portfolios Solutions and Proofs: Optimizing Portfolios An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan Covariance Proof: Cov(X, Y) = E [XY Y E [X] XE [Y] + E [X] E [Y]] = E [XY] E [Y] E

More information

A converse Gaussian Poincare-type inequality for convex functions

A converse Gaussian Poincare-type inequality for convex functions Statistics & Proaility Letters 44 999 28 290 www.elsevier.nl/locate/stapro A converse Gaussian Poincare-type inequality for convex functions S.G. Bokov a;, C. Houdre ; ;2 a Department of Mathematics, Syktyvkar

More information

Semi-strongly asymptotically non-expansive mappings and their applications on xed point theory

Semi-strongly asymptotically non-expansive mappings and their applications on xed point theory Hacettepe Journal of Mathematics and Statistics Volume 46 (4) (2017), 613 620 Semi-strongly asymptotically non-expansive mappings and their applications on xed point theory Chris Lennard and Veysel Nezir

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

A PRIMER OF LEBESGUE INTEGRATION WITH A VIEW TO THE LEBESGUE-RADON-NIKODYM THEOREM

A PRIMER OF LEBESGUE INTEGRATION WITH A VIEW TO THE LEBESGUE-RADON-NIKODYM THEOREM A PRIMR OF LBSGU INTGRATION WITH A VIW TO TH LBSGU-RADON-NIKODYM THORM MISHL SKNDRI Abstract. In this paper, we begin by introducing some fundamental concepts and results in measure theory and in the Lebesgue

More information

Probability: Handout

Probability: Handout Probability: Handout Klaus Pötzelberger Vienna University of Economics and Business Institute for Statistics and Mathematics E-mail: Klaus.Poetzelberger@wu.ac.at Contents 1 Axioms of Probability 3 1.1

More information

Ordinary Differential Equations (ODEs)

Ordinary Differential Equations (ODEs) Chapter 13 Ordinary Differential Equations (ODEs) We briefly review how to solve some of the most standard ODEs. 13.1 First Order Equations 13.1.1 Separable Equations A first-order ordinary differential

More information

A SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY MEASURE

A SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY MEASURE K Y B E R N E I K A V O L U M E 4 4 ( 2 0 0 8 ), N U M B E R 2, P A G E S 2 4 3 2 5 8 A SECOND ORDER SOCHASIC DOMINANCE PORFOLIO EFFICIENCY MEASURE Miloš Kopa and Petr Chovanec In this paper, we introduce

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Fabio Bellini a, Bernhard Klar b, Alfred Müller c,, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin a,1 a Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca,

More information

2 Random Variable Generation

2 Random Variable Generation 2 Random Variable Generation Most Monte Carlo computations require, as a starting point, a sequence of i.i.d. random variables with given marginal distribution. We describe here some of the basic methods

More information

Lecture 11. Probability Theory: an Overveiw

Lecture 11. Probability Theory: an Overveiw Math 408 - Mathematical Statistics Lecture 11. Probability Theory: an Overveiw February 11, 2013 Konstantin Zuev (USC) Math 408, Lecture 11 February 11, 2013 1 / 24 The starting point in developing the

More information

3. Convex functions. basic properties and examples. operations that preserve convexity. the conjugate function. quasiconvex functions

3. Convex functions. basic properties and examples. operations that preserve convexity. the conjugate function. quasiconvex functions 3. Convex functions Convex Optimization Boyd & Vandenberghe basic properties and examples operations that preserve convexity the conjugate function quasiconvex functions log-concave and log-convex functions

More information

3.1 Basic properties of real numbers - continuation Inmum and supremum of a set of real numbers

3.1 Basic properties of real numbers - continuation Inmum and supremum of a set of real numbers Chapter 3 Real numbers The notion of real number was introduced in section 1.3 where the axiomatic denition of the set of all real numbers was done and some basic properties of the set of all real numbers

More information

Lu Cao. A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics

Lu Cao. A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics Multivariate Robust Vector-Valued Range Value-at-Risk Lu Cao A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics Presented in Partial Fulllment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science

More information

Convex Optimization & Parsimony of L p-balls representation

Convex Optimization & Parsimony of L p-balls representation Convex Optimization & Parsimony of L p -balls representation LAAS-CNRS and Institute of Mathematics, Toulouse, France IMA, January 2016 Motivation Unit balls associated with nonnegative homogeneous polynomials

More information

Exercises and Answers to Chapter 1

Exercises and Answers to Chapter 1 Exercises and Answers to Chapter The continuous type of random variable X has the following density function: a x, if < x < a, f (x), otherwise. Answer the following questions. () Find a. () Obtain mean

More information

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Walter Schneider July 26, 20 Abstract In this paper an analytic expression is given for the bounds

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension. n=1

Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension. n=1 Chapter 2 Probability measures 1. Existence Theorem 2.1 (Caratheodory). A (countably additive) probability measure on a field has an extension to the generated σ-field Proof of Theorem 2.1. Let F 0 be

More information

Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints

Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints Charles University in Prague Faculty of Mathematics and Physics Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints December 16, 2014 Contents Motivation 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 Contents Motivation

More information

Convex Geometry. Carsten Schütt

Convex Geometry. Carsten Schütt Convex Geometry Carsten Schütt November 25, 2006 2 Contents 0.1 Convex sets... 4 0.2 Separation.... 9 0.3 Extreme points..... 15 0.4 Blaschke selection principle... 18 0.5 Polytopes and polyhedra.... 23

More information

Lecture Notes in Functional Analysis

Lecture Notes in Functional Analysis Lecture Notes in Functional Analysis Please report any mistakes, misprints or comments to aulikowska@mimuw.edu.pl LECTURE 1 Banach spaces 1.1. Introducton to Banach Spaces Definition 1.1. Let X be a K

More information

j=1 [We will show that the triangle inequality holds for each p-norm in Chapter 3 Section 6.] The 1-norm is A F = tr(a H A).

j=1 [We will show that the triangle inequality holds for each p-norm in Chapter 3 Section 6.] The 1-norm is A F = tr(a H A). Math 344 Lecture #19 3.5 Normed Linear Spaces Definition 3.5.1. A seminorm on a vector space V over F is a map : V R that for all x, y V and for all α F satisfies (i) x 0 (positivity), (ii) αx = α x (scale

More information

SOME REMARKS ON THE SPACE OF DIFFERENCES OF SUBLINEAR FUNCTIONS

SOME REMARKS ON THE SPACE OF DIFFERENCES OF SUBLINEAR FUNCTIONS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 22,3 (1994), pp. 419 426 S. G. BARTELS and D. PALLASCHKE (Karlsruhe) SOME REMARKS ON THE SPACE OF DIFFERENCES OF SUBLINEAR FUNCTIONS Abstract. Two properties concerning the space

More information

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε 1. Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

STAT 200C: High-dimensional Statistics

STAT 200C: High-dimensional Statistics STAT 200C: High-dimensional Statistics Arash A. Amini May 30, 2018 1 / 59 Classical case: n d. Asymptotic assumption: d is fixed and n. Basic tools: LLN and CLT. High-dimensional setting: n d, e.g. n/d

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

Distributionally Robust Discrete Optimization with Entropic Value-at-Risk

Distributionally Robust Discrete Optimization with Entropic Value-at-Risk Distributionally Robust Discrete Optimization with Entropic Value-at-Risk Daniel Zhuoyu Long Department of SEEM, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, zylong@se.cuhk.edu.hk Jin Qi NUS Business School, National

More information

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989),

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989), Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 April 26, 2005 1 Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski 1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer

More information

MATH 202B - Problem Set 5

MATH 202B - Problem Set 5 MATH 202B - Problem Set 5 Walid Krichene (23265217) March 6, 2013 (5.1) Show that there exists a continuous function F : [0, 1] R which is monotonic on no interval of positive length. proof We know there

More information