Asymptotic Analysis for Spectral Risk Measures Parameterized by Confidence Level

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Asymptotic Analysis for Spectral Risk Measures Parameterized by Confidence Level"

Transcription

1 Asymptotic Analysis for Spectral Risk Measures Parameterized by Confidence Level arxiv: v1 [q-fin.rm] 2 Nov 217 Takashi Kato Association of Mathematical Finance Laboratory (AMFiL) 2 1, Kojimachi, Chiyoda, Tokyo 12 83, Japan takashi.kato@mathfi-lab.com November 2, 217 Abstract We study the asymptotic behavior of the difference ρ X,Y := ρ (X + Y ) ρ (X) as 1, where ρ is a risk measure equipped with a confidence level parameter < < 1, and where X and Y are non-negative random variables whose tail probability functions are regularly varying. The case where ρ is the value-at-risk (VaR) at, is treated in [2]. This paper investigates the case where ρ is a spectral risk measure that converges to the worst-case risk measure as 1. We give the asymptotic behavior of the difference between the marginal risk contribution and the Euler contribution of Y to the portfolio X + Y. Similarly to [2], our results depend primarily on the relative magnitudes of the thicknesses of the tails of X and Y. We also conducted a numerical experiment, finding that when the tail of X is sufficiently thicker than that of Y, ρ X,Y does not increase monotonically with and takes a maximum at a confidence level strictly less than 1. Keywords: Spectral risk measures, quantitative risk management, asymptotic analysis, extreme value theory, Euler contribution 1 Introduction The purpose of this paper is to investigate the asymptotic behavior of the difference ρ X,Y := ρ (X + Y ) ρ (X) (1.1) as 1, where X and Y are fat-tailed random variables (loss variables) and (ρ ) <<1 is a family of risk measures. The case where ρ is an -percentile value-at-risk (VaR), has been treated in [2], where it was shown that the asymptotic behavior of VaR X,Y drastically changes according to the relative magnitudes of the thicknesses of the tails of X and Y (the definition of the VaR is given in (2.1) in the next section). In this paper, we study a progressive case in which ρ is given as a parameterized spectral risk measure, and we obtain similar results as in [2]. In particular, we find that if X and Y are independent and if the tail of X is sufficiently fatter than that of Y, then ρ X,Y converges to the expected value E[Y ] 1

2 as 1 whenever (ρ ) <<1 are spectral risk measures converging to a risk measure of the worst case scenario. That is, whenever ρ (Z) 1 ess sup Z(ω) (1.2) ω for each loss random variable Z in some sense. Our result does not require any specific form for ρ, implying that this property is robust. Furthermore, assuming some technical conditions for the probability density functions of X and Y, we study the asymptotic behavior of the Euler contribution, defined as (see Remark 17.1 in [29]), and show that ρ X,Y ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) = h ρ (X + hy ) (1.3) h=1 is asymptotically equivalent to δρ Euler (Y X+Y ) as 1. Here, δ (, 1] is a constant determined according to the relative magnitudes of the thicknesses of the tails of X and Y. We now briefly review the financial background for this study. In quantitative financial risk management, it is important to capture tail loss events by using adequate risk measures. One of the most standard risk measures is the VaR. The Basel Accords, which provide a set of recommendations for regulations in the banking industry, essentially recommend using VaR as a measure of risk capital for banks. VaRs are indeed simple, useful, and their values are easy to interpret. For instance, a yearly 99.9% VaR calculated as x means that the probability of a risk event with a realized loss larger than x is.1%. In other words, an amount x of risk capital is sufficient to prevent a default with 99.9% probability. The meaning of the amount x is therefore easy to understand. However, VaRs are often criticized for their lack of subadditivity (see, for instance, [2,4,15]). VaRs do not reflect the risk diversification effect. The expected shortfall (ES) has been proposed as an alternative risk measure that is coherent (in particular, subadditive) and tractable, with the risk amount at least that of the corresponding VaR. Note that there are various versions of ES, such as the conditional valueat-risk (CVaR), the average value-at-risk (AVaR), the tail conditional expectation (TCE), and the worst conditional expectation (WCE). These are all equivalent under some natural assumptions (see [3 6]). It should be noted that the Basel Accords have also considered recently the adoption of ESs as a minimal capital requirement, in order to better capture market tail risks (see for instance [7, 8]). A spectral risk measure (SRM) has been proposed as a generalization of ESs, in [2]. SRMs are characterized by a weight function φ that represents the significance of each confidence level for the risk manager. SRMs are equivalent to comonotonic law-invariant coherent risk measures (see Remark 1 in the next section). VaRs and ESs as risk measures depend on a confidence level parameter (, 1). We let VaR (resp., ES ) denote the VaR (resp., ES) with confidence level. When is close to 1, the values of VaR and ES are increasing without bound as in (1.2). The parameter corresponds to the risk aversion level of the risk manager. Higher values of indicate that the risk manager is more risk-averse and evaluates the tail risk as more severe. In this paper, we consider a family (ρ ) <<1 of SRMs parameterized by the confidence level. we make a mathematical assumption that intuitively implies situation (1.2) and investigate the asymptotic behaviors of (1.1) and (1.3) as 1, when the tail probability function of X 2

3 (resp., Y ) is regularly varying with index β (resp., γ). Our main theorem asserts that the asymptotic behaviors of (1.1) and (1.3) strongly depend on the relative magnitudes of β and γ. Note that our results include the case ρ = ES, the inclusion of which was discussed as a future task in [2]. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we prepare the basic settings and introduce the definitions for SRMs based on confidence level. In Section 3, we give our main results. We numerically verify our results in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 summarizes our studies. Throughout the main part of this paper, we assume that X and Y are independent. The more general case where X and Y are not independent is studied in Appendix A. All proofs are given in Appendix B. 2 Preliminaries Let (Ω, F, P ) be a standard probability space and let L + denote a set of non-negative random variables defined on (Ω, F, P ). For each Z L +, we denote by F Z the distribution function of Z and by F Z its tail probability function; that is, F Z (z) = P (Z z) and F Z (z) = P (Z > z). Moreover, for each (, 1), we define VaR (Z) = inf{z R ; P (Z z) }. (2.1) Note that VaR (Z) is exactly the left-continuous version of the generalized inverse function of F Z. We now introduce the definition of SRMs. Definition 1. (i) A Borel measurable function φ : [, 1) [, ) is called an admissible spectrum if φ is right-continuous, non-decreasing, and satisfies φ()d = 1. (2.2) (ii) A risk measure ρ : L + [, ) is called an SRM if there is an admissible spectrum φ such that ρ = M φ, where M φ (Z) = VaR (Z)φ()d, Z L +. Remark 1. SRMs are law-invariant, comonotonic, and coherent risk measures. However, as shown in [17, 18, 21], if (Ω, F, P ) is atomless, then for any law-invariant comonotonic convex risk measure ρ, there is a probability measure µ on [, 1] such that ρ(z) = ES (Z)µ(d), (2.3) for each Z L (Ω, F, P ). This is due to the generalized Kusuoka representation theorem (Theorem 4.93 in [17]), where ES (Z) is the -percentile expected shortfall of Z: ES (Z) = VaR u (Z)du. (2.4)

4 Moreover, such a ρ is always coherent and satisfies the Fatou property [18]. Furthermore, representation (2.3) can also be rewritten as ρ(z) = M φµ (Z), where φ µ () = 1 1 u 1 [,](u)µ(du). Here, it is easy to see that φ µ is non-negative, non-decreasing, right-continunous, and satisfies φ µ ()d = 1 1 u 1 { u } dµ(du) = 1, meaning that φ µ is an admissible spectrum (see [25]). Therefore, any law-invariant comonotonic convex (or coherent) risk measure is completely characterized as an SRM. Arguments similar to those above, replacing L (Ω, F, P ) with L p (Ω, F, P ), where 1 p <, can be found in [23, 25]. Next, we introduce a family (ρ ) <<1 of SRMs parameterized by the confidence level. Definition 2. Let (φ ) <<1 be a familly of admissible spectra and let ρ = M φ. Then (ρ ) <<1 is called a set of confidence-level-based spectral risk measures (CLBSRMs) if Φ w δ 1, 1, (2.5) where Φ is a probability measure on [, 1] defined by Φ (du) = φ (u)du and δ 1 is the Dirac measure with unit mass at 1. Condition (2.5) formally implies (1.2). Indeed, if Z L + is a bounded random variable with a distribution function that is continuous and strictly increasing on [, z ], where z = esssup Z(ω), then the function u VaR u (Z) is bounded and continuous, so that (2.5) gives ω ρ (Z) = VaR u (Z)Φ (du) z, 1, where we recognize VaR 1 (Z) = F 1 Z (1) = z. Moreover, we see that Lemma 1. Relation (2.5) is equivalent to φ (u), 1 for each u [, 1). (2.6) We now give some examples of CLBSRMs. Example 1. Expected Shortfalls (ES ) <<1 defined by (2.4) is a typical example of a CLBSRM. The corresponding admissible spectra are given as φ ES (u) = [,1)(u). 4

5 It is easy to see that (2.5) does hold. Indeed, for any bounded continuous function f defined on [, 1], we see that 1 1 f(u)du = f(u + (1 u))du f(1), 1 due to the bounded convergence theorem. Equivalently, we can also check that (ES ) satisfies (2.6). ES is characterized as the smallest law-invariant coherent risk measures that are greater than or equal to VaR [21]. Note that if the distribution function of the target random variable Z is continuous, then ES (Z) coincides with CVaR (Z), where (see [5] for details). CVaR (Z) = E[Z Z VaR (Z)] Example 2. Exponential/Power SRMs An admissible spectrum φ corresponding to an SRM M φ represents the preferences of a risk manager for each quantile of the loss distribution. Therefore, the form taken by φ corresponds to the manager s risk aversion, which is also described in terms of utility functions in classical decision theory. Recently, the relation between expected utility functions and SRMs has been studied, though it has not been entirely resolved. Here we introduce some examples of SRMs based on specific utility functions. The exponential utility function is a typical example of tractable utility functions U γ (p) = e γp γ, where p denotes the profit-and-loss (p > indicating profit) and γ characterizes the degree of risk preference. We focus on the case < γ < so that U γ describes a risk-averse utility function. We transform the parameter γ into the confidence level (, 1) using = (2/π) tan 1 γ. Note that the original parameter γ can be recovered using the inverse γ = t := tan(π/2). The exponential utility of the loss l with confidence level is then given as U t ( l) = e lt /t. Cotter and Dowd [12] have proposed an SRM ρ EXP = M φ EXP based on the exponential utility by constructing an admissible spectrum φ EXP (u) = λu t ( u) for some λ >, so that φ EXP (u) satisfies (2.2). Then, λ must be set as t 2 /(e t 1), giving φ EXP (u) = t e t(1 u) 1 e. t Note that the theoretical validity of the above method is still unclear. Other methods to adequately construct SRMs from exponential utility functions have been discussed in [11, 26, 3], but no definite answer has been reached. In particular, it is pointed out in [11] that there exists no general consistency between expected utility theory and SRM-decision making. In any case, we can easily verify that (φ EXP ) as defined above satisfies (2.5) (2.6), which implies that (ρ EXP ) is actually a CLBSRM. 5

6 Similarly to the above, an SRM ρ POW = M φ POW based on the power utility function has been studied in [14]. After changing the risk aversion parameter to the confidence level (, 1) as above, φ POW is given as φ POW (u) = u/(1 ) 1. We can also verify that (ρ POW ) <<1 is a CLBSRM. We now introduce some notations and definitions used in asymptotic analysis and extreme value theory. Let f and g be positive functions defined on [x, x 1 ), where x [, ) and x 1 (x, ]. We say that f and g are asymptotically equivalent (denoted as f g) as x x 1 if lim f(x)/g(x) = 1. When x 1 =, we say that f is regularly varying with index k R x x 1 if it holds that lim f(tx)/f(x) = t k for each t >. Moreover, we say that f is ultimately x decreasing if f is non-increasing on [x 2, ) for some x 2 >. For more details, we refer the reader to [1, 16]. 3 Main results Our main purpose is to investigate the property of (1.1) for a CLBSRM (ρ ) <<1 and random variables X, Y L + whose distributions are fat-tailed. To consider this case, we assume that F X and F Y are regularly varying functions with indices β and γ, respectively. That is, FX (x), F Y (x) > for each x and lim x F X (tx) F X (x) = t β, FY (tx) lim x F Y (x) = t γ, t > (3.1) for some β, γ >. In [2], we study the asymptotic property of (1.1) as 1 when ρ = VaR. The results display the following five patterns: (i) β + 1 < γ, (ii) β < γ β + 1, (iii) β = γ, (iv) γ < β γ + 1, and (v) γ + 1 < β. In cases (iv) and (v), we consider the difference VaR Y,X instead of VaR X,Y, and the results are restated consequences of cases (i) and (ii). Hence, we assume here that β γ and focus on cases (i) (iii) only. We further assume that β > 1. This assumption guarantees the integrability of X and Y (see, for instance, Proposition A3.8 in [16]). Let (ρ ) <<1 be a CLBSRM with a family of admissible spectra (φ ) <<1. Here we assume that for each (, 1). Then, Lemma A.23 in [17] implies that ρ (X + Y ) φ (1 ) φ (1 ) = lim u 1 φ (u) < (3.2) VaR u (X + Y )du = φ (1 )(E[X] + E[Y ]) < 6

7 for each < < 1. This immediately implies that ρ (X), ρ (Y ) <. Furthermore, by (17.9b) and Proposition 17.2 in [29], we see that ρ X,Y ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) ρ (Y ), (3.3) where ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) is given by (1.3) if ρ (X + hy ) is continuously differentiable in h. Note that inequality (3.3) holds for each < < 1 whenever ρ is coherent. Our main purpose in this section is to investigate in detail the asymptotic behavior of, as well as ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) if it is defined, as 1. To clearly state our main results, we establish the following conditions, which are assumed to hold in Section 4 of [2]. ρ X,Y [C1] [C2] X and Y are independent. There is some x such that F X has a positive, non-increasing density function f X on [x, ); that is, F X (x) = F X (x ) + x x f X (y)dy, x x. [C3] The function x γ β FY (x)/ F X (x) converges to some real number k as x. Let us adopt the notation E[Y ] if β + 1 < γ, k 1 M() = VaR u (X) β+1 γ φ (u)du if β < γ β + 1, β {(1 + k) 1/β 1}ρ (X) if β = γ (3.4) for < < 1. Note that M() is finite for each fixed (, 1) (see Corollary 1 in Appendix B). Our main results are the two following theorems. Theorem 1. Assuming [C1] [C3], ρ X,Y M() as 1. Formally, assertions (i) (iii) of Theorem 4.1 in [2] are the same as the assumptions of Theorem 1, by setting Φ = δ. That is, we have VaR X,Y f() as 1, where E[Y ] if β + 1 < γ, k f() = β VaR (X) β+1 γ if β < γ β + 1, (3.5) {(1 + k) 1/β 1}VaR (X) if β = γ. Theorem 1 justifies the following relation: ρ X,Y = VaR X,Y u φ (u)du f(u)φ (u)du = M(), 1. Note that condition [C3] is not required for Theorem 1 when β + 1 < γ. Moreover, when β + 1 < γ, Theorem 1 implies that ρ X,Y converges to E[Y ] as 1. The limit E[Y ] does not depend on the forms of (φ ), so this result is robust. The second main result is as follows. Theorem 2. Assume [C1] and [C3]. Moreover, assume that 7

8 [C4] X and Y have positive, continuous, and ultimately decreasing density functions f X and f Y, respectively, on [, ). Under these assumptions, ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) M()/δ as 1, where δ is a positive constant given by δ = 1 if β + 1 < γ, k/(e[y ]β + kγ) if β + 1 = γ, 1/γ if β < γ < β + 1, {1 + k (1 + k) 1 1/β }/k if β = γ. (3.6) Theorems 1 and 2 together imply that if X and Y are independent, and if F X and F Y have adequate density functions, then ρ X,Y δρ Euler (Y X + Y ), 1. (3.7) Note that δ is always smaller than or equal to 1, so that (3.7) is consistent with inequality (3.3). In particular, if β + 1 < γ, then the asymptotic equivalence between the marginal risk contribution ρ X,Y and the Euler contribution ρ Euler (Y X +Y ) is justified (see (17.1) in [29]). Note that ρ X,Y is always larger than or equal to E[Y ] so long as the random vector (X, Y ) satisfies a suitable technical condition, such as Assumption (S) in [27]. (Here, we modify some conditions of the original version of Assumption (S) to facilitate focusing on non-negative random variables.) Indeed, because ρ is a convex risk measure, the function r(h) := ρ (X + hy ) is convex. Thus, we get ρ X,Y = r(1) r() r () = E[Y ], (3.8) where the last equality in the above relation is obtained from (see (5.12) in [27]) and h VaR (X + hy ) = E[Y X + hy = VaR (X + hy )] (3.9) ρ (X + hy ) = h h= VaR u (X + hy )φ (u)du = E[Y ] h h= due to the dominated convergence theorem. Therefore, if β + 1 < γ, then E[Y ] ρ X,Y ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) E[Y ], 1. In Section 4, we numerically verify the above relation. Note that we can also verify a version of Assumption (S) under [C4]. Remark 2. (i) If F X is continuous, then F X (X) has a uniform distribution on (, 1) (see, for instance, Lemma A.21 in [17]). Therefore, M() with β < γ β + 1 is rewritten as M() = k β E QX [X β+1 γ ], 8

9 where E QX denotes the expectation operator with respect to the probability measure defined as Q X dq X dp = φ (F X (X)). (3.1) Note that we have ρ (X) = E QX [X], and so Q X represents the risk scenario that attains the maximum in the following robust representation of ρ (X): ρ (X) = max Q Q E Q [X], where Q is a set of probability measures on (Ω, F). Also note that if ρ = ES, then Q X is given by and therefore dq X dp = {X VaR (X)}, E QX [X β+1 γ ] = E[X β+1 γ X VaR (X)]. Until the end of Remark 2, we assume that F X and F Y are continuous. (ii) In fact, we can relax the independence condition [C1] so that X may weakly depend on Y within the negligible joint tail condition (see Remark A.1 in [2]). In this case, under some additional assumptions such as [A5] and [A6] in [2], we can make the same assertion as in Theorem 1, where the value E[Y ] in the definition (3.4) of M() is replaced by E QX [Y ]. In particular, if β + 1 < γ, then ρ X,Y E QX [Y ], 1. (3.11) Indeed, our proof in Appendix B also works by applying Theorem A.1 in [2] instead of Theorem 4.1. Note that we need some additional condition to have that (see Proposition 3 in Appendix B). lim inf E QX [Y ] > (3.12) (iii) As mentioned in Appendix A.1 of [2], we can get another version of Theorem A.1 by switching the roles of X + Y and X and by imposing modified (though somewhat artificial) mathematical conditions such as [A5 ] and [A6 ] in [2]. In particular, if β + 1 < γ, we see that VaR X,Y E[Y X + Y = VaR (X + Y )], 1 (3.13) and then (by the same proof as Theorem 1 with (3.13)) ρ X,Y E QX+Y [Y ] = ρ Euler (Y X + Y ), 1 (3.14) 9

10 under some assumptions. Here, Q X+Y is a probability measure defined by (3.1) with replacing X by X + Y. If X and Y are independent (with natural assumptions on the density functions), then (3.7) implies that (3.14) is also true. Here, note that the last equality of (3.14) is obtained by (1.3), (3.9), and the dominated convergence theorem. Indeed, we have ρ Euler (Y X + Y ) = E[Y X + Y = VaR u (X + Y )]φ (u)du = E QX+Y [Y ] (3.15) because F X+Y (X + Y ) is uniformly distributed on (, 1). In Appendix A, we will show that under some technical conditions that are more natural than both [A5] [A6] and [A5 ] [A6 ] in [2], relations (3.11) and (3.14) simultaneously hold in the case β + 1 < γ, even if X and Y are dependent. Note that if ρ = ES, then E QX+Y [Y ] = ES Euler (Y X + Y ) = E[Y X + Y VaR (X + Y )], which is known as the component CVaR (also known as the CVaR contribution) and widely used, particularly in the practice of credit portfolio risk management (see for instance [1, 19, 24]). 4 Numerical analysis In this section, we numerically investigate the behavior of ρ X,Y. Throughout this section, we assume that the distributions of X and Y are given as GPD(ξ X, σ X ) and GPD(ξ Y, σ Y ), respectively, with ξ X, ξ Y (, 1) and σ X, σ Y >, where GPD(ξ, σ) denotes the generalized Pareto distribution whose distribution function is given by 1 (1 + ξx/σ) 1/ξ, x. Then, F X and F Y satisfy (3.1) with β = 1/ξ X and γ = 1/ξ Y. Note that condition [C3] is satisfied with ( ) 1/ξY ( ) 1/ξX σy σx k = ξ Y (see (5.2) in [2]). Also note that VaR (X) and VaR (Y ) are analytically solved as ξ X VaR (X) = σ X ξ X { (1 ) ξ X 1 }, VaR (Y ) = σ Y ξ Y { (1 ) ξ Y 1 }. We numerically compute VaR X,Y = ES Euler ES Euler, ES X,Y, ρ EXP,X,Y, ρ POW,X,Y, and ES Euler, where we let (Y X + Y ) for brevity. In all calculations, we fix σ X = 1 and σ Y = 8. For ξ X and ξ Y, we examine several patterns to study each of the following three cases: (i) β + 1 < γ, (ii) β < γ β + 1, and (iii) β = γ. Case (i) β + 1 < γ We set ξ X =.5 and ξ Y =.1. Hence, β = 2 and γ = 1, so that β + 1 < γ holds. Figure 1 shows the graphs of ES X,Y, ρ EXP,X,Y, ρ POW,X,Y, and ES Euler. These values are always 1

11 larger than E[Y ] whenever (, 1), and they converge to E[Y ] for both and 1. Indeed, lim ρx,y = E[X + Y ] E[X] = E[Y ] (4.1) holds because φ ES (u), φ EXP (u), φ POW (u) 1, for each u [, 1). The limit as 1 is a consequence of Theorem 1. Moreover, the forms of these graphs are unimodal. That is, the function ρ X,Y incereases on (, ) and decreases on (, 1) for some (, 1). Intuitively, the values of ρ X,Y seem to become large as increases because a larger implies a greater risk sensitivity. However, our result implies that the impact of adding loss variable Y into the prior risk profile X is maximized at some < 1. Figure 2 shows the relation between ES X,Y and VaR X,Y. We see that ES X,Y takes a maximum at =, where is a solution to Indeed, we have the following result. VaR X,Y Proposition 1. If there is a unique solution ES X,Y. = ES X,Y. (4.2) (, 1) to (4.2), then max <<1 ESX,Y = Note that unlike the case of SRMs, VaR X,Y takes a value smaller than E[Y ] if is small. This is because VaR is not a convex risk measure, so the relation (3.8) is not guaranteed for ρ = VaR. In particular, we observe that lim VaRX,Y = essinf(x + Y ) essinf X =. (4.3) Case (ii) β < γ β + 1 Figure 3 shows the approximation errors, defined as Error = M() ρ X,Y 1 (4.4) with ξ X = 2/3 (β = 1.5) and ξ Y =.5 (γ = 2). We see that Error is close to as 1 for each case of ρ = ES, ρ EXP, ρ POW. Moreover, we numerically verify the assertion of Theorem 2 for ρ = ES in Figure 4. We observe that M /ES Euler converges to δ = 1/γ = ξ Y =.5 as 1. By contrast, the convergence speed of Error as 1 decreases if the tails of X and Y are less fat-tailed. Figure 5 shows Error with ξ X = 2/7 (β = 3.5) and ξ Y =.25 (γ = 4). We find that Error decreases as tends to 1, but the gap between Error and is still large, even in the case =.999. Case (iii) β = γ Finally, we look at the case ξ X = ξ Y =.7. The results are summarized in Figures 6 and 7. We see that Error approaches as 1 for each case of ρ = ES, ρ EXP, ρ POW. We also Euler confirm that M()/ES converges to δ = {1 + k (1 + k) 1 1/β }/k.87 as 1. Similarly to Case (ii), the convergence speed of Error decreases as the tails of X and Y become thinner. Figure 8 shows the graph of Error with ξ X = ξ Y =.3. The approximation error tends to zero as 1, but remains smaller than 2% even when =

12 5 Conluding remarks In this paper, we have studied the asymptotic behavior of the difference between ρ (X +Y ) and ρ (X) as 1 when ρ is a parameterized SRM satisfying (1.2). We have shown that ρ X,Y is asymptotically equivalent to M() given by (3.4), whose form changes according to the relative magnitudes of the thicknesses of the tails of X and Y. In particular, for β +1 < γ, we found the convergence lim ρ X,Y = E[Y ] for general CLBSRMs (ρ ). Moreover, we also 1 found that ρ X,Y δρ Euler (Y X + Y ) as 1 for a constant δ (, 1] given by (3.6). This clarifies the asymptotic relation between the marginal risk contribution and the Euler contribution. Our numerical results in the case β + 1 < γ showed that ρ X,Y is not increasing but is unimodal with respect to, which implies that the impact of Y in the portfolio X + Y does not always increase with. Interestingly, this phenomenon is inconsistent with intuition. Our results essentially depend on the assumption that X and Y are independent. However, the dependence structure of the loss variables X and Y plays an essential role in financial risk management. The case of dependent X and Y for ρ = VaR has already been studied in Section A.1 of [2]. As mentioned in Remark 2, we have now generalized this result to the case of CLBSRMs. However, we require the somewhat strong assumption that X and Y are not strongly dependent on each other. With the additional analysis in Appendix A below, we will see that our main results still hold for a general dependence structure if β + 1 < γ, but that they are easily violated if β γ β + 1. In future work, we will continue to study the asymptotic behavior of ρ X,Y as 1, without the independence condition. A A short consideration of the dependent case Here, we briefly investigate the asymptotic behavior of ρ X,Y as 1 when X and Y are not independent. Throughout this section, we assume that F X, F Y, and F X+Y are continuous. With this, (3.8) is rewritten as ρ X,Y E QX [Y ]. Combining this result with (3.3), we have E QX [Y ] ρ X,Y E QX+Y [Y ]. (A.1) Note that (A.1) holds for general SRM ρ whenever (3.9) holds. A.1 Comonotonic case We consider the case where X and Y are comonotone. In other words, they are perfectly positively dependent (see Definition 4.82 of [17] and Definition 5.15 in [22]). In this case, the following proposition is straightforwardly shown. Proposition 2. If X and Y are comonotone, then ρ X,Y = E QX [Y ] = E QX+Y [Y ] = ρ (Y ). (A.2) This proposition implies that when β + 1 < γ, the asymptotic relations (3.11) and (3.14) still hold, even if X and Y are strongly correlated, but that the assertions of Theorems 1 and 2 do not necessarily hold when β γ β

13 A.2 Additional numerical analysis Similarly to Section 4, we assume that X GPD(ξ X, σ X ) and Y GPD(ξ Y, σ Y ) with σ X = 1, σ Y = 8. To describe the dependence between X and Y, we introduce a copula. By Sklar s theorem, we see that the joint distribution function F (X,Y ) (x, y) = P (X x, Y y) of the random vector (X, Y ) is represented by F (X,Y ) (x, y) = C(F X (x), F Y (y)), for a copula C : [, 1] 2 [, 1], which is a distribution function with uniform marginals. Here, we examine the following three copulas: (a) The Gaussian copula C Gauss ρ (u, v) = Φ(Φ 1 (u), Φ 1 (v)), 1 < ρ < 1, (b) The Gumbel copula C Gumbel θ (u, v) = exp ( (( log u) θ + ( log v) θ ) 1/θ), θ 1, (c) The countermonotonic copula C cmon (u, v) = max{u + v 1, }, where Φ(x) = x e y2 /2 / 2πdy is the distribution function of the standard normal distribution (for more details on the copulas, see, for instance, Chapter 5 of [22]). The parameters ρ in (a) and θ in (b) describe the strength of the dependence between X and Y. We always set ρ =.3 and θ = 3 in this section. If C = C cmon, then X and Y are perfectly negatively dependent. In particular, in that case, X and Y are represented as X = F 1 X (U) and Y = F 1 Y (1 U), where U is a random variable with uniform distribution on (, 1). Figure 9 summarizes the results with ξ X =.5 and ξ Y =.1. We compare the values of ρ X,Y (with ρ = ES, ρ EXP, ρ POW ) and ES Euler (Y X + Y ). We find that all these values converge to the same value, which is not equal to E[Y ], by letting 1. Note that when X and Y are countermonotonic, they converge to zero as 1, so (3.12) does not hold in this case. Figure 1 shows the graphs of the relative errors defined by (4.4) with ρ = ES, ρ EXP, ρ POW when we set ξ X = 2/3 and ξ Y =.5. We find that Error does not converge to zero as 1. Similar phenomena are observed in Figure 11 with the settings ξ X = ξ Y =.7. Therefore, the assertion of Theorem 1 does not hold when β γ β + 1 if X and Y are correlated. Note that the above findings are consistent with the comonotonic case (Proposition 2). A.3 Theoretical result in the case β + 1 < γ We describe the following conditions. [C5] For each y, F X ( Y = y) has a positive, non-increasing density function f X ( Y = y) on [, ), where F X ( Y = y) is the conditional distribution function of X given Y = y. Moreover, f X (x Y = y) is continuous in x and y. [C6] There is a κ R such that f X (x Y = y) is uniformly regularly varying with index κ in the following sense: f X (tx Y = y) f X (x Y = y) tκ, x (A.3) sup y for each t >. Moreover, f X+Y is regularly varying. 13

14 [C7] It holds that sup x for some η > max{ κ β, 1}. E[Y η X = x] + sup E[Y η X + Y = z] < z (A.4) Conditions [C5] [C7] strongly correspond to conditions [A5] [A6] in [2]. It should be noted that the index parameter κ is assumed to be equal to β 1 in condition [A6] in [2], but that this equality is not required to obtain our results. Note also that κ may be different from β 1. Indeed, we can verify, at least numerically, that for each y, the function f X ( Y = y) is regularly varying with index κ = 1 β/(1 ρ 2 ) (resp., κ = θβ 1) if we adopt C = Cρ Gauss (resp., C = Cθ Gumbel ) as a copula for the random vector (X, Y ) whose marginal distributions are given by the generalized Pareto distribution. Using a similar argument as in the proof of the uniform convergence theorem (Theorem in [1]), together with the continuity of f X (x Y = y) in y, we get from (A.3) that f X (tx Y = y) f X (x Y = y) tκ, x, (A.5) sup t K sup y for each compact set K (, ). We now introduce the following result. Theorem 3. Assume [C5] [C7] and (3.12). If β + 1 < γ, it holds that E QX [Y ] ρ X,Y E QX+Y [Y ], 1. This theorem claims that both (3.11) and (3.14) are true under some conditions, even when X and Y are dependent. B Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. Assume (2.5). Fix any u [, 1). Then, (2.5) implies that (1+u)/2 lim 1 u φ (v)dv =. Because φ is non-decreasing and non-negative, we see that (1+u)/2 u φ (v)dv 1 u φ (u). 2 (B.1) (B.2) Combining (B.1) with (B.2), we have lim φ (u) =. Conversely, if we assume (2.6), then Prokhorov s theorem implies that for each increasing sequence ( n ) n 1 (, 1) with lim n n = 1 there is a further subsequence ( nk ) k 1 and a probability measure µ on [, 1] such that Φ nk weakly converges to µ as k. Then, for each β (, 1), we see that µ([, β)) lim inf k β φ nk (u)du lim inf k βφ nk (β) =. This immediately leads us to µ([, 1)) =, hence µ = δ 1. We therefore arrive at (2.5). 14

15 Proof of Proposition 1. Let f() = ES X,Y f () = where g() = ES X,Y 1 (1 ) 2. We observe that VaR X,Y u du 1 1 VaRX,Y = g() 1, VaR X,Y. By (4.1), (4.3), and Theorem 1, we see that g is continuous on (, 1), g(+) = E[Y ] > and g(1 ) =. Moreover, by the assumption, it holds that g( ) = and g() for all (, 1) \ { }. Together, these imply that g is positive on (, ) and negative on (, 1), and that f has the same pattern. Therefore, f() takes a maximum at =. Proof of Proposition 2. Because ρ is comonotonic, we obviously have ρ X,Y = ρ (X) + ρ (Y ) ρ (X) = ρ (Y ). Here, we see that X = F 1 1 X (U) and Y = FY (U) for some random variable U with uniform distribution on (, 1) (see Lemmas in [17] and their proofs). Then we have and thus Similarly, because F 1 X+Y = F 1 X E[Y X = VaR (X)] = F 1 Y () = VaR (Y ), E QX [Y ] = VaR u (Y )φ (u)du = ρ (Y ). + F 1 Y, we have E[Y X + Y = VaR (X + Y )] = VaR (Y ), and E QX+Y [Y ] = ρ (Y ), which completes the proof. B.1 Proof of Theorem 1 We first state some propositions and prove them. For this, let f be given as (3.5). Note again that M defined in (3.4) satisfies Proposition 3. lim inf 1 M() >. M() = f(u)φ (u)du. Proof. If β +1 < γ, we see that f() = E[Y ] > because Y is non-negative and F Y is positive. If β < γ β + 1, we observe M() k VaR u (X) β+1 γ φ (u)du, β k ) β VaR (X) (1 β+1 γ φ (u)du, k β VaR (X) β+1 γ >, 1, 15

16 where (, 1) is a real number satisfying VaR (X) >. The existence of such an can be proven using Propositions and in [1]. Similarly, if β = γ, we have lim inf 1 M() {(1 + k) 1/β 1}VaR (X) >. Proposition 4. f(u)du <. Proof. If β + 1 < γ, the assertion is obvious from the assumption β > 1. If β < γ β + 1, we see that because of < β + 1 γ < 1. If β = γ, we have f(u)du = k β E [X β+1 γ ] k β E [X] β+1 γ <, f(u)du = {(1 + k) 1/β 1} E[X] <. Corollary 1. M() <, (, 1). Proof. This follows from (3.2) and Proposition 4. Proof of Theorem 1. Let f() = VaR X,Y, (, 1). Note that f() lim 1 f() = 1, by virtue of Theorem 4.1(i) (iii) in [2]. Moreover, (B.3) immediately implies lim sup f(u) f(u) 1 =. 1 u [,1) (B.3) (B.4) Furthermore, it holds that f(u)du = VaR u (X + Y )du VaR u (X)du = E[X + Y ] E[X] = E[Y ] <, (B.5) hence f is integrable. The integrability of f is guaranteed by Proposition 4. Temporarily fix any δ (, 1). From (2.6) and (B.5), we easily see that Similarly, we have δ ( ) f(u)φ (u)du φ (δ) f(u)du, 1. (B.6) δ lim 1 f(u)φ (u)du =. (B.7) 16

17 Additionally, we have δ f(u)φ (u)du M() = δ f(u) f(u) ψ (u)du, (B.8) where ψ (u) = f(u)φ (u)/ M(). Using (B.7) and Proposition 3, we obtain δ ψ (u)du = 1 1 M() δ f(u)φ (u)du 1, 1. (B.9) By (B.8) and (B.9), we have δ f(u)φ (u)du 1 M() 1 ( ) f(u) δ f(u) 1 1 ψ (u)du + ψ (u)du 1 δ sup f(u) f(u) ψ (u)du 1 sup f(u) f(u) 1, 1. u [δ,1) δ u [δ,1) Combining this with (B.6) and Proposition 3, we arrive at lim sup ρ X,Y 1 M() 1 sup f(u) f(u) 1. u [δ,1) Because δ (, 1) is arbitrary, we obtain the desired assertion by (B.4). B.2 Proof of Theorem 2 Let Z = X + Y for brevity. We see that Z has a density function f Z (z) = z f X (z y)f Y (y)dy = z f X (x)f Y (z x)dx. Lemma 2. f Z is positive and continuous on (, ). Moreover, f Z is regularly varying with index min{β, γ} 1 and it holds that zf Z (z) lim z F Z (z) = min{β, γ}. (B.1) Proof. Continuity and positivity are obvious. By [C4] and Theorem 1.1 in [9], we see that f Z (z) f X (z) + f Y (z), z and that f Z is regularly varying with index max{ β 1, γ 1} = min{β, γ} 1. The last assertion is obtained by Proposition in [1]. Let F Y ( Z = z) be the conditional distribution function of Y given Z = z. Then we have Proposition 5. It holds that E[Y Z = z] = yf Y (dy Z = z). (B.11) F Y (y Z = z) = y z f X (z y ) f Y (y )dy, y, z. f Z (z) 17

18 Proof. For each y, z, a straightforward calculation gives z y z which implies our assertion. f X (z y ) f f Z (z Y (y )dy f Z (z )dz = P (Y y, Z z), ) Note that (B.11) and Proposition 5 lead to E[Y Z = z] = Proposition 6. If β + 1 < γ, then z y f X(z y) f Y (y)dy. f Z (z) (B.12) E[Y Z = VaR (Z)] E[Y ], 1. Proof. Let Then, we see that E[G (Y )] + E[H (X)] = Therefore, we need to show that First, we show that z = VaR (Z), (B.13) G (y) = y f X(z y) 1 [,z/2](y), f Z (z ) (B.14) H (x) = (z x) f Y (z x) 1 [,z/2)(x). f Z (z ) (B.15) ( z/2 ) z + y f X(z y) f Y (y)dy = E[Y Z = z ]. z /2 f Z (z ) (B.16) E[G (Y )] E[Y ], E[H (X)], 1. (B.17) G (y) y, H (x), 1 for each x, y. (B.18) Using (B.1), Lemmas A.1 and A.3 in [2], and Proposition A3.8 in [16], we obtain f X (z y) f Z (z ) = f X(z y) f X (z ) Furthermore, we observe that zf X (z ) F X (z ) F X (z ) F Z (z ) F Z (z ) z f Z (z ) 1 β 1 1 β = 1, 1. H (x) z f Y (z /2), (B.19) f Z (z ) and that the function z zf Y (z/2)/f Z (z) is regulary varying with index β +1 γ <. Thus, we obtain z f Y (z /2) f Z (z ), 1. 18

19 Now, (B.18) is obvious. Next, we observe that G (Y ) + H (X) Y f X(z /2) f Z (z ) + z f Y (z /2). f Z (z ) Because (f X (z /2)/f Z (z )) and (z f Y (z /2)/f Z (z )) are convergent (as 1), they are bounded. Thus, we have G (Y ) + H (X) C(Y + 1) (B.2) for some C >. By (B.18) and (B.2), we can apply the dominated convergence theorem to obtain (B.17). Proposition 7. If β + 1 = γ, then E[Y Z = VaR (Z)] E[Y ] + kγ β, 1. Proof. Let z, G (y), and H (x) be the same as in (B.13) (B.15). First, we have E[G (Y )] E[Y ], 1 by the same argument as in the proof of Proposition 6. Next, for each x, we see that H (x) = (z x)f Y (z x) F Y (z x) F Y (z x) F Y (z ) F X (z ) F Z (z ) F Z (z ) z f Z (z ) 1 [,z /2)(x) γ 1 k 1 1 β 1 = kγ β, 1 z F Y (z ) F X (z ) due to [C3], (B.1), Proposition A3.8 in [16], Proposition 3.1(i) in [2], and Lemmas A.1 and A.3 in [2]. Moreover, we have (B.19), and the right-hand side of this inequality converges to 2 γ+1 kγ/β as 1, and so it is bounded. Therefore, we apply the dominated convergence theorem to obtain E[H (X)] kγ/β as 1. We complete the proof by combining these with (B.16). Proposition 8. If β < γ < β + 1, we have E[Y Z = VaR (Z)] kβ γ VaR (X) β+1 γ, 1. Proof. Let z, G (y) and H (x) be set as earlier. Similarly to the proof of Propositions 6 and 7, we get E[G (Y )] E[Y ], 1. This implies that E[G (Y )]/x β+1 γ, 1, where x = VaR (X). Therefore, it suffices to show that E[H (X)]/x β+1 γ kβ/γ as 1, which is easy to see by using similar calculations as in the proof of Proposition 7 and by using Proposition 3.1(i) in [2]. Proposition 9. If β = γ, then E[Y Z = VaR (Z)] k(1 + k) 1+1/β VaR (X), 1. 19

20 Proof. Similarly to the proof of Proposition 8, we need to show only that E[ H (X)] k(1 + k) 1+1/β, 1, (B.21) where H (x) = H (x)/x. Note that Lemmas A.1 and A.2 in [2] imply F Z (x) F X (x) + F Y (x) (1 + k) F X (x) (k 1 + 1) F Y (x), x and z (1 + k) 1/β x, 1. Therefore, for each x, we observe H (x) = z (z x)f Y (z x) F Y (z x) F Y (z ) x F Y (z x) F Y (z ) F Z (z ) F Z (z ) z f Z (z ) 1 [,z /2)(x) (1 + k) 1/β k β k 1 β 1 = k(1 + k) 1+1/β, 1 by [C3], (B.1), Proposition A3.8 in [16], and Lemma A.3 in [2]. Moreover, we have H (x) z f Y (z /2) x f Z (z ) 2 γ+1 k(1 + k) 1+1/β, 1, and thus we obtain (B.21) by applying the dominated convergence theorem. Proof of Theorem 2. We can verify that the random vector (X, Y ) satisfies (a version of) Assumption (S) in [27] by using a standard argument. Therefore, (3.9) is true from (5.13) in [27]. Additionally, using Propositions 6 9, we see that for each ε >, there is an (, 1) such that δḡ() f() 1 < ε, [, 1), (B.22) where we denote ḡ() = E[Y Z = VaR (Z)]. Moreover, it is easy to see that f and ḡ are bounded on [, ]. Therefore, combining (3.9), (3.15), and (B.22), we get δρ Euler (Y Z) 1 M() {( ) 1 } 1 δ sup ḡ(u) + sup f(u) φ (u)du + ε f(u)φ (u)du M() u [, ] u [, ] ε δ, 1, where δ = lim inf M(), which is positive due to Proposition 3. Because ε > is arbitrary, 1 we obtain the desired assertion. B.3 Proof of Theorem 3 First, note that condition [C5] immediately implies [C2] with x = and f X (x) = f X (x Y = y)f Y (dy). 2

21 Second, note that by [C6], Proposition 3.1(i) in [2] (see also Remark 3.2 therein) and Proposition A3.8 in [16], we have (B.1) and f X (x) f Z (x), x. (B.23) To prove Theorem 3, we give the following three propositions. Proposition 1. VaR (X + uy ) is continuously differentiable in u [, 1] and it holds that u VaR (X + uy ) = E[Y X + uy = VaR (X + uy )], u 1. Proposition 1 is obtained by an argument similar to the proof of Lemma 5.3 in [27], using the implicit function theorem. Proposition 11. The function x E[Y X = x] is regularly varying with index κ + β + 1. Proof. Fix any t >. We observe that E [Y X = tx] t κ+β+1 E[Y X = x] y f X(x Y = y) f X (tx Y = y) f X (x) f X (x Y = y) fx(x) { sup x f X (x) f X (tx) sup y f X (tx) tκ+β+1 F Y (dy), } f X (tx Y = y) f X (x Y = y) tκ + f X (x) tκ f X (tx) tβ+1 E[Y X = x], and therefore, using [C5], we arrive at lim x E [Y X = tx] E[Y X = x] tκ+β+1 =. Proposition 12. E[Y X = x] E[Y X + Y = x], x. Proof. Fix any ε >. Then we have E[Y Z = x] E[Y X = x] A ε (x) + B ε (x), where we denote Z = X + Y and A ε (x) = εx y f X (x y Y = y) f X(x Y = y) f Z (x) f X (x) F Y (dy), B ε (x) = E[Y 1 {Y >εx} Z = x] + E[Y 1 {Y >εx} X = x]. By [C7] and the Chebyshev inequality, we get B ε (x) E[Y X = x] C ε η 1 x η 1 E[Y X = x], (B.24) for some C >. Because Proposition 11 tells us that x x η 1 E[Y X = x] is regularly varying with index η + κ + β >, the right-hand side of (B.24) converges to zero as x (see Proposition in [1]). 21

22 Moreover, we see that A ε (x) = εx ε y f X(x Y = y) f X (x) ux f X(x Y = ux) f X (x) f X (x y Y = y) fx(x) f X (x Y = y) f Z (x) 1 F Y (dy) f X ((1 u)x Y = ux) fx(x) f X (x Y = ux) f Z (x) 1 F Y/x(du), x >. Here, we observe that f X ((1 u)x Y = ux) fx(x) f X (x Y = ux) f Z (x) 1 1 (1 u) κ + (1 u) κ f X (x) f Z (x) 1 + f X ((1 u)x Y = ux) f X (x Y = ux) (1 u) κ f X (x) f Z (x), for each u [, ε]. Note that if κ (resp., κ < ), we have (1 ε) κ (1 u) κ 1 (resp., 1 (1 u) κ (1 ε) κ ). Moreover, by (B.23), f X (x)/f Z (x) converges to 1 as x, and so it is bounded. Therefore, we get { A ε (x) E[Y X = x] 1 (1 ε) κ + max{1, (1 ε) κ } f X (x) f Z (x) 1 } +C sup 1 ε t 1 sup y f X (tx Y = y) f X (x Y = y) tκ, for some C >. Now we arrive at lim sup x E [Y Z = x] E[Y X = x] 1 1 (1 ε)κ by using (A.5) and (B.23). Because ε > is arbitrary, we obtain the desired assertion. Proof of Theorem 3. First, note that Proposition 1 guarantees that E QX [Y ] = E[Y X = x u ]φ (u)du, E QX+Y [Y ] = E[Y X + Y = z u ]φ (u)du, where x u = VaR u (X) and z u = VaR u (X + Y ). Then, fix any ε >. By Propositions and Lemma A.3 in [2], we see that E[Y X = x ] E[Y X = z ] E[Y X + Y = z ], 1, Thus, there is an (, 1) such that E [Y X + Y = z ] 1 E[Y X = x ] < ε, [, 1). 22

23 Therefore, we have E QX+Y [Y ] 1 E QX [Y ] 1 E QX [Y ] 1 E QX [Y ] ε, 1 E[Y X + Y = z u ] E[Y X = x u ] φ (u)du {E[Y X + Y = z u ] + E[Y X = x u ]} φ (u)du + ε by virtue of (3.12). Because ε > is arbitrary, we get that E QX [Y ] E QX+Y [Y ], 1. Combining this result with (A.1), we obtain the desired assertion. References [1] Andersson, F., Mausser, H., Rosen, D. and Uryasev, S. (21) Credit Risk Optimization with Conditional Value-at-Risk Criterion, Mathematical Programming Series B, 89(2), [2] Acerbi, C. (22) Spectral Measures of Risk: A Coherent Representation of Subjective Risk Aversion, Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(7), /S (2)281-9 [3] Acerbi, C., Nordio, C. and Sirtori, C. (21) Expected Shortfall as a Tool for Financial Risk Management, Preprint. [4] Acerbi, C. and Tasche, D. (22) Expected Shortfall: A Natural Coherent Alternative to Value at Risk, Economic Notes, 31(2), [5] Acerbi, C. and Tasche, D. (22) On the Coherence of Expected Shortfall, Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(7), [6] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M. and Heath, D. (1999) Coherent Measures of Risk, Mathematical Finance, 9(3), [7] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (212) Fundamental Review of the Trading Book, Press Release, Bank for International Settlements. bcbs219.pdf [8] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (216) Minimum Capital Requirements for Market Risk, Press Release, Bank for International Settlements. publ/d352.pdf [9] Bingham, N. H., Goldie, C. M. and Omey, E. (26) Regularly Varying Probability Densities, Publications de l Institut Mathematique, 8(94), PIM69447B [1] Bingham, N. H., Goldie, C. M. and Teugels, J. L. (1989) Regular Variation, Cambridge University Press. 23

24 [11] Brandtner, M. and Kürsten, W. (217) Consistent Modeling of Risk Averse Behavior with Spectral Risk Measures: Wächter/Mazzoni Revisited, European Journal of Operational Research, 259(1), [12] Cotter, J. and Dowd, K. (26) Extreme Spectral Risk Measures: An Application to Futures Clearinghouse Margin Requirements, Journal of Banking & Finance, 3(12), [13] Dowd, K. and Blake, D. (26) After VaR: The Theory, Estimation, and Insurance Applications of Quantile-Based Risk Measures, The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73(2), [14] Dowd, K., Cotter, J. and Sorwar, G. (28) Spectral Risk Measures: Properties and Limitations, Journal of Financial Services Research, 34(1), /s [15] Embrechts, P. (2) Extreme Value Theory: Potential and Limitations as an Integrated Risk Management Tool, Derivatives Use, Trading & Regulation, 6(1), [16] Embrechts, P., Klüppelberg, C. and Mikosch, T. (1997) Modelling Extremal Events, Springer. [17] Föllmer, H. and Schied, A. (216) Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time 4th rev. ed., De Gruyter. [18] Jouini, E., Schachermayer, W. and Touzi, N. (26) Law Invariant Risk Measures Have the Fatou Property, In: Kusuoka, S. and Yamazaki, A., Ed., Advances in Mathematical Economics, 9, 49 71, Springer, Japan. [19] Kalkbrener, M., Kennedy, A. and Popp, M. (27) Efficient Calculation of Expected Shortfall Contributions in Large Credit Portfolios, Journal of Computational Finance, 11(2), [2] Kato, T. (217) Theoretical Sensitivity Analysis for Quantitative Operational Risk Management, International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 2(5), 23 pages. [21] Kusuoka, S. (21) On Law-invariant Coherent Risk Measures, In: Kusuoka, S. and Maruyama, T., Ed., Advances in Mathematical Economics, 3, 83 95, Springer, Japan. [22] McNeil, A.J., Frey, R. and Embrechts, P. (25) Quantitative Risk Management, Princeton University Press, Princeton. [23] Pflug, G. Ch. and Römisch, W. (27) Modeling, Measuring and Managing Risk, World Scientific Publishing Co., London. [24] Puzanova, N. and Düllmann, K. (213) Systemic Risk Contributions: A Credit Portfolio Approach, Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(4), j.jbankfin

25 [25] Shapiro, S. (213) On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures, Mathematics of Operations Research, 38(1), [26] Sriboonchitta, S., Nguyen, H. T. and Kreinovich, V. (21) How to Relate Spectral Risk Measures and Utilities, International Journal of Intelligent Technologies and Applied Statistics, 3(2), [27] Tasche, D. (2) Risk Contributions and Performance Measurement, Working Paper b26adab4fb68846e8334a49dd.pdf [28] Tasche, D. (22) Expected Shortfall and Beyond, Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(7), [29] Tasche, D. (28) Capital Allocation to Business Units and Sub-portfolios: The Euler Principle, In: Resti, A., Ed., Pillar II in the New Basel Accord: The Challenge of Economic Capital, , Risk Books, London. [3] Wächter, H.P. and Mazzoni, T. (213) Consistent Modeling of Risk Averse Behavior with Spectral Risk Measures, European Journal of Operational Research, 229(2),

26 Figure 1: Graphs of ES X,Y (blue), ρ EXP,X,Y (orange), ρ POW,X,Y (green) and ES Euler (Y X + Y ) (black, dashed) with ξ X =.5 and ξ Y =.1. The red solid line shows E[Y ]. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Figure 2: Graphs of ES X,Y (blue) and VaR X,Y (brown, dashed) with ξ X =.5 and ξ Y =.1. The red solid line shows E[Y ]. The horizontal axis corresponds to. 26

27 Figure 3: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξ X = 2/3 and ξ Y =.5. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρ EXP. Green line: ρ = ρ POW. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Euler Figure 4: M()/ES (blue) and δ = 1/γ = ξ Y (red). We set ξ X = 2/3 and ξ Y =.5. The horizontal axis corresponds to. 27

28 Figure 5: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξ X = 2/7 and ξ Y =.25. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρ EXP. Green line: ρ = ρ POW. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Figure 6: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξ X = ξ Y =.7. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρ EXP. Green line: ρ = ρ POW. The horizontal axis corresponds to. 28

29 Euler Figure 7: M()/ES (blue) and δ = {1 + k (1 + k) 1 1/β }/k (red). We set ξ X = ξ Y =.7. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Figure 8: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξ X = ξ Y =.3. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρ EXP. Green line: ρ = ρ POW. The horizontal axis corresponds to. 29

30 Figure 9: Graphs of ESX,Y (blue), ρexp,x,y (orange), ρpow,x,y (green) and Euler ES (Y X + Y ) (black, dashed) with ξx =.5 and ξy =.1. The red solid line shows E[Y ]. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Left: C = CρGauss with ρ =.3. Center: C = CθGumbel with θ = 3. Right: C = C cmon. Figure 1: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξx = 2/3 and ξy =.5. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρexp. Green line: ρ = ρpow. The horizontal axis corresponds Gauss Gumbel to. Left: C = Cρ with ρ =.3. Center: C = Cθ with θ = 3. Right: C = C cmon. Figure 11: Approximation errors defined by (4.4) with ξx = ξy =.7. Blue line: ρ = ES. Orange line: ρ = ρexp. Green line: ρ = ρpow. The horizontal axis corresponds to. Left: Gauss C = Cρ with ρ =.3. Center: C = CθGumbel with θ = 3. Right: C = C cmon. 3

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Finance & Stochastics seminar Imperial College, November 20, 2013 1 The opinions

More information

On the coherence of Expected Shortfall

On the coherence of Expected Shortfall On the coherence of Expected Shortfall Carlo Acerbi Dirk Tasche First version: March 31, 2001 This update: September 12, 2001 Abstract Expected Shortfall (ES) in several variants has been proposed as remedy

More information

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Modern Risk Management of Insurance Firms Hannover, January 23, 2014 1 The

More information

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures Michael Kalkbrener Deutsche Bank AG Abstract An axiomatic definition of coherent capital allocations is given. It is shown

More information

Theoretical Sensitivity Analysis for Quantitative Operational Risk Management

Theoretical Sensitivity Analysis for Quantitative Operational Risk Management Theoretical Sensitivity Analysis for Quantitative Operational Risk Management Takashi Kato arxiv:1104.0359v5 [q-fin.rm] 24 May 2017 First Version: April 3, 2011 This Version: May 24, 2017 Abstract We study

More information

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 3332. Abstract. In this

More information

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Walter Schneider July 26, 20 Abstract In this paper an analytic expression is given for the bounds

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Susanne Emmer Dirk Tasche September 15, 2003 Abstract Even in the simple Vasicek one-factor credit portfolio model, the exact contributions

More information

Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk

Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Haijun Li Department of Mathematics Washington State University Humboldt Univ-Berlin Haijun Li Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Humboldt Univ-Berlin

More information

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions Samuel Drapeau Michael Kupper Ranja Reda October 6, 21 We give robust representations of law-invariant monotone quasiconvex functions.

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Introduction Extreme Scenarios Asymptotic Behavior Challenges Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Seminar at ETH Zurich

More information

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Jin Peng, Shengguo Li Institute of Uncertain Systems, Huanggang Normal University, Hubei 438, China Email: pengjin1@tsinghua.org.cn lisg@hgnu.edu.cn Abstract: A key

More information

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas Claudia Klüppelberg Technische Universität München email: cklu@ma.tum.de http://www-m4.ma.tum.de References: - Böcker, K. and Klüppelberg, C. (25) Operational VaR

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Institut de mathématiques de Toulouse 2 juin 2014 Joint work with F. Gamboa, A. Garivier (IMT) and B. Iooss (EDF R&D). 1 Coherent measure of

More information

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming Operations Research Letters 37 2009 143 147 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Operations Research Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/orl On a time consistency concept in risk averse

More information

Coherent risk measures

Coherent risk measures Coherent risk measures Foivos Xanthos Ryerson University, Department of Mathematics Toµɛας Mαθηµατ ικὼν, E.M.Π, 11 Noɛµβρὶoυ 2015 Research interests Financial Mathematics, Mathematical Economics, Functional

More information

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Risk Measures under Solvency II Dietmar Pfeifer (2004) Risk measures and premium principles a comparison VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Dependence and its implications for risk measures

More information

Risk Aversion and Coherent Risk Measures: a Spectral Representation Theorem

Risk Aversion and Coherent Risk Measures: a Spectral Representation Theorem Risk Aversion and Coherent Risk Measures: a Spectral Representation Theorem Carlo Acerbi Abaxbank, Corso Monforte 34, 2122 Milano (Italy) July 1, 21 Abstract We study a space of coherent risk measures

More information

Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation

Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation Bin Wang and Ruodu Wang January, 015 Abstract We introduce the concept of an extremely negatively dependent (END) sequence of random variables with a given

More information

A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk

A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk A Theory for Measures of Tail Risk Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/~wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Extreme Value Analysis Conference 2017 TU Delft

More information

Modeling of Dependence Structures in Risk Management and Solvency

Modeling of Dependence Structures in Risk Management and Solvency Moeling of Depenence Structures in Risk Management an Solvency University of California, Santa Barbara 0. August 007 Doreen Straßburger Structure. Risk Measurement uner Solvency II. Copulas 3. Depenent

More information

Risk Aggregation and Model Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation and Model Uncertainty Risk Aggregation and Model Uncertainty Paul Embrechts RiskLab, Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor www.math.ethz.ch/ embrechts/ Joint work with A. Beleraj, G. Puccetti and L. Rüschendorf

More information

On convex risk measures on L p -spaces

On convex risk measures on L p -spaces MMOR manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) On convex risk measures on L p -spaces M. Kaina and L. Rüschendorf University of Freiburg, Department of Mathematical Stochastics, Eckerstr. 1, 79104

More information

Research Article Continuous Time Portfolio Selection under Conditional Capital at Risk

Research Article Continuous Time Portfolio Selection under Conditional Capital at Risk Hindawi Publishing Corporation Journal of Probability and Statistics Volume 2010, Article ID 976371, 26 pages doi:10.1155/2010/976371 Research Article Continuous Time Portfolio Selection under Conditional

More information

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas Claudia Klüppelberg Technische Universität München email: cklu@ma.tum.de http://www-m4.ma.tum.de References: - Böcker, K. and Klüppelberg, C. (25) Operational VaR

More information

Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures

Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures Multivariate comonotonicity, stochastic orders and risk measures Alfred Galichon (Ecole polytechnique) Brussels, May 25, 2012 Based on collaborations with: A. Charpentier (Rennes) G. Carlier (Dauphine)

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency

Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency Alexander J. McNeil 1 1 Heriot-Watt University Edinburgh Vienna April 2012 a.j.mcneil@hw.ac.uk AJM Stress Testing 1 / 50 Regulation General Definition of Stress

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables

Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables Asymptotic Bounds for the Distribution of the Sum of Dependent Random Variables Ruodu Wang November 26, 2013 Abstract Suppose X 1,, X n are random variables with the same known marginal distribution F

More information

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs arxiv:1806.01497v1 [math.oc] 5 Jun 2018 A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology Atlanta,

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 on bivariate Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 07: April 2, 2015 1 / 54 Outline on bivariate 1 2 bivariate 3 Distribution 4 5 6 7 8 Comments and conclusions

More information

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model arxiv:cond-mat/0302402v5 [cond-mat.other] 4 Jan 2005 Susanne Emmer Dirk Tasche Dr. Nagler & Company GmbH, Maximilianstraße 47, 80538 München,

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Risk Management Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Value at Risk (VaR) Extreme Value Theory (EVT) References

More information

On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models

On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models Hideatsu Tsukahara Department of Economics, Seijo University e-mail address: tsukahar@seijo.ac.jp 1 Introduction In general, the purpose of backtesting is twofold:

More information

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications

Bregman superquantiles. Estimation methods and applications Bregman superquantiles Estimation methods and applications Institut de mathématiques de Toulouse 17 novembre 2014 Joint work with F Gamboa, A Garivier (IMT) and B Iooss (EDF R&D) Bregman superquantiles

More information

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods Duality and Methods Darinka Dentcheva 1 Andrzej Ruszczyński 2 1 Stevens Institute of Technology Hoboken, New Jersey, USA 2 Rutgers University Piscataway, New Jersey, USA Research supported by NSF awards

More information

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson.

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management February 6, 2019 As we discussed last semester, the general goal of risk measurement is to come up with a single metric that can be used to make financial

More information

Finanzrisiken. Fachbereich Angewandte Mathematik - Stochastik Introduction to Financial Risk Measurement

Finanzrisiken. Fachbereich Angewandte Mathematik - Stochastik Introduction to Financial Risk Measurement ment Convex ment 1 Bergische Universität Wuppertal, Fachbereich Angewandte Mathematik - Stochastik @math.uni-wuppertal.de Inhaltsverzeichnis ment Convex Convex Introduction ment Convex We begin with the

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH

More information

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples VU University Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences Jagiellonian University Faculty of Mathematics and Computer Science Joint Master of Science Programme Dorota Kopycka Student no. 1824821 VU, WMiI/69/04/05 UJ

More information

Additivity properties for Value-at-Risk under Archimedean dependence and heavy-tailedness

Additivity properties for Value-at-Risk under Archimedean dependence and heavy-tailedness Additivity properties for Value-at-Risk under Archimedean dependence and heavy-tailedness Paul Embrechts, Johanna Nešlehová, Mario V. Wüthrich Abstract Mainly due to new capital adequacy standards for

More information

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug, Alois Pichler June 16, 15 Abstract In management and planning it is commonplace for additional information

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures F. Bellini 1, B. Klar 2, A. Müller 3, E. Rosazza Gianin 1 1 Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca 2 Institut für Stochastik,

More information

Tail Value-at-Risk in Uncertain Random Environment

Tail Value-at-Risk in Uncertain Random Environment Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Tail Value-at-Risk in Uncertain Random Environment Yuhan Liu Dan A. Ralescu Chen Xiao Waichon Lio Abstract Chance theory is a rational tool to be

More information

An Academic Response to Basel 3.5

An Academic Response to Basel 3.5 An Academic Response to Basel 3.5 Risk Aggregation and Model Uncertainty Paul Embrechts RiskLab, Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor www.math.ethz.ch/ embrechts/ Joint work with

More information

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 8, 2014, no. 109, 5439-5447 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2014.43176 Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued

More information

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity 3 214 5 ( ) Journal of East China Normal University (Natural Science) No. 3 May 214 Article ID: 1-5641(214)3-23-7 Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity TIAN De-jian, JIANG Long, JI

More information

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions Nicole Lorenz Gert Wanka In this paper we give subdifferential formulas of some convex deviation measures using their conjugate functions

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}.

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}. So far in this course we have used several different mathematical expressions to quantify risk, without a deeper discussion of their properties. Coherent Risk Measures Lecture 11, Optimisation in Finance

More information

A Review and Some Complements on Quantile Risk Measures and Their Domain

A Review and Some Complements on Quantile Risk Measures and Their Domain risks Article A Review and Some Complements on uantile Risk Measures and Their Domain Sebastian Fuchs 1 * ID, Ruben Schlotter 2 and Klaus D. Schmidt 3 1 Faculty of Economics and Management, Free University

More information

Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation

Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation Shijie Wang a, Yiyu Hu a, Lianqiang Yang a, Wensheng Wang b a School of Mathematical Sciences,

More information

Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming

Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 30332. Abstract. In

More information

Estimating Bivariate Tail: a copula based approach

Estimating Bivariate Tail: a copula based approach Estimating Bivariate Tail: a copula based approach Elena Di Bernardino, Université Lyon 1 - ISFA, Institut de Science Financiere et d'assurances - AST&Risk (ANR Project) Joint work with Véronique Maume-Deschamps

More information

Distribution-Invariant Risk Measures, Entropy, and Large Deviations

Distribution-Invariant Risk Measures, Entropy, and Large Deviations Distribution-Invariant Risk Measures, Entropy, and Large Deviations Stefan Weber Cornell University June 24, 2004; this version December 4, 2006 Abstract The simulation of distributions of financial positions

More information

Ruin, Operational Risk and How Fast Stochastic Processes Mix

Ruin, Operational Risk and How Fast Stochastic Processes Mix Ruin, Operational Risk and How Fast Stochastic Processes Mix Paul Embrechts ETH Zürich Based on joint work with: - Roger Kaufmann (ETH Zürich) - Gennady Samorodnitsky (Cornell University) Basel Committee

More information

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups L. Rüschendorf J. Witting February 23, 2017 Abstract We derive improved estimates for the model risk of risk portfolios when additional

More information

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Stoyan V. Stoyanov Svetlozar T. Rachev September 3, 7 Abstract In this paper, we prove a result for the asymptotic distribution of the sample

More information

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation 4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation We consider a discrete-time information structure given by a filtration (F t ) t=0,...,t on our probability space (Ω, F, P ). The time horizon

More information

Aggregation-Robustness and Model Uncertainty of Regulatory Risk Measures

Aggregation-Robustness and Model Uncertainty of Regulatory Risk Measures Aggregation-Robustness and Model Uncertainty of Regulatory Risk Measures Paul Embrechts, Bin Wang and Ruodu Wang February 10, 2014 Abstract Research related to aggregation, robustness, and model uncertainty

More information

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures Nonlife Actuarial Models Chapter 4 Risk Measures Learning Objectives 1. Risk measures based on premium principles 2. Risk measures based on capital requirements 3. Value-at-Risk and conditional tail expectation

More information

Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order

Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order Hee Seok Nam a,, Qihe Tang a, Fan Yang b a Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Iowa, 241 Schaeffer Hall, Iowa City,

More information

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS EVA IV, CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS Jose Olmo Department of Economics City University, London (joint work with Jesús Gonzalo, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid) 4th Conference

More information

Lu Cao. A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics

Lu Cao. A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics Multivariate Robust Vector-Valued Range Value-at-Risk Lu Cao A Thesis in The Department of Mathematics and Statistics Presented in Partial Fulllment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science

More information

Optimal Risk Sharing with Different Reference Probabilities

Optimal Risk Sharing with Different Reference Probabilities Optimal Risk Sharing with Different Reference Probabilities Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland July 29, 2008 Abstract We investigate the problem of optimal risk sharing between agents endowed with cashinvariant

More information

Pareto Optimal Allocations for Law Invariant Robust Utilities

Pareto Optimal Allocations for Law Invariant Robust Utilities Pareto Optimal Allocations for Law Invariant Robust Utilities on L 1 Claudia Ravanelli Swiss Finance Institute Gregor Svindland University of Munich and EPFL November 2012 Abstract We prove the existence

More information

Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence

Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence Journal of Operational Risk 51 57) Volume 1/Number 2, Summer 2006 Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence Mikhail Makarov EVMTech AG, Baarerstrasse 2, 6300 Zug, Switzerland In this paper we

More information

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures Jakub Černý Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance November 10, 2014 1 / 25 Contents CVaR - Dual

More information

Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas

Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas Klaus Böcker Claudia Klüppelberg Abstract Simultaneous modelling of operational risks occurring in different event type/business line

More information

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Paola Bortot Department of Statistical Sciences - University of Bologna paola.bortot@unibo.it Abstract: Quantifying dependence between

More information

Sum of Two Standard Uniform Random Variables

Sum of Two Standard Uniform Random Variables Sum of Two Standard Uniform Random Variables Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/~wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Dependence Modeling in Finance, Insurance

More information

Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures

Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures IMA New Directions Short Course on Mathematical Optimization Jim Luedtke Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering University of Wisconsin-Madison August

More information

The newsvendor problem with convex risk

The newsvendor problem with convex risk UNIVERSIDAD CARLOS III DE MADRID WORKING PAPERS Working Paper Business Economic Series WP. 16-06. December, 12 nd, 2016. ISSN 1989-8843 Instituto para el Desarrollo Empresarial Universidad Carlos III de

More information

Lecture 2 One too many inequalities

Lecture 2 One too many inequalities University of Illinois Department of Economics Spring 2017 Econ 574 Roger Koenker Lecture 2 One too many inequalities In lecture 1 we introduced some of the basic conceptual building materials of the course.

More information

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity homas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover knispel@stochastik.uni-hannover.de AnStAp0 Vienna, July

More information

X

X Correlation: Pitfalls and Alternatives Paul Embrechts, Alexander McNeil & Daniel Straumann Departement Mathematik, ETH Zentrum, CH-8092 Zürich Tel: +41 1 632 61 62, Fax: +41 1 632 15 23 embrechts/mcneil/strauman@math.ethz.ch

More information

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Emir Kamenica and Matthew Gentzkow University of Chicago June 2010 1 Persuasion mechanisms In this paper we study a particular game where Sender chooses a signal π whose

More information

arxiv: v3 [math.oc] 25 Apr 2018

arxiv: v3 [math.oc] 25 Apr 2018 Problem-driven scenario generation: an analytical approach for stochastic programs with tail risk measure Jamie Fairbrother *, Amanda Turner *, and Stein W. Wallace ** * STOR-i Centre for Doctoral Training,

More information

Multivariate Stress Scenarios and Solvency

Multivariate Stress Scenarios and Solvency Multivariate Stress Scenarios and Solvency Alexander J. McNeil 1 1 Heriot-Watt University Edinburgh Croatian Quants Day Zagreb 11th May 2012 a.j.mcneil@hw.ac.uk AJM Stress Testing 1 / 51 Regulation General

More information

LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS. S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov. September 25, 2011

LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS. S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov. September 25, 2011 LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov September 25, 20 Abstract We study large deviations of linear functionals on an isotropic

More information

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs Klaus Abberger, University of Konstanz, Germany Abstract: For a bivariate data set the dependence structure can not only be measured

More information

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Alexander Shapiro Abstract. We discuss in this paper asymptotics of the sample average approximation (SAA) of the optimal value of a minimax stochastic programming

More information

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Ka Chun Cheung, Michel Denuit, Jan Dhaene AFI_15100 TAIL MUTUAL EXCLUSIVITY AND TAIL-VAR LOWER BOUNDS KA CHUN CHEUNG Department of Statistics and Actuarial

More information

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI Research supported by the NSF award CMMI-0965689 Outline 1 Risk-Averse Preferences 2 Coherent Risk Measures 3 Dynamic Risk Measurement 4 Markov Risk Measures 5 Risk-Averse Control Problems 6 Solution Methods

More information

Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation

Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation Yannan Sun Haijun Li July 00 Abstract This paper presents a general tail approximation method for evaluating the Valueat-Risk of

More information

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Proceedings of the World Congress on Engineering 29 Vol II WCE 29, July 1-3, 29, London, U.K. Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Tao Jiang Abstract

More information

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas Eric Zivot Updated: May 10, 2010 Reading MFTS, chapter 19 FMUND, chapters 6 and 7 Introduction Capturing co-movement between financial asset returns

More information

Extreme Value Analysis and Spatial Extremes

Extreme Value Analysis and Spatial Extremes Extreme Value Analysis and Department of Statistics Purdue University 11/07/2013 Outline Motivation 1 Motivation 2 Extreme Value Theorem and 3 Bayesian Hierarchical Models Copula Models Max-stable Models

More information

Overview of Extreme Value Theory. Dr. Sawsan Hilal space

Overview of Extreme Value Theory. Dr. Sawsan Hilal space Overview of Extreme Value Theory Dr. Sawsan Hilal space Maths Department - University of Bahrain space November 2010 Outline Part-1: Univariate Extremes Motivation Threshold Exceedances Part-2: Bivariate

More information

The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach

The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach Marcello Galeotti 1, Emanuele Vannucci 2 1 University of Florence, marcello.galeotti@dmd.unifi.it 2 University of Pisa,

More information

n! (k 1)!(n k)! = F (X) U(0, 1). (x, y) = n(n 1) ( F (y) F (x) ) n 2

n! (k 1)!(n k)! = F (X) U(0, 1). (x, y) = n(n 1) ( F (y) F (x) ) n 2 Order statistics Ex. 4. (*. Let independent variables X,..., X n have U(0, distribution. Show that for every x (0,, we have P ( X ( < x and P ( X (n > x as n. Ex. 4.2 (**. By using induction or otherwise,

More information

Information measures in simple coding problems

Information measures in simple coding problems Part I Information measures in simple coding problems in this web service in this web service Source coding and hypothesis testing; information measures A(discrete)source is a sequence {X i } i= of random

More information

Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures

Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures Ruodu Wang November 29, 2015 Abstract We introduce regulatory arbitrage of risk measures as one of the key considerations in choosing a suitable risk measure to use

More information

Comparing downside risk measures for heavy tailed distributions

Comparing downside risk measures for heavy tailed distributions Comparing downside risk measures for heavy tailed distributions Jon Danielsson Bjorn N. Jorgensen Mandira Sarma Casper G. de Vries March 6, 2005 Abstract In this paper we study some prominent downside

More information

Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints

Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints Charles University in Prague Faculty of Mathematics and Physics Portfolio optimization with stochastic dominance constraints December 16, 2014 Contents Motivation 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 Contents Motivation

More information

Worst-Case Expected Shortfall with Univariate and Bivariate. Marginals

Worst-Case Expected Shortfall with Univariate and Bivariate. Marginals Worst-Case Expected Shortfall with Univariate and Bivariate Marginals Anulekha Dhara Bikramjit Das Karthik Natarajan Abstract Worst-case bounds on the expected shortfall risk given only limited information

More information