STATIONARY EQUILIBRIA IN ASSET-PRICING MODELS WITH INCOMPLETE MARKETS AND COLLATERAL

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "STATIONARY EQUILIBRIA IN ASSET-PRICING MODELS WITH INCOMPLETE MARKETS AND COLLATERAL"

Transcription

1 Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 6 (November, 2003), STATIONARY EQUILIBRIA IN ASSET-PRICING MODELS WITH INCOMPLETE MARKETS AND COLLATERAL BY FELIX KUBLER AND KARL SCHMEDDERS 1 We consider an infinite-horizon exchange economy with incomplete markets and collateral constraints. As in the two-period model of Geanakoplos and Zame (2002), households can default on their liabilities at any time, and financial securities are only traded if the promises associated with these securities are backed by collateral. We examine an economy with a single perishable consumption good, where the only collateral available consists of productive assets. In this model, competitive equilibria always exist and we show that, under the assumption that all exogenous variables follow a Markov chain, there also exist stationary equilibria. These equilibria can be characterized by a mapping from the exogenous shock and the current distribution of financial wealth to prices and portfolio choices. We develop an algorithm to approximate this mapping numerically and discuss ways to implement the algorithm in practice. A computational example demonstrates the performance of the algorithm and shows some quantitative features of equilibria in a model with collateral and default. KEYWORDS: Collateral, default, incomplete markets, Markov equilibrium. 1. INTRODUCTION LUCAS (1978) CONSIDERS AN EXCHANGE ECONOMY with a single perishable consumption good where infinitely lived identical agents trade shares in physical assets ( trees ). We extend the model to allow for heterogeneous agents who not only can trade in trees but can also make promises by selling financial securities. As in the two-period model of Geanakoplos and Zame (2002), agents can default on these promises at any time without any utility penalties or loss of reputation. Financial securities are therefore only traded if the promises associated with these securities are backed by collateral. The only collateral in this economy consists of shares in the physical assets. Under the assumption that all exogenous variables are Markovian, there exist Markov equilibria that can be characterized by a mapping from the exogenous shock and the current distribution of financial wealth to prices and portfolio choices. We develop an algorithm to approximate this mapping numerically 1 We thank seminar participants at the 2001 CEME General Equilibrium Conference at Brown, the SCE conference 2001 at Yale, SAET 2001 in Ischia, the 2001 Workshop on Game Theory in Stony Brook, the Tow conference on Computational Economics at the University of Iowa, the workshop on mathematical economics at IMPA/Rio de Janeiro, the 2002 Latin American meeting of the Econometric Society at Sao Paulo, Arizona State University, UC Davis, HEC Paris, the University of Maastricht, the University of Melbourne, the University of New South Wales, Northwestern University, the University of Rochester, and Stanford University, and in particular Jayasri Dutta, John Geanakoplos, Ken Judd, Dirk Krueger, Mordecai Kurz, Hanno Lustig, George Mailath, Alvaro Sandroni, and Steve Tadelis for helpful comments and conversations. We thank three anonymous referees and the Co-Editor for very useful suggestions on earlier drafts. 1767

2 1768 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS and give details on how to implement the algorithm on a computer. The implementation of the algorithm allows us to compute equilibria for realistically calibrated examples. We consider a simple model with a single tree (representing aggregate equity) and show that significant welfare gains can be obtained from collateralized borrowing. We also illustrate how equilibrium default may be welfare-improving. We include collateral and default in an infinite-horizon economy with incomplete markets because of the necessity to have economically meaningful constraints on agents choices. In models with infinitely lived agents, investors possible trading strategies have to be restricted to avoid Ponzi schemes. Levine and Zame (1996) propose a so-called implicit debt constraint that ensures that, in equilibrium, agents unconstrained Euler equations always hold. Unfortunately, when there are stocks in the economy, which pay dividends over more than one period, and when markets are incomplete, sequential equilibria do not always exist under this constraint. 2 Moreover, in calibrated models, an implicit debt constraint implies unrealistically high levels of individual debt; along the equilibrium path, agents sometimes borrow more than 20 times their yearly income. These problems have led applied researchers to impose much tighter exogenous debt constraints as well as short-sale constraints. Without modeling default, however, these constraints have no economic interpretation. Dubey, Geanakoplos, and Shubik (2000) and Geanakoplos and Zame (2002) incorporate default and collateral into the standard two-period GEI model. In Geanakoplos and Zame (2002), agents have to put up durable goods as collateral when they want to take short positions in financial markets. Economic agents are allowed to default on their promises, but in the case of default, the collateral associated with the promise is seized and distributed among the creditors. Araujo, Pascoa, and Torres-Martinez (2002) extend the model to a dynamic framework with infinitely lived agents and prove equilibrium existence. In this paper we simplify the model in Araujo, Pascoa, and Torres-Martinez (2002) to make it computationally tractable. A key feature of our model is that, just as in Geanakoplos and Zame (2002) and Araujo, Pascoa, and Torres- Martinez (2002), agents default on their promises whenever the market value of the shares they hold as collateral is lower than the face value of their promise. To obtain a better understanding of the impact of collateral constraints and default on the dynamic behavior of economies with incomplete markets, it is necessary to compute equilibria in such models. Computationally, it is only feasible to approximate equilibria that are dynamically simple in the sense that all endogenous variables are functions of some current state that follows a Markov 2 Magill and Quinzii (1996) show existence generically in infinite dividend sequences but their genericity conditions do not translate directly to conditions on an economy with stationary dividends and endowments.

3 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1769 process. It is standard in modern macroeconomics to study the equilibrium dynamics indirectly by using recursive methods. According to Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000), recursive methods characterize a pair of functions: a transition function mapping the state of the model today into the state tomorrow and a policy function mapping the state into the other endogenous variables of the model. Previous computational work on models with incomplete markets and heterogeneous agents (e.g., Heaton and Lucas (1996), Judd, Kubler, and Schmedders (2003)) focuses on equilibria that can be described recursively, using as a state the current shock combined with last period s portfolio holdings. Unfortunately, for interesting specifications of the model, there are no known conditions that guarantee the existence of such equilibria (even without collateral constraints and default; see Kubler and Schmedders (2002)). When the state is taken to include all current endogenous variables, a Markov equilibrium does exist (see Duffie et al. (1994)), but the transition function that maps the state today into the state tomorrow can be arbitrarily complicated, and it is often impossible to determine even the set over which it is defined. In this paper we develop an alternative approach by merging a recursive method with the ideas of Duffie et al. (1994). The endogenous state is the collection of all current endogenous variables. Our notion of a stationary equilibrium is similar to a recursive equilibrium in that it also consists of a transition map and a policy map. However, in our approach, the policy map is a correspondence that maps beginning-of-period financial wealth (cash at hand) into possible current-period equilibrium prices and portfolios. The transition maps the current state into next periods endogenous states under the restriction that these have to lie in the graph of the policy map. Adapting an argument from Duffie et al. (1994) we construct a nonempty policy correspondence. Since it is computationally impossible to compute exact equilibria, the objective of our algorithm is to search for approximate equilibria that can be described via a policy function. We define a notion of ɛ-equilibrium and discuss its relation to exact equilibria. While the described algorithm is not globally convergent (i.e., we cannot prove that for arbitrary economies and arbitrary ɛ>0 it always computes a Markov ɛ-equilibrium), we find it to be very robust for a wide variety of calibrated economies. We use the algorithm to determine the impact of different collateral requirements on equilibrium welfares. In the model, the collateral requirement is exogenously given, and it is a natural question whether there are margin requirements that are socially optimal. In our examples, the households disagree on optimal margin requirements. Agents who own most of the financial wealth in the economy prefer low collateral requirements although they lead to frequent default in equilibrium while poor households prefer high requirements that lead to no default. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. We introduce the model in Section 2. In Section 3 we give an existence proof of a Markov equilibrium that provides the basis for the development of an algorithm. Section 4 defines

4 1770 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS and discusses ɛ-equilibria and describes the implementation of the algorithm. A computational example in Section 5 demonstrates the performance of our algorithm and shows some quantitative features of equilibria in a model with collateral and default. Section 6 concludes. 2. THE ECONOMIC MODEL We examine a model of an exchange economy that extends over an infinite time-horizon and is populated by infinitely-lived heterogeneous agents. The Physical Economy At each period t 0oneofY possible exogenous shocks y Y ={1 Y} occurs. We represent the resolution of uncertainty by an event tree Σ. The root of the tree σ 0 is given by a fixed state y 0 Y in which the economy starts at time 0. Each node of the tree is characterized by a history of shocks σ = (y 0 y t ).Eachnodeσ has Y immediate successors, (σy) y = 1 Y and a unique predecessor σ. To simplify notation we sometimes include the root node s predecessor σ 0 in the event tree Σ. The exogenous shocks follow a Markov process with transition matrix π At each node σ Σ there is a single perishable consumption good. There are H agents, which we collect in a set H. Atnodeσ Σ agent h s individual endowment in the consumption good, e h (σ), depends on the current shock alone, i.e. e h (σ y) = e h (y) where e h : Y R ++ is a time-invariant function. In addition, the agent owns shares in physical assets (i.e., Lucas trees these assets can be interpreted as firms, machines, land, or houses). There are A different such assets, which we collect in A. At period 0 each agent h owns a share θ h(σ ) 0oftreea and we normalize a 0 h H θh(σ a 0 ) = 1foralla A. At a node σ = (σ y) let θ h a (σ) denote agent h s (end-of-period) share in tree a. We assume that trees are traded cum dividends, that is, buying a tree allows the agent to harvest the fruit in the same period: If agent h holds a share θ h(σ) of tree a, then he obtains a dividend payment a θh a (σ) dh a (y) The dividend that asset a produces when it is held by agent h, d h : Y R a + depends solely on the current state y Y.Ifd h a is identical across all agents h H then we have the standard Lucas model. We allow the payoff of some collateralizable assets to depend on their current owner. This generalization of the model makes no sense when the trees represent equity as in Lucas model. However, there is at least one alternative interpretation of trees for which the generalization is useful: In Shleifer and Vishny (1992) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), the collateralizable asset can only be used productively if owned by agents who can operate it. Harvesting the trees requires human capital that cannot be traded: the tree may be full of fruit, but if the agent who owns it has to pick the fruit, he may lose some of it in the process.

5 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1771 With this construction of dividends, aggregate consumption depends on the distribution of assets and is therefore endogenous. We define an upper bound on aggregate consumption for each shock y by ē(y) = h H e h (y) + max d h (y) a h H a A Agent h H maximizes a time-separable expected utility function { } U h (c) = E β t u h h(c t y t ) t=0 We assume that the possibly state dependent Bernoulli function u h ( y) : R ++ R is strictly monotone, C 2, strictly concave, bounded above, and unbounded below, i.e., u h (x y) as x 0, for all y Y. In order to rule out that agents are almost satiated at aggregate endowments, we assume that there exists a consumption level ĉ such that for all h H, min u h (ĉ y) > 1 max u h (ē(y) y) y Y 1 β h y Y We also assume that each agent s discount factor lies between zero and one, β h (0 1), and that all agents agree on the transition matrix for the shock process. In the following discussion we will suppress the dependence of u h on y whenever there is no possibility of confusion. Markets We consider an economy with security trading in every time period. Agent h can buy θ h(σ) shares of tree a at node σ for a price q a a(σ). Aslongasθ h 0 a there is no possibility of default since no promises are made when shares of the physical assets change hands. In addition to the physical assets, there are J financial assets, which we collect in a set J. These assets are one-period securities; asset j traded at node σ promises a payoff b j (σy) = b j (y) > 0 at the successor nodes (σy), y = 1 Y.Wedenoteagenth s portfolio in financial assets by φ h and write p j (σ) for the price of asset j. Agents can only sell (short) a financial security if they hold shares of trees as collateral. At each node σ, weassociatean A-dimensional vector k j (σ) > 0 of collateral requirements with each financial security j J. If an agent sells 1 unit of security j she is required to hold k j a (σ) dollars worth of each tree a = 1 A as collateral. If an asset a can be used as collateral for different financial securities, the agent is required to invest k j a (σ) for each j = 1 J. In the next period the agent can default on her promise b j In this case the buyer of the financial security gets the collateral associated with the promise.

6 1772 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS We allow the margin requirement k j a to vary across nodes, but to retain stationarity it must be a function of the current shock and current period endogenous variables. We write k j (σ) = k ( j a a p(σ) q(σ) (θ h (σ) c h (σ)) h H y ) for some continuous functions k j a ( y), y Y. In order to rule out trivial equilibria we need to assume that for all j J, y Y, q c, andθ, (1) inf k j (p q c θ y)>0 a p 0 for at least one a A For notational simplicity we sometimes suppress the dependence of k on σ. Since there are no penalties for default, a seller of an asset defaults at a node σ = (σ y) whenever b j (y) > a A kj (σ a )(q a (σ)/q a (σ )). By individual rationality, the actual payoff of security j at node σ = (σ y) is therefore always given by { f j (σ) = min b j (y) k j (σ a ) q } a(σ) q a A a (σ ) Note that an agent can default on individual promises without declaring personal bankruptcy and giving up all the assets he owns. Since this implies that the decision to default on a promise is independent of the debtor, we do not need to consider pooling of contracts as in Dubey, Geanakoplos, and Shubik (2000), even though there may be default in equilibrium. This treatment of default is somewhat unconvincing since default does not affect a household s ability to borrow in the future and it does not lead to any direct reduction in consumption at the time of default. Moreover, declaring personal bankruptcy typically results in a loss of all assets, and it is rarely possible to default on some loans while keeping the collateral for others. However, there do exist laws for collateralizable borrowing where default is possible without declaring bankruptcy. Examples include pawn shops and the housing market in some U.S. states, in which households are allowed to default on their mortgages without defaulting on other debt. Conversely, in some U.S. states such as Texas and Florida, property can be seized in a personal bankruptcy, but houses are exempt from seizure. Our model therefore captures some aspect of default even though it is certainly not a compelling model of bankruptcy. Our model is analytically tractable and default provides a rationale for collateral constraints. Following Geanakoplos and Zame (2002), we can endogenize the margin requirements by introducing a menu of financial securities. All securities promise the same payoff, but they distinguish themselves by the margin requirement. In equilibrium only some of them will be traded, thereby determining an endogenous margin requirement.

7 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1773 We can also determine the existence of socially optimal margin requirements. In Section 5 we consider a simple example, which shows that there is often disagreement between agents on welfare-maximizing requirements. Financial Markets Equilibrium with Collateral An economy E is a collection of Bernoulli functions, impatience parameters, state-dependent endowments and asset promises, transition probabilities and collateral requirements, E = ( (u h β h e h θ h (σ 0 ) dh ) h H b π k ) We define a financial markets equilibrium as follows: DEFINITION 1: A financial markets equilibrium for an economy E with initial tree holdings (θ h (σ 0 )) h H and initial shock y 0 is a collection ( ( θ 1 (σ) φ 1 (σ) c 1 (σ)) ( θ H (σ) φ H (σ) c H (σ)) q 1 (σ) q A (σ) p 1 (σ) p J (σ) ) σ Σ satisfying the following conditions: (i) Markets clear: θ h (σ) = 1 and h H h H (ii) For each agent h: φ h (σ) = 0 forallσ Σ ( θ h (σ) φ h (σ) c h (σ)) arg max U h (c) θ 0 φ c 0 such that for all σ = (σ y) Σ c h (σ) = e h (y) + φ h (σ ) f(σ)+ θ h (σ ) q(σ) + θ h (σ) (d h (y) q(σ)) φ h (σ) p(σ) q a θ h (σ) + a k j a φh(σ) 0 j j J :φ h j (σ)<0 (a = 1 A) The following observation from Duffie et al. (1994) is important throughout the analysis of this paper: In each financial markets equilibrium, agents optimality implies that there exists a positive lower bound on an agent s optimal consumption. For each agent h and shock y we can define a lower bound on consumption, c h (y) > 0 by u h (c h (y) y) + β h max 1 β h y Y u h (ē(y ) y ) 1 min u h (e h (y ) y ) 1 β h y Y

8 1774 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS Let c h = min y c h (y). This positive lower bound for possible equilibrium consumption always exists, since all utility functions u h are unbounded from below. The term on the right-hand side is a lower bound on the agent s lifetime utility if the agent has sold all her shares in trees, because she can still afford to consume her labor endowments e h (y). The second term on the left-hand side is an upper bound on the agent s utility after the first period because consumption is bounded above by aggregate endowments. Financial Wealth In any financial markets equilibrium, tree prices are positive, q>0 We define ω h (σ) as household h s fraction of financial wealth (cash at hand) in the economy at the beginning of node σ = (σ y),i.e. ω h (σ) := θh (σ ) q(σ) + φ h (σ ) f(σ) A q a=1 a(σ) Let Ω(σ) = (ω 1 (σ) ω H (σ)) Note that by the definition of f, in equilibrium Ω always lies in the (H 1)-dimensional simplex H 1 i.e. ω h 0 h H and h H ωh = 1. If all initial tree holdings are proportional (i.e. if for all h H, thereisa θ h such that θ h a (σ 0 ) = θ h for all a A), we must have that ω h (σ 0 ) = θ h. 3. EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM Araujo et al. (2002) consider a model that is related to ours, but with durable and storable goods instead of long-lived assets, and prove that equilibria always exist. However, since we are interested in approximating equilibria numerically, an adaptation of their existence proof to our model would not help us. We want to describe equilibria as a mapping from the beginning-of-period wealth distribution to current period equilibrium prices and portfolio holdings. From such a mapping we are able to infer a transition mapping the current state of the economy into next period s state. We call equilibria that can be described in such a way Markov Markov Equilibrium In order to define our notion of Markov equilibrium, we need to adapt some concepts from Duffie et al. (1994) to our model The State Space We let the state space S consist of all exogenous and endogenous variables that occur in the economy at some node σ,i.e.s = Y Z,whereY is the finite

9 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1775 set of exogenous shocks and Z is the set of all possible endogenous variables. Let z(σ) = (Ω(σ) (c h (σ) θ h (σ) φ h (σ)) h H q(σ) p(σ)) be the endogenous state at node σ. We define the endogenous state space as Z = { z H 1 R H + RAH + RHJ R A + RJ + : h H θh a = 1foralla A h H φh j = 0forallj J } By definition, in any financial markets equilibrium, all endogenous variables lie in Z We will make frequent use of the set of endogenous variables without the wealth variables, and we denote this set by Z ˆ Note that Z = H 1 Z ˆ Expectations Correspondence For a set X,letX Y be the Cartesian product of Y copies of X. Given a state (y z) S, the expectations correspondence g : S Z Y describes all next period states that are consistent with market clearing and agents first-order conditions. A vector of endogenous variables (z + 1 z+ Y ) g(s) if for all households h H the following conditions hold. (a) For all y = 1 Y, ω h+ y = θh q + + y j J φh min{b j j(y) a A kj q ay + a q a } A a=1 q+ ay and c h+ y = e h (y) + ω h+ y A a=1 q + ay + θh+ y (d h (y) q + y ) φh+ y p + y ch (b) There exist multipliers λ h R A and + µh R A + such that for all a A the following equations and inequalities hold: (2) (3) (4) (5) µ h a q a + λ h a + (dh a q a)u h (ch ) + β h E s{ q + a u h (ch+ ) } = 0 λ h a θh = 0 a ( q a θ h + a µ h a q a θ h a + j J :φ h j <0 k j a φh j {j J :φ h j <0} k j a φh j 0 ) = 0

10 1776 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS (c) In addition, if we define φ h( ) = max(0 j φh) and j φh j (+) = max(0 φ h), there exist multipliers j νh (+) ν h ( ) R J +,suchthatforallj J the following conditions are satisfied: (6) µ h a kj p a ju h (ch ) + β h E s{ f j u h (ch+ ) } ν h j ( ) = 0 a A (7) p j u h (ch ) + β h E s{ f j u h (ch+ ) } + ν h j (+) = 0 ν h (+) φ h (+) = 0 (8) (9) ν h ( ) φ h ( ) = 0 Conditions (a) follow from the definition of ω and the budget constraint. The conditions (b) are part of the standard first-order conditions with respect to θ h a Finally, conditions (c) consist of the Kuhn Tucker conditions with respect to φ h j, where we treat the choices of long and short positions in the asset separately (i.e. the agent chooses both φ h( ) and j φh j (+) and therefore has two first-order conditions for each financial asset). There is a redundancy in the Kuhn Tucker conditions in (b): if the collateral constraint for an asset a is satisfied, the short-sale constraint on this collateralizable asset holds automatically. We keep the redundant conditions for illustrative purposes. We need the following lemma to show existence. All proofs are collected in the Appendix. LEMMA 1: The graph of g is a closed subset of S Z Y Definition of Markov Equilibrium A Markov equilibrium consists of a (nonempty valued) policy correspondence, P, and a transition function, F, P : Y H 1 ˆ Z and F : graph(p) Z Y such that for all s graph(p) and all y Y F(s) g(s) and (y F y (s)) graph(p) We say a Markov equilibrium is simple if the associated policy correspondence is single valued. The following lemma verifies that Markov equilibria are in fact competitive equilibria in the usual sense. LEMMA 2: A Markov equilibrium is a financial markets equilibrium according to Definition 1.

11 ASSET-PRICING MODELS Constructing Markov Equilibria In constructing a Markov equilibrium (P F), we closely follow the existence proof in Duffie et al. (1994). The basic idea of our approach is very similar to backward induction. We start with a compact set, T Z ˆ that is large enough to ensure that for all finitely truncated economies the endogenous variables take equilibrium values in T. The fact that such a set exists is established in Lemma 3 below. Assuming that next period s equilibrium variables can be described by some correspondence, V n : Y H 1 T we define for each exogenous shock y and wealth distribution Ω a new correspondence, V n+1 where V n+1 (y Ω) is the set of all endogenous variables today that are consistent (in the sense that all agents first-order conditions and market clearing hold) with some ((Ω 1 ẑ 1 ) (Ω Y ẑ Y )) tomorrow for which ẑ y V n (y Ω).Withthis construction, V n n=1 (y Ω) is nonempty for all y Y, Ω H 1. Formally, given a compact set T Z ˆ and a correspondence V : Y H 1 T define an operator, G T that maps the correspondence V : Y H 1 T to a new correspondence W : Y H 1 T as follows: W = G T (V ) if for all Ω H 1 and all y Y, W(y Ω)= { (c θ φ q p) T : (z 1 z Y ) g(y Ω c θ φ q p) such that for all y Y (c y θ y φ y q y p y ) V(y Ω y ) where z y = (Ω y c y θ y φ y q y p y ) } In order to construct a policy correspondence we first need a suitable set T that is large enough to contain all endogenous variables. We define a truncated economy with T + 1 periods to be a finite-horizon economy with an event tree, where all nodes of the form σ = (y 0 y 1 y T ) are terminal nodes. Endowments and asset payoffs at nodes of the truncated tree, as well as agents preferences over consumption at these nodes, are the same as in the infinite-horizon economy. LEMMA 3: For all T 1 there exists a financial markets equilibrium for the truncated economy in which values of all prices, asset holdings, and consumption allocations lie in a compact set T Z ˆ Define V 0 by V 0 (y Ω) = T for all Ω H 1 and all y Y. Given a correspondence V n n= 0 1 define recursively V n+1 = G T (V n ) Finally let (10) V (y Ω) := V n (y Ω) n=1 We can now state our main theorem. for all y Y Ω H 1 THEOREM 1: The correspondence V is nonempty valued and there exists a Markov equilibrium with policy correspondence V.

12 1778 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS Equilibrium Correspondence Remarkably, the correspondence V as constructed above contains all possible values of first period endogenous variables for all equilibria with values in the bounded set T Let the equilibrium correspondence, B y (Ω), contain all ((c h θ h φ h ) h H q p)for which there exists a financial markets equilibrium for initial shock y and initial tree-holdings θ h(0 a ) = ω h for all h H, a A with ( (c h θ h φ h ) h H q p ) = ( ( c h (σ 0 ) θ h (σ 0 ) φ h (σ 0 )) h H q(σ 0 ) p(σ 0 ) ) and with all endogenous variables lying in T. For any policy correspondence P,weobviouslyhaveP(y Ω) B y (Ω) for all Ω H 1 y Y. More importantly, we have V (y Ω) = B y (Ω).Forcomputational purposes, it would be important to know under which conditions there exists a (single-valued) selection of B that is also a policy correspondence. We know of no nontrivial conditions. 4. COMPUTATION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIA To examine quantitative features of equilibria, we develop an algorithm to approximate Markov equilibria numerically. The algorithm searches for a continuous policy function that describes prices and allocations, such that markets clear and agents make small optimization errors. Since computed equilibria suffer from rounding and truncation errors, they are (almost) never exact. We therefore define an ɛ-equilibrium. The purpose of the described algorithm is then to find ɛ-equilibria for small ɛ>0. We will interpret ɛ-equilibria purely as a computational necessity. To assess the quality of a solution from a numerical procedure, it is now common in computational work to examine the relative errors in agents first-order conditions (see den Haan and Marcet (1994), Judd (1998), and Santos (2000)) Epsilon-Equilibria We define an ɛ-equilibrium by requiring that in the expectations correspondence relative errors in Euler equations (i.e. the relative error in equations (2), (6), and (7)) are smaller than ɛ for all (Ω y) H 1 Y. In the definition, we assume that market clearing and budget constraints hold exactly. Since in numerical work all equations hold at most with machine precision, this is an idealization. In Section 4.3 below, we argue how this can be justified.

13 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1779 To define an ɛ-markov equilibrium, we define an approximate expectations correspondence g ɛ as in Section above, with the exception that we replace equation (2) by 1 + µhq a a + λ h + β a he s {q + a u h (ch+ )} (2 ) (q a d q )u h (ch ) ɛ equation (6) by 1 + a A µh a kj + β a he s {f j u h (ch+ )} ν h( ) j (6 ) p j u h (ch ) ɛ and (7) by 1 + β he s {f j u h (ch+ )}+ν h(+) j (7 ) p j u h (ch ) ɛ An ɛ-markov equilibrium is then a pair (P ɛ F ɛ ) such that for all s graph(p ɛ ) and all y Y, (y F ɛ y (s)) graph(p ɛ ) and F ɛ (s) g ɛ (s) An ɛ-markov equilibrium is simple if P ɛ is a function. While simple exact equilibria may fail to exist (see Kubler and Schmedders (2002) 3 ), simple ɛ-equilibria always exist. The following argument from Kubler and Polemarchakis (2002) proves how this follows from the existence of an exact Markov equilibrium. By construction, the equilibrium correspondence V has a compact graph. Therefore, for each ɛ 1 > 0 there exists a finite set F ɛ 1 graph(v ) such that [ ] sup inf s s <ɛ 1 s graph(v ) s F ɛ 1 which can be written as the graph of a function v ɛ 1 : Y Z, with the finite sets Z Z ˆ and H 1 ensuring that if ( c θ φ q p) Z then for all y Y there exist Ω and (c θ φ q p)= v ɛ 1 (y Ω) such that for all h, ω h = θ h q + φ h f A a=1 q a 3 Krebs (2000) also discusses existence in these models, but his analysis rests crucially on the absence of trading constraints and has therefore no implications for our model.

14 1780 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS Given an ɛ>0, by continuity of the utility functions, for sufficiently small ɛ 1 the function v ɛ 1 describes a simple Markov ɛ-equilibrium. Evidently, by construction, this function can generally not be extended to a continuous function over H 1. Before we describe our algorithm for computing ɛ-equilibria in Section 4.3 we discuss possible interpretations of ɛ-equilibria Interpretation of ɛ-equilibria As mentioned above, we view our focus on ɛ-equilibria as a computational necessity. A different motivation would be to argue that economic agents have bounded computational capacity and can only find approximately optimal choices. Any improvement over their choices results in an extra gain of at most ɛ (see, e.g., Akerlof and Yellen (1985)). However, in our model there is a tension between assuming that agents have rational expectations about future prices and assuming that they make errors in choosing their consumptions given the correct forecasts for prices. Furthermore, since markets clear exactly, future prices must already reflect the agents optimization errors. In order to relate computed ɛ-equilibria to exact equilibria we suggest estimation of perturbations that need to be imposed on the exogenous variables in order to obtain the results actually computed as approximate solutions. 4 In the context of dynamic games, Mailath, Postlewaite, and Samuelson (2002) show that a pure ɛ-nash equilibrium is an exact Nash equilibrium of a game with nearby discount factors and reward functions. Similarly, we want to interpret acomputedɛ-equilibrium as an approximate equilibrium of some other economy with endowments and preferences that are close to those in the original economy. As an example, consider a simple economy without financial assets and with a single tree. In this case, perturbing the individual discount factors at every node is sufficient for obtaining an economy for which a computed ɛ-equilibrium is exact: 5 We can assume without loss of generality that in equation (2 ) λ h = 0. If for some agent h, λ h > 0 and the left-hand side of equation (2 ) is nonzero, the error in the equation can be reduced by varying λ h.in a the optimum, either the error or λ h must be equal to zero. In order for a (2 )to hold exactly, it suffices that the true impatience parameter β h is replaced by some β h satisfying β 1 + ɛ β h β 1 ɛ 4 In numerical analysis this method is called backward error analysis (see, e.g., Judd (1998, p. 48)). 5 If there are several trees or financial securities in the economy, the perturbations need to involve individual endowments as well. Deriving exact bounds for this case is subject to further research.

15 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1781 Unfortunately, for a given ɛ>0 it is generally impossible to infer how close computed allocations and prices are to exact equilibrium allocations and prices for the same economy. In simple finite-dimensional fixed-point problems, it is obvious that f(x) <ɛdoes not always imply (reasonable) bounds on x x for an x with f(x ) = 0. General conditions that ensure that approximate fixed points are close to true fixed points have to involve higher derivatives of f at x and are often difficult to obtain (see, for example, Blum et al. (1998, Chapter 8)). In our infinite-horizon models, matters are even worse. As ɛ 0 there is no guarantee that the ɛ-equilibrium allocation converges to an exact equilibrium allocation. It is easy to construct an ɛ-equilibrium for the above simple example that is not close to an exact equilibrium of the original economy. The intuition is that small errors in the Euler equations may propagate over time and lead to large errors in the long run behavior of the model. This poses a challenge for computational methods that claim to approximate an exact equilibrium by an ɛ-equilibrium and it is the reason why we include perturbations of exogenous parameters. In applications of dynamic general equilibrium models most exogenous variables such as discount factors, endowments, or asset dividends are often not known exactly. The approximation of equilibria for a close-by economy might then be almost as interesting as the approximation of equilibria for the given economy The Algorithm We compute an approximate 6 policy function via an iterative algorithm. Denote this function by ρ : Y H 1 T As a starting point, we choose a continuous function ρ 0 : Y H 1 T In each iteration of the algorithm, given functions ρ n we construct ρ n+1 y (Ω) for all y Y Ω H 1 by taking a selection of G T (ρ n ) Intuitively, we assume that the values of the endogenous variables in the next period, as a function of agents wealth, is determined by the function ρ n We then move backwards one period and determine ρ n+1 by solving for an equilibrium in the current period. The algorithm terminates if for some prespecified δ>0 (11) sup ρ n+1 ρ n <δ y Ω We define a candidate policy function, ρ = ρ n+1 and examine the quality of the solution by computing the maximum relative error in Euler equations. If this error lies above some prespecified ɛ we restart the algorithm with a lower value for δ. 6 For the remainder of the paper, we drop the adjective approximate. It is understood that all equilibria we compute are only ɛ-equilibria.

16 1782 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS Our algorithm will not converge if there does not exist a continuous policy function. In our practical computational experience using realistically calibrated models, this problem has not occurred. The implemented algorithm has always produced a policy function. Outline of Main Steps The actual implementation of the algorithm involves several tedious details, many of which are common in the literature on finding equilibrium functions for infinite-horizon problems. We do not discuss them in detail here and instead refer to the survey by Judd, Kubler, and Schmedders (2003). We focus on the aspects of the algorithm that are new to the literature. We restrict attention to economies with H = 2 agents. In this case, the wealth distribution is represented by a single number in the unit interval. Therefore the equilibrium policy function ρ is a function of only the discrete exogenous state variable y and the single continuous wealth variable ω 1 [0 1]. We approximate the equilibrium functions by cubic splines (i.e. twice differentiable piecewise cubic functions; see deboor (1978)). In order to handle nondifferentiabilities in the policy functions, we use several hundred knots (i.e. pieces in the spline-approximation). We solve for the spline coefficients using a time-iteration collocation algorithm similar to the one described in detail in Judd, Kubler, and Schmedders (2003). As the example in Section 5 demonstrates, in economies with collateral constraints, policy functions may not be smooth on the entire domain, but instead exhibit some kinks. At these kinks cubic splines are not well behaved approximating functions. Therefore we need to use many knots in order to obtain a good approximation. On the other hand, we cannot use lower order piecewise polynomials, such as piecewise linear functions, since we want to approximate the smooth portions of the policy and price functions with differentiable functions. Our choices regarding the approximation of the equilibrium functions represent a trade-off between the goal of achieving approximations with small errors and the need for keeping running times at acceptable levels. More knots would increase the precision and the running times; fewer knots would reduce the precision and running times. Given a wealth distribution Ω = (ω 1 1 ω 1 ), the current shock y today, and the spline coefficients of an approximate map from tomorrow s wealth distribution into tomorrow s prices and portfolio holdings ξ, we need to solve for prices and optimal choices today that lie in G(ρ n ) In order to do so, we simultaneously solve two systems of nonlinear equations. Given a value for wealth shares next period, ω 1+, (p q (θ h φ h ) h=1 2 ) lie in G(ρ n ) at ω 1 if and only if they solve all first order conditions and markets today clear. The Kuhn Tucker inequalities in these first order conditions can easily

17 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1783 be replaced by equalities via a change of variable (see Garcia and Zangwill (1981)) and the system can be written as (12) F(q p (θ h φ h ) h=1 2 ; ω 1 y ξ)= 0 In order to infer tomorrow s wealth share, ω 1+ (which is implicit in equation (12)), from today s choices, we solve a second nonlinear system of equations. Given choices (θ h φ h ) h=1 2 today, as well as approximate equilibrium price functions ρ n q (y Ω; ξ), tomorrow s wealth distribution Ω+ must solve (13) ω 1+ (y) := θ1 ρ n(y q ω1+ ; ξ) + φ 1 f(y ω 1+ ) A a=1 ρn q a (y ω 1+ ; ξ) We can solve this single equation in the one unknown ω 1+ using a standard Newton solver. Via equation (13), we have then tomorrow s optimal choices implicitly defined as functions of today s portfolio choices, and so equation (12) is well defined. The system can be solved with standard nonlinear equation solvers. At the beginning of iteration n the spline coefficients ξ n for the policy function iterate ρ n are given. For each shock y = 1 Y and on agridofω 1 [0 1] the algorithm solves the nonlinear system of equations (12) for prices and choices (q p (θ h φ h ) h H ) The resulting functions (q p (θ h φ h ) h H )(y ω 1 ) are then approximated by splines with new coefficients, ξ n+1 and the next iteration begins. Since we use interpolating splines, we need to solve (12) at as many points as there are spline-knots for each shock y. Our algorithm can be summarized as follows: Time Iteration Spline Collocation Algorithm Step 0: Select an error tolerance δ for the stopping criterion (11), a finite grid W [0 1] of collocation points, and the spline coefficients ξ 0 for a starting point ρ 0 Step 1: Given spline coefficients ξ n and thus the function ρ n, solve system (12) ω 1 W y Y finding a solution (q p (θ h φ h ) h H )(y ω 1 ) Step 2: The implicit wealth share ω 1+ in (12) is found by solving (13). Compute the new approximations ρ n+1, that is, the new coefficients ξ n+1 by interpolation of (q p (θ h φ h ) h H )(y ω 1 ) ω 1 W y Y Step 3: Check stopping criterion (11). If sup y Ω ρ n+1 ρ n <δ,thengotostep4. Otherwise increase n by 1 and go to Step 1. Step 4: The algorithm terminates. Set ρ = ρ n+1.

18 1784 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS Epsilon-Equilibria and Computed Equilibria In order to assess the accuracy of a candidate solution we compute the maximal relative error in Euler equations on a grid of 10,000 points. Evidently this error only provides a lower bound on the true maximal error in Euler equations. However, since our approximated functions are continuous and (except at a small number of kinks) smooth, the true maximal error is not likely to be much higher. As mentioned above, market-clearing and all budget constraints will also not hold exactly but only with machine precision. The machine precision lies around (on most PC s). Therefore, errors in budget constraints and market clearing are always several orders of magnitude below the errors in Euler equations and can thus be suppressed in our analysis. We revisit the issue of numerical errors (and running times) in Section 5.1 in the context of a concrete example Recursive Equilibria and Simple Markov Equilibria Existing algorithms to approximate equilibria in infinite-horizon models with incomplete markets focus on recursive equilibria. In these equilibria, the endogenous state space consists of agents previous period s portfolio choices (see, for example, Heaton and Lucas (1996) and Judd, Kubler, and Schmedders (2003)). In order to approximate such a recursive equilibrium, the set of possible portfolios must be compact and known ex ante. Exogenous portfolio bounds are used to ensure this compactness requirement. Obviously, we cannot use this equilibrium concept in a model with default and collateral constraints where portfolios are only bounded endogenously. In addition, it appears unlikely that the portfolio choices from the previous period are sufficient state variables, since the payoffs of financial assets depend on previous-period prices. If there are no financial securities in our model (and the tree s dividends are independent of its owner), there are no collateral constraints and thus our model essentially reduces to a version of Lucas (1978) model with heterogeneous agents. In this case, we can use our algorithm to compute recursive equilibria. The set of admissible portfolios is known and compact, and a recursive equilibrium is described by a function mapping portfolios and the current shock, (Θ y) ( H 1 ) A Y to current-period prices and portfolios. Although we cannot show that the existence of simple Markov equilibria is equivalent to the existence of recursive equilibrium, we can construct a recursive equilibrium (if it exists 7 ) from a simple Markov equilibrium with a continuous policy corre- 7 Recursive equilibria do not always exists (see Kubler and Schmedders (2002)), but it is not clear whether there are examples where simple Markov equilibria exist but recursive equilibria do not.

19 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1785 spondence. The construction is as follows: For all Θ = (θ h ) h H ( H 1 ) A the function Γ Θ : H 1 H 1 defined by Γ Θ (Ω) = θh q(ω) A a=1 q a(ω) is continuous and therefore always has a fixed-point. Numerically, we solve for this fixed point by solving equation (13). The subproblem of solving equation (13) is an innovation, which is made necessary by the use of the state variable wealth. Contrary to the literature of computing recursive equilibria, the agents choice variables (portfolios) are not state variables. Agents portfolio decisions today do not immediately yield tomorrow s wealth distribution. Since the dimension of the domain of the equilibrium map is independent of the number of securities traded, this setup is a significant practical improvement over existing algorithms, which, due to a curse of dimensionality, cannot consider models with more than two assets (see Judd, Kubler, and Schmedders (2003) for an overview). In particular, our algorithm can be used to compute equilibria in a model in which all assets are several Lucas trees (i.e. Lucas (1978) model with heterogeneous agents). 5. AN EXAMPLE We compute equilibria for a stylized example that illustrates the impact of collateral requirements on equilibrium welfares. In the model setup, the asset structure and the collateral requirements are exogenously fixed. By maintaining the assumption of exogenously given asset payoffs, we show that it is very well possible that agents disagree on the optimal (exogenous) margin requirements. Model Parameterization There are two agents with identical constant relative risk aversion utility and a coefficient of risk aversion of 2. They have identical impatience parameters β 1 = β 2 = There are 4 exogenous shocks. Aggregate endowments are given by ē = ( ). We assume that the payoffs of the tree are independent of its owner and given by d(y) = 0 3 ē(y) for all y. Individual endowments are e 1 = ( ) e 2 = 0 7ē e 1 The transition probabilities are given by { π(y y ) = 0 4 fory y = 1 2ory y = 3 4, 0 1 otherwise.

20 1786 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS FIGURE 1. Agent 1. We first examine the welfare gains from introducing collateralized borrowing. We compare an economy where the only asset available is the tree to an economy, where this tree can be used as collateral for trading in a risk-free bond. We assume that the collateral requirement in the latter economy is fixed across states at k = 1 3 Figures 1 and 2 depict the welfare gains from the additional asset in the economy with collateral as a function of the wealth distribution for an economy with initial shock y 0 = 1 Welfare changes are in terms of percentage consumption equivalent variation. FIGURE 2. Agent 2.

21 ASSET-PRICING MODELS 1787 Agent 1, who starts off in his bad idiosyncratic shock, gains significantly. When he owns only 10 percent of the stock, his consumption in the one-asset economy would have to increase by 7.4% in each state in order to make him as well off as he is with collateralized borrowing. Agent 2 s welfare losses are generally much smaller, except in situations where agent 1 owns most of the tree. For a very extreme initial wealth distribution, where agent 2 owns the entire tree, he loses when a new asset is introduced because of the price effect on the tree. Margin Requirements We expect equilibrium welfares to depend on the margin requirement k since different values for k result in different probabilities of default and different consumption allocations. Quantitatively, these welfare effects turn out to be relatively small. Table I reports default percentages as a function of k In addition, it depicts welfare gains and losses (in %) from reducing the collateral requirement from 1.3 to a smaller value. In the computed equilibria, default never occurs if collateral requirements are larger than k = 1 2 Collateral requirements exceeding 1.2 are not optimal from a welfare point of view; higher requirements only decrease agents ability to borrow and therefore lead to welfare losses compared to an economy with k = 1 2 Remarkably, when agents initial wealth levels are unequal, the agents disagree on the optimal requirement. The rich agents tend to favor low collateral requirements that lead to high default rates, while poor agents tend to favor requirements that lead to low default rates. Although the above example is very stylized, it matches some key features of U.S. data. The variation in total endowments, as well as the capital share, seem reasonable. In order to examine the robustness of the qualitative result, we also computed equilibria for an eight-state model using the calibration of Heaton and Lucas (1996). In their calibration, idiosyncratic uncertainty is much smaller, but aggregate shocks are about the same. In this model, the resulting welfare gains from introducing an asset in addition to a single tree are generally very small. For k = 1 2 welfare gains lie between 0.1 and 0.6 percent of consumption equivalent variation. While different collateral requirements TABLE I MARGIN REQUIREMENTS, DEFAULT, AND WELFARE k Default rate Ω = ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Ω = ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Ω = ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

22 1788 F. KUBLER AND K. SCHMEDDERS do lead to slightly different equilibrium welfares that exhibit the same qualitative features as those in our stylized model, the differences always lie below 0.01 percent. (Since we compute ɛ-equilibria with ɛ lying around 10 5,itis unclear whether these welfare differences are meaningful.) 5.1. Some Remarks on the Computation We implemented the algorithm in Fortran 77 on a 500 MHz Pentium PC. In the examples in this section, maximal errors lie between and 10 5 (evaluated on a grid of points). In the case where there is only a tree and no financial security, this implies that the computed equilibrium is exact for economies where the β h vary stochastically between and For the example with 4 states, running times lie around 1 5 hours. For the example with 8 shocks and the calibration from Heaton and Lucas (1996), running times lie around 5 6 hours. As mentioned above, collateral constraints provide additional computational challenges because policy functions fail to be smooth when a constraint becomes binding. Figures 3 and 4 depict the portfolio policy functions for y = 1 and k = 1 2. It is apparent from the figures that cubic splines perform well, although the portfolio policy functions exhibit two nondifferentiabilities. In the example, we used 300 knots for the spline approximation. Although there are only two kinks in each policy function, we do not know where they occur and therefore use equi-spaced points. FIGURE 3. Stock-holding.

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Dynamic Competitive Economies with Complete Markets and Collateral Constraints

Dynamic Competitive Economies with Complete Markets and Collateral Constraints Dynamic Competitive Economies with Complete Markets and Collateral Constraints Piero Gottardi Department of Economics European University Institute Felix Kubler IBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance

More information

Negishi s method for stochastic OLG models

Negishi s method for stochastic OLG models Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Felix Kubler University of Zurich QSPS, May 2013 Motivation OLG models are important tools in macro and public finance Unfortunately, humans typically live for 80 years...

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics

Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Papers in Economics No. 10/11 A General Equilibrium Corporate Finance Theorem for Incomplete Markets: A Special Case By Pascal Stiefenhofer, University of York Department of Economics and Related

More information

Projection Methods. Felix Kubler 1. October 10, DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute

Projection Methods. Felix Kubler 1. October 10, DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute Projection Methods Felix Kubler 1 1 DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute October 10, 2017 Felix Kubler Comp.Econ. Gerzensee, Ch5 October 10, 2017 1 / 55 Motivation In many dynamic economic

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints Cuong Le Van IPAG Business School, CNRS, Paris School of Economics Ngoc-Sang Pham EPEE, University of Evry Yiannis

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) subject to for all t Jonathan Heathcote updated, March 2006 1. The household s problem max E β t u (c t ) t=0 c t + a t+1

More information

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION Jan Werner European University Institute May 2010 1 I. Price Bubbles: An Example Example I.1 Time is infinite; so dates are t = 0,1,2,...,.

More information

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics Thomas M. Mertens NYU Stern Risk Economics Lab April 17, 2012 1 / 78 Motivation Many problems in finance and economics are high dimensional. Dynamic Optimization:

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B Lecture 2 Giulio Fella c Giulio Fella, 2014 ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B - Lecture 2 40/197 Aim of consumption theory Consumption theory aims at explaining consumption/saving decisions

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Slides II - Dynamic Programming Slides II - Dynamic Programming Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides II - Dynamic Programming Spring 2017 1 / 32 Outline 1. Lagrangian

More information

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default, Econometrica 2000 Notes on Alvarez Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000 Jonathan Heathcote November 1st 2005 1 Model Consider a pure exchange economy with I agents one

More information

SDT 313 EQUILIBRIUM WITH LIMITED-RECOURSE COLLATERALIZED LOANS

SDT 313 EQUILIBRIUM WITH LIMITED-RECOURSE COLLATERALIZED LOANS SDT 313 EQUILIBRIUM WITH LIMITED-RECOURSE COLLATERALIZED LOANS Rubén Poblete-Cazenave Juan Pablo Torres-Martínez Santiago, julio 2010 EQUILIBRIUM WITH LIMITED-RECOURSE COLLATERALIZED LOANS Abstract. We

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies Takashi Kamihigashi September 28, 2015 Abstract We show a simple no-bubble theorem that applies to a wide range of deterministic sequential

More information

Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium

Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium Felix Kubler Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania fkubler@gmail.com Karl Schmedders Kellogg MEDS Northwestern University

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Kevin X.D. Huang and Jan Werner. Department of Economics, University of Minnesota

Kevin X.D. Huang and Jan Werner. Department of Economics, University of Minnesota Implementing Arrow-Debreu Equilibria by Trading Innitely-Lived Securities. Kevin.D. Huang and Jan Werner Department of Economics, University of Minnesota February 2, 2000 1 1. Introduction Equilibrium

More information

TWO-FUND SEPARATION IN DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

TWO-FUND SEPARATION IN DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM TWO-FUND SEPARATION IN DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM KARL SCHMEDDERS KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT NORTHWESTERN UNIVERSITY K-SCHMEDDERS@NORTHWESTERN.EDU JANUARY 18, 2005 Abstract. The purpose of this paper

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600. Alternative Methods of Discrete Time Intertemporal Optimization We will start by solving a discrete time intertemporal

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006)

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006) A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006) A Presentation for Corporate Finance 1 Graduate School of Economics December, 2009

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

Solving non-linear systems of equations

Solving non-linear systems of equations Solving non-linear systems of equations Felix Kubler 1 1 DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute October 7, 2017 Felix Kubler Comp.Econ. Gerzensee, Ch2 October 7, 2017 1 / 38 The problem

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time David Laibson 9/30/2014 Outline Lectures 9-10: 9.1 Continuous-time Bellman Equation 9.2 Application: Merton s Problem 9.3 Application:

More information

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Heterogeneous Agent Models: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown September, 2017 Introduction Early heterogeneous-agent models integrated the income-fluctuation problem into general equilibrium models. A key

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies Takashi Kamihigashi March 26, 2016 Abstract We show a simple no-bubble theorem that applies to a wide range of deterministic sequential

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium Tianxiao Zheng SAIF 1. Introduction We have studied single agent problems. However, macro-economy consists of a large number of agents including individuals/households,

More information

Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production

Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production Johannes Brumm DBF, University of Zurich johannes.brumm@googlemail.com Dominika Kryczka DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set 10. - Solutions Question 1 1. AUTARKY Autarky implies that the agents do not have access to credit or insurance markets. This implies that you cannot trade across

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession ONLINE APPENDIX INVESTMENT HANGOVER A1 Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession By MATTHEW ROGNLIE, ANDREI SHLEIFER, AND ALP SIMSEK APPENDIX A: CALIBRATION This appendix describes

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

Lecture XI. Approximating the Invariant Distribution

Lecture XI. Approximating the Invariant Distribution Lecture XI Approximating the Invariant Distribution Gianluca Violante New York University Quantitative Macroeconomics G. Violante, Invariant Distribution p. 1 /24 SS Equilibrium in the Aiyagari model G.

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

An approximate consumption function

An approximate consumption function An approximate consumption function Mario Padula Very Preliminary and Very Incomplete 8 December 2005 Abstract This notes proposes an approximation to the consumption function in the buffer-stock model.

More information

Essays in Financial Economics

Essays in Financial Economics Essays in Financial Economics Submitted by Giuseppe Bova to the University of Exeter as a thesis for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics In June 2013 This thesis is available for Library use

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

Housing with overlapping generations

Housing with overlapping generations Housing with overlapping generations Chiara Forlati, Michael Hatcher, Alessandro Mennuni University of Southampton Preliminary and Incomplete May 16, 2015 Abstract We study the distributional and efficiency

More information

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Gabriel Y. Weintraub, Lanier Benkard, and Benjamin Van Roy Stanford University {gweintra,lanierb,bvr}@stanford.edu Abstract

More information

In the benchmark economy, we restrict ourselves to stationary equilibria. The individual

In the benchmark economy, we restrict ourselves to stationary equilibria. The individual 1 1. Appendix A: Definition of Stationary Equilibrium In the benchmark economy, we restrict ourselves to stationary equilibria. The individual state variables are deposit holdings, d, mortgage balances,

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 1 [1] In this problem (see FT Ex. 1.1) you are asked to play with arbitrary 2 2 games just to get used to the idea of equilibrium computation. Specifically, consider the

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies

Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies Discrete State Space Methods for Dynamic Economies A Brief Introduction Craig Burnside Duke University September 2006 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Discrete State Space Methods September 2006 1 / 42

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 5, 2014 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 5, 2014 1 / 56 Growth

More information

SDT 314 LONG-LIVED COLLATERALIZED ASSETS AND BUBBLES

SDT 314 LONG-LIVED COLLATERALIZED ASSETS AND BUBBLES SDT 314 LONG-LIVED COLLATERALIZED ASSETS AND BUBBLES Aloisio Araujo Mário R. Páscoa Juan Pablo Torres-Martínez Santiago, julio 2010 LONG-LIVED COLLATERALIZED ASSETS AND BUBBLES ALOISIO ARAUJO, MÁRIO R.

More information

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006 Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Model June 20, 2006 The Representative Agent Hypothesis and its Notion of Equilibrium 9.2.1 An infinitely lived Representative Agent Avoid terminal period problem Equivalence

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II)

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II) ECO 503: Macroeconomic Theory I Benjamin Moll Princeton University Fall 204 /6 Plan of Lecture Sequence of markets CE 2 The growth model and

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Cosmin Ilut Duke & NBER Pavel Krivenko Stanford March 2016 Martin Schneider Stanford & NBER Abstract This paper proposes a simple perturbation

More information

The Non-Existence of Representative Agents

The Non-Existence of Representative Agents The Non-Existence of Representative Agents Matthew O. Jackson and Leeat Yariv November 2015 Abstract We characterize environments in which there exists a representative agent: an agent who inherits the

More information

Asset Pricing. Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. # X E β t U(c t ) t=0

Asset Pricing. Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. # X E β t U(c t ) t=0 Asset Pricing 1 Lucas (1978, Econometrica) Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. 1.1 Environment Tastes: " # X E β t U( ) t=0 Technology:

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1 Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm February 25, 2007 Problem : Pareto Optimality The planner solves the following problem: u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + v(l ) + v(l 2 ) () {c,c 2,l,l

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

1 General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium 1 General Equilibrium 1.1 Pure Exchange Economy goods, consumers agent : preferences < or utility : R + R initial endowments, R + consumption bundle, =( 1 ) R + Definition 1 An allocation, =( 1 ) is feasible

More information

Lecture 3: Huggett s 1993 model. 1 Solving the savings problem for an individual consumer

Lecture 3: Huggett s 1993 model. 1 Solving the savings problem for an individual consumer UNIVERSITY OF WESTERN ONTARIO LONDON ONTARIO Paul Klein Office: SSC 4044 Extension: 85484 Email: pklein2@uwo.ca URL: http://paulklein.ca/newsite/teaching/619.php Economics 9619 Computational methods in

More information

Taxing capital along the transition - Not a bad idea after all?

Taxing capital along the transition - Not a bad idea after all? Taxing capital along the transition - Not a bad idea after all? Online appendix Hans Fehr University of Würzburg CESifo and Netspar Fabian Kindermann University of Bonn and Netspar September 2014 In Appendix

More information

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Intertemporal equilibrium with production: bubbles and efficiency Stefano BOSI, Cuong LE VAN, Ngoc-Sang PHAM 2014.43 Maison des Sciences Économiques,

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Prices and Investment. with. Collateral and Default

Prices and Investment. with. Collateral and Default Prices and Investment with Collateral and Default Michael MAGILL University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA 90089-0253, USA magill@usc.edu Martine QUINZII (corresponding author) Department of Economics

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

1 Basic Analysis of Forward-Looking Decision Making

1 Basic Analysis of Forward-Looking Decision Making 1 Basic Analysis of Forward-Looking Decision Making Individuals and families make the key decisions that determine the future of the economy. The decisions involve balancing current sacrifice against future

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

Supplement to The cyclical dynamics of illiquid housing, debt, and foreclosures (Quantitative Economics, Vol. 7, No. 1, March 2016, )

Supplement to The cyclical dynamics of illiquid housing, debt, and foreclosures (Quantitative Economics, Vol. 7, No. 1, March 2016, ) Supplementary Material Supplement to The cyclical dynamics of illiquid housing, debt, and foreclosures Quantitative Economics, Vol. 7, No. 1, March 2016, 289 328) Aaron Hedlund Department of Economics,

More information

Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market. Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère

Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market. Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère YEQT XI: Winterschool on Energy Systems Netherlands, December, 2017 CERMICS - EPOC 1/43 Uncertainty on

More information

On the existence, efficiency and bubbles of a Ramsey equilibrium with endogenous labor supply and borrowing constraints

On the existence, efficiency and bubbles of a Ramsey equilibrium with endogenous labor supply and borrowing constraints On the existence, efficiency and bubbles of a Ramsey equilibrium with endogenous labor supply and borrowing constraints Robert Becker, Stefano Bosi, Cuong Le Van and Thomas Seegmuller September 22, 2011

More information

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, 2017 9:00 am - 2:00 pm INSTRUCTIONS Please place a completed label (from the label sheet provided) on the

More information

Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles

Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles Marcelo Veracierto Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago February 2016 Abstract: I consider a real business cycle model in which agents have private information

More information

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions 1. For each of the following propositions, state whether the proposition is true or false. If true, provide a proof (or at least indicate how a proof could

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework Online Appendix to the paper Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework October 5, 2015 Part I: Maturity specific shocks in affine and equilibrium models This Appendix present

More information

The Hansen Singleton analysis

The Hansen Singleton analysis The Hansen Singleton analysis November 15, 2018 1 Estimation of macroeconomic rational expectations model. The Hansen Singleton (1982) paper. We start by looking at the application of GMM that first showed

More information

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley July 2013 1 1. MOTIVATION Controversy about proper level of inheritance taxation 1) Public

More information

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Kjetil Storesletten Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Gianluca Violante

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Notes on Recursive Utility Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Section 1 (or Chapter 29, LeRoy & Werner, 2nd Ed.) Let u st be the continuation utility at s t. That

More information

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications George W. Evans University of Oregon and University of St Andrews Bruce McGough University of Oregon WAMS, December 12, 2015 Outline Introduction Shadow-price

More information

Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix)

Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix) Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix Flavio Cunha The University of Pennsylvania James Heckman The University

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS DECISIONS WITH QUASI-GEOMETRIC DISCOUNTING. By Per Krusell and Anthony A. Smith, Jr introduction

CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS DECISIONS WITH QUASI-GEOMETRIC DISCOUNTING. By Per Krusell and Anthony A. Smith, Jr introduction Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 1 (January, 2003), 365 375 CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS DECISIONS WITH QUASI-GEOMETRIC DISCOUNTING By Per Krusell and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 1 1 introduction The purpose of this paper

More information