Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale"

Transcription

1 Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale Xiaoshu Xu y Octorber, 2017 Abstract In practice, when bidders arrive sequentially and resale cannot be banned, the auctioneer s reauction incentive naturally extends a standard one-shot auction to a dynamic game. If the initial auction is not successful, the auctioneer can re-auction the item to current and future bidders at a later date; otherwise, the winner can opt to resell it to future bidders. To study intricacies in the auctioneer s revenue maximization problem, we develop a two-stage private-value model in which patient bidders arrive in two di erent batches and characterize the optimal sequential ascending English auctions when bidders use a symmetric increasing bidding strategy. We have three interesting ndings in the auctioneer s optimal design. First, the auctioneer always includes the rst batch of bidders as potential buyers in the re-auction, although her updated belief makes their value distribution weaker than that of the second batch of bidders ex post. Second, there is a problem of multiple equilibria, suggesting that the auctioneer would encounter the implementation issue. We invent a novel selection rule to restore equilibrium uniqueness. Third, the auctioneer and the rst batch of bidders are competitors in extracting surplus from the second batch of bidders; thus, the auctioneer has an incentive to control the winner s possible gain from resale. We identify several su cient conditions under which resale never occurs in the optimal design, implying that the second-best allocation e ciency is achieved. I thank Dan Levin, Lixin Ye, James Peck, Yaron Azrieli, Marco Ottaviani, Alessandro Pavan, Rakesh Vohra and Andy Skrzypacz for very helpful comments and suggestions. I also thank the support from National Natural Science Foundation of China (grant code: ). y College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, No Hua Shan Road, Shanghai , China. xuxiaoshu@sjtu.edu.cn 1

2 Keywords: Optimal sequential auctions, Noncommitment, Sequential arrival, Patient bidders, Resale JEL Classi cations: D44, C7, D82 1 Introduction Extremely popular online auction platforms such as Ebay act as a focal point of demand where potential buyers can constantly search to determine whether the items in which they are interested are being auctioned. In such auctions, buyers thus arrive sequentially (or in di erent batches) 1, which could fundamentally change the incentives of the auctioneer and bidders. The auctioneer realizes that if there is no winner, a subsequent auction can be conducted at some future date when a new batch of potential bidders arrive. 2 Similarly, experienced current bidders also see future bidders as an opportunity: when the current auction admits a winner, the winner has the option of holding a resale. The re-auction incentive 3 and resale incentive are also pervasive in other auctions in the private sector, such as art pieces, precious wine, and antiques. The story is largely similar for auctions in the public sector: re-auction is not rare 4 and resale or resale-like actions (e.g., mergers) cannot be completely prohibited even with rm regulatory policies. Therefore, in real auctions, sequential arrival, re-auction and resale are non-separable. Re-auction not only gives the auctioneer an opportunity to sell to new bidders, but it also serves as a second chance for the original bidders: when they anticipate that an unsuccessful initial auction will lead to a re-auction, they rationally wait if they are not forced to leave. Moreover, there is no obvious reason for the auctioneer to exclude the original bidders or new bidders from the re-auction. 5 Our aim is to characterize the auctioneer s revenue maximization problem and its implications in this environment, which has not been studied 1 We focus on the non-strategic arrival of bidders, meaning that they arrive for exogenous reasons (e.g., a new need for the item, being nancially incapable at the time of the previous auction). 2 Ebay even provides special guidance including tips to relist items, the fees charged, and how to make the auction more attractive. See for details. 3 McAfee and Vincent (1997) o er several good examples of re-auctions regularly being observed in auction houses. 4 For example, in timber auctions, there is a policy that unsold quantities need to be re-auctioned at later auctions after approximately six months. During the time elapsed, additional interested bidders could arrive. 5 In practice, there have been examples where re-auction is not open to new bidders because the winner of the initial auction failed to make the payment; however, this type of event is not the focus of this paper. 2

3 in the previous literature. We propose an illustrative two-stage model with discounting: two batches of patient bidders (male, de ned as B1 bidders and B2 bidders) arrive sequentially, where the term patient refers to the assumption that B1 bidders can wait until the second stage without explicit costs. We focus on an ascending English auction (strategically equivalent to a second-price sealed-bid auction in this context) and assume that the auctioneer can only control reserve prices. 6 The second-stage game depends on the rst-stage outcome: when no B1 bidder drops out at or above the rst reserve price, the auctioneer (female) updates her belief about their values and posts a second reserve price in the re-auction to both batches of bidders; otherwise, the winner of the initial auction decides whether to consume the item 7 or attempt to resell it in the second stage. A key point of the model is that the reserve price in the re-auction is sequentially optimal. This is also the assumption of McAfee and Vincent (1997), although they restrict attention to a xed set of bidders. We consider perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which B1 bidders use symmetric and monotonic bidding strategies with a cuto in the initial auction: a B1 bidder remains active past the reserve price only when his value is higher than or equal to some cuto. On the equilibrium path, when the initial auction fails, the auctioneer consistently believes that all B1 bidders have values below that cuto. We explicitly address two challenges intrinsic to this speci c dynamic game. The rst challenge comes from what we label endogenous asymmetry: even if two batches of bidders are symmetric in values ex ante, asymmetry is inevitably created ex post in the re-auction; thus, the auctioneer must decide whether to include B1 bidders as potential buyers when selecting the contingently optimal reserve price. Our analysis also reveals that this phenomenon causes a critical issue of equilibrium selection because some reserve prices in the initial auction can induce two equilibrium cuto s. The second challenge concerns resale: since the auctioneer and B1 bidders are competitors in extracting B2 bidders surplus, to what extent can the auctioneer control B1 bidders possible gains from resale? Although resale increases their bids in the initial auction, the auctioneer would prefer to directly serve B2 bidders if the winner manages to bene t from resale ex post. Determining how this incentive is governed by the revenue maximization incentive is di cult. 6 This assumption might seem restrictive, but it holds in many auctions in the private sector. 7 One implicit assumption regarding the item is that once it is "opened" (or consumed), its resale value drops to zero. Items such as wine, collectible toys and initial releases of certain books or DVDs have this property. 3

4 We have several interesting ndings. First, although the traditional one-to-one correspondence between the reserve price (in the initial auction) and the equilibrium cuto breaks down, we create a novel selection rule that focuses on the incentives of pivotal (de ned below) B1 bidders to restore uniqueness. Second, on the optimal reserve price path, B1 bidders are never excluded as potential buyers in the re-auction after they fail the initial auction. Third, under some su cient conditions, the auctioneer s revenue-maximizing incentive would induce an equilibrium cuto high enough that no B1 bidder resells conditional on winning. Finally, even if resale is removed from this model, all analytical results continue to hold. This paper is closely related to the literature on optimal auctions with resale and revenue management with little (or no) commitment. Although resale has always been a widely discussed issue in the auction literature, most papers focus on bidders post-auction interactions and how they can in uence the equilibrium properties in the initial auction 8. There are only a few studies that address the issue of revenue maximization. Ausubel and Cramton (1999) prove that when inter-bidder resale of complete information cannot be banned, resale does not occur under the auctioneer s revenuemaximizing incentive. Zheng (2002) considers how the Myerson revenue can be achieved with interbidder resale. 9 Calzolari and Pavan (2006) study both the cases of inter-bidder resale and resale to a third party, but they focus on what disclosure rule the auctioneer should use to maximize revenue. Zhang and Wang (2013) consider which bidder the item should be assigned to in auctions with a regular bidder and a bidder whose value is publicly known. Our paper contributes to this literature in two respects. Theoretically, the new batch of bidders are recognized as "outsiders" in previous studies; by integrating them into the overall picture, we are able to examine in detail the auctioneer s competition incentive against B1 bidders and further reveal situations in which resale does not occur. Empirically, our results regarding resale question the necessity of banning resale. There have always been debates over regulatory policies concerning resale, mainly because of two concerns: the high cost of law enforcement and supervision despite the poor performance achieved, and the argument that forbidding resale may impede market e ciency. We show that under the auctioneer s revenuemaximizing incentive, resale does not occur in several circumstances. Therefore, although there may 8 Recent studies in this direction include Garratt et al. (2009), Hafalir and Krishna (2008), Haile (2000, 2003), Lebrun (1999), Pagnozzi (2007), and Xu et al. (2013). 9 Lebrun (2012) generalizes Zheng s result. 4

5 still be unrealized surplus, e ciency cannot be further improved with incomplete information. In this sense, rm regulations on secondary markets may not be necessary. The literature on revenue management with limited (or no) commitment and (a xed set of) strategic buyers includes Hörner and Samuelson (2011), Liu et al. (2013), McAfee and Vincent (1997) and Skreta (2006, 2015). Among these studies, McAfee and Vincent (1997) is the most related to ours. They consider an auction setting with nitely many periods during which the auctioneer cannot commit to future reserve prices. When sequential arrival and resale is removed, our model is their two-period case. Skreta s seminal work extends McAfee and Vincent (1997) to allow for general mechanisms, while Liu et al. (2013) extend McAfee and Vincent (1997) to an in nite-horizon auction model. Hörner and Samuelson (2011) consider a monopolist that has multiple objects to sell before a deadline, using posted prices. Our major contribution to this literature comes from the modeling of sequential arrival and the new ndings associated with it. Sequential arrival is a usual assumption in mechanism design with full commitment, but it has been ignored by the non-commitment literature, mainly for reasons of tractability. We show that endogenous asymmetry generates two critical new features. First, the earlier batch of bidders will always be included in later rounds of the auction. This result can be generalized since the intuition is not restricted to this model. Second, equilibrium selection is inevitable. We invent a novel rule and believe that its idea can be borrowed in other similar models. Finally, this paper is also related to the large and growing literature on mechanism design with a dynamic (but not necessarily patient) buyer population. Bergemann and Said (2011) summarize representative work in this eld. Board and Skrzypacz (2016) consider a monopolist s revenue maximization problem when selling a xed quantity of products to a dynamic and patient buyer population. The monopoly has full commitment power, and unsold quantities in any given period would be destroyed. They also prove that the optimal mechanism can be implemented by ascending English auctions and second-price sealed-bid auctions. 10 Without resale, our model is the two-period case of Board and Skrzypacz (2016) with a single item and limited commitment. Our research highlights 10 Dilme and Li (2014) attempt to add noncommitment to a setting similar to that of Board and Skrzypacz (2016), but to maintain tractability, they restrict their attention to the posted price mechanism and further assume that buyers only have two possible types. Thus all high-valued buyers are served immediately upon arrival. The dual-type assumption subtly avoids endogenous asymmetry. 5

6 that when limited (or no) commitment is combined with a dynamic and patient bidder population, the multi-equilibria phenomenon is inevitable, which instantly creates an obstacle to direct mechanism design: the existence of a maximum is not su cient since the maximum revenue in theory may not be achieved by an indirect mechanism when the designer and buyers have di erent preferences over the equilibria. Despite this concern, we believe that the results in this paper still serve as an important step toward further research on dynamic mechanism design without commitment. We proceed as follows: Section 2 presents a simple example under the uniform distribution but without resale; Section 3 proposes a general model; Section 4 o ers a brief discussion on possible extensions and concludes. 2 A Uniform Distribution Example without Resale We begin with possibly the simplest example and delay all proofs until Section 3. To highlight the challenges created by endogenous asymmetry, we assume for the present that the auctioneer can explicitly ban resale. Notations in this section are consistent with their counterparts in Section 3. Consider a private-value model with two stages: an auctioneer (female) has an indivisible item, which she values at 0, to be sold to two potential buyers (male), denoted bidder 1 and bidder 2. Bidder i arrives at the beginning of the i th stage, with the valuation v i that is independently drawn from the uniform distribution on [0; 1]. The auctioneer holds at most two successive English (or sealed-bid second-price) auctions. She rst announces a reserve price r 1 to bidder 1: if bidder 1 does not drop out at 0, he wins at the price r 1, and the game ends; otherwise, the game proceeds to the second stage. The auctioneer then announces a reserve price r 2 to bidder 1 and the newly arrived bidder 2, where r 2 is sequentially optimal. Two bidders thus compete as in a normal English auction. We assume that all players are risk neutral with the common discount factor 2 (0; 1). In this indirect mechanism, the auctioneer s revenue crucially depends on bidders strategies and the reserve price path. In the second stage, we assume that each bidder adopts the weakly dominant strategy of dropping out at his value if it is higher than r 2. In the rst stage, we focus on a cuto strategy for bidder 1: he drops out at 0 when v 1 is smaller than some cuto v; otherwise, he immediately wins the item. Beliefs are constructed accordingly. Using backward induction, the auctioneer s task in the second stage is to determine the optimal 6

7 r 2, with the belief that v 1 ~U[0; v] and v 2 ~U[0; 1]. Because of endogenous asymmetry, she has to consider whether to announce an r 2 that is higher than v. Such an r 2 can exclude bidder 1 from the competition: the bene t is that if bidder 2 wins, the payment would increase; however, losing bidder 1 as a potential buyer is not wise if he is competitive. The measure of bidder 1 s attractiveness clearly depends on v. According to our calculation, there exists a threshold T H such that the auctioneer excludes bidder 1 only when v T H, with the following structure: 8 < the sequentially optimal r 2 = : T H is approximately 0:415 in this example. 1 2, when v 2 [0; T H] v+1 4, when v 2 (T H; 1] (1) In the rst stage, bidder 1 is the last mover and decides whether to drop out at 0. Looking ahead, he knows that r 2 is determined by v through equation (1). Denote his continuation payo from dropping out at 0 as l(v 1 ; v): l(v 1 ; v) is 0 when v 1 r 2 ; otherwise, it is equal to R v 1 0 (v 1 maxfv 2 ; r 2 g)dv 2. Clearly, bidder 1 compares l(v 1 ; v) to v 1 in making his decision. The construction of the equilibrium strategy requires that in equilibrium, v 1 r 1 (his payo from winning immediately) r 1 > l(v 1 ; v) when v 1 > v; v 1 r 1 = l(v 1 ; v) when v 1 = v; and v 1 r 1 < l(v 1 ; v) otherwise. From the indi erence condition at v 1 = v, the correspondence between r 1 and v can be derived. We postpone the formal proof of equilibrium existence until Section 3 and focus on the properties of this correspondence for the present. Pic_1 depicts equilibrium pairs of r 1 (X-axis) and v (Y-axis) when = 0:9. 7

8 Pic_1 The rst observation is not surprising: this correspondence is broken into two parts as a direct result of the piecewise structure of r 2 in equation (1). However, the second observation is new: some values of r 1 (approximately (0:43; 0:45)) can induce two equilibrium cuto s. This fact immediately raises the equilibrium selection issue, which may bother the auctioneer. To see this point, denote by r 1 (v) the corresponding r 1 given v and by rev(r 1 (v); v) the auctioneer s expected revenue. Suppose that v maximizes rev(r 1 (v); v). If r 1 (v ) happens to fall into (0:43; 0:45), there exists some v 0 6= v such that r 1 (v 0 ) = r 1 (v ). In this case, the auctioneer cannot implement r 1 (v ) if bidder 1 prefers v 0 instead; thus, the theoretically maximum revenue cannot be achieved. Fortunately, in this example, r 1 (v ) lies outside the multi-cuto region, as depicted by Pic_2: 8

9 Pic_2 Pic_2 illustrates how rev(r 1 (v); v) (Y-axis) changes with v (X-axis) when = 0:9. Because of endogenous asymmetry, the graph has two parts. The rst part increases in v, and the second part is strictly concave with an interior maximizer that is also the global maximizer v. v is approximately 0:8. According to Pic_1, r 1 (v ) is higher than 0:6. Therefore, the optimal r 1 lies outside the multicuto region of (0:43; 0:45). Although Pic_2 only illustrates the = 0:9 case, this pattern can be proven for any in this uniform example. Moreover, v is clearly larger than T H 0:415, suggesting that on the optimal reserve price path, bidder 1 is not excluded from the re-auction. This pattern can also be proven analytically for any value of in this example. To conclude this section, we brie y discuss the challenges that endogenous asymmetry raises for revenue maximization. The rst challenge is whether it is optimal to include bidder 1 in the re-auction after the initial auction fails. This concern is inevitable with limited commitment and a dynamic and patient bidder population, and it would become more severe when the game has more than two stages. Board and Skrzypacz (2016) study this setting under full commitment and characterize 9

10 a stable condition across periods. With limited commitment, stableness would be impossible to achieve since backward induction keeps adding more batches of earlier bidders into consideration. Another related study is Liu et al. (2013), who use the traditional approach with a constraint representing sequential rationality to characterize the optimal auction with non-commitment and an in nite horizon. However, to keep the analysis tractable, they do not consider sequential arrival. The second challenge arises from the equilibrium selection issue. Consider a case in which the auctioneer selects some r 1 with two equilibrium cuto s. If the auctioneer and bidder 1 s interests diverge, she can implement the cuto that she prefers in a direct mechanism but not in the indirect mechanism because bidder 1 moves after her. This concern implies that the traditional mechanism design approach cannot be applied in this setting. In Section 3, the generalization of the number of bidders and allowing for resale make the analysis less tractable. We are nevertheless able to prove that the auctioneer would always include B1 bidders as potential buyers in the re-auction. However, the equilibrium selection issue cannot be avoided. Instead, we invent a selection rule that focuses on pivotal bidders from the rst batch and prove that their interests coincide. 3 The General Model Based on the model in Section 2, we make the following generalizations. First, the number of B1 bidders is n, and the number of B2 bidders is m. Second, bidders values independently and identically follow some arbitrary F () on [0; 1], where the conditional distribution F (xjx a) satis es the monotonic likelihood ratio property for any a Third, at the end of the rst stage, the winner (if any) can choose to consume the item (in which case his gross payo is his value) or to resell it in the second stage (in which case his gross payo is the discounted expected resale payo ) to B2 bidders and B1 losers. Resale takes the form of an optimal ascending English auction. For notational convenience, in the following analysis, we do not include the parameters n; m; in mathematical terms unless speci ed. subsection for quick reference. We also list major de nitions at the beginning of each 11 This implies that x F (a) F (x) f(x) price in resale. Hafalir and Krishna (2008) also impose this assumption. is a strictly increasing function. It ensures that there is a unique optimal reserve 10

11 The solution concept we adopt is perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE). In the rst stage, we still focus on a symmetric and monotonic bidding strategy with a cuto : given r 1, there exists a cuto v such that a B1 bidder with value v drops out at 0 when v < v and drops out at some (v) otherwise, where (v) strictly increases with v and (v) r In the second stage, regardless of the auctionholder s identity, we assume that all bidders follow the weakly dominant strategy of sincere bidding. All beliefs are consistent. Therefore, on the equilibrium path, when n > 1, the winner of the initial auction believes that all losers values are below his; thus, in resale, he only takes B2 bidders into account. We discuss the possibility of tacit collusion among B1 bidders in Section Equilibrium Analysis: Second Period We make the following de nitions for the present. Definition 1 F (j) k (j) and f k : the distribution and density function of the j th order statistic out of k bidders with the value distribution F () r 2 (v) : the sequentially optimal reserve price in the re-auction r : the optimal reserve price in a standard auction with bidders values independently and identically drawn from F () 13 T H : the value of v at which the auctioneer is indi erent between excluding and including B1 bidders as potential buyers in the re-auction r(v) : the optimal reserve price in the resale when the winner s value is v w(v) : the expected payo from resale when the winner s value is v The seller s identity in the second auction depends on the outcome of the initial auction. We rst consider the case of re-auction. The following proposition characterizes r 2 (v): Proposition 1 (The Contingently Optimal Re-auction) 12 Note that although (v) can be strictly higher than r 1, dropping out at (v) or r 1 does not change the contingent payo. We assume that these bidders drop out at (v) (if not at zero) for continuity. 11

12 m[1 F (x)]+n[f (v) F (x)] De ne (v) as the unique solution to x = (m+n)f(x). r 2 (v) is piece-wise: 8 < r, when v 2 [0; T H] r 2 (v) = : (v), when v 2 (T H; 1] 14 Proof. The sketch of the proof is as follows: When the auctioneer is forced to include B1 bidders (namely, r 2 < v), (v) is optimal; when she is forced to exclude them, r is optimal. As v increases, the expected revenue from including them increases, and it equals the expected revenue from excluding them when v hits T H. (v) strictly increases in v with (1) = r. Details are relegated to the Appendix. From the analysis in Section 2, Proposition 1 is the starting point at which our results depart from previous related studies. Inevitably, the piece-wise structure projects back to the auctioneer s optimization problem in the initial auction and creates the multiple equilibria phenomenon through backward induction. Note that according to Myerson (1981), the optimal direct mechanism would assign the item to a bidder with the highest positive virtual value, which may not be ex post e cient. Even if we allow for more stages for possible resale among the mixed bidder population (and exclude more batches of bidders), Zheng (2002) shows that the Myerson revenue can typically only be achieved with two bidders. We next consider the case when the initial auction admits a winner. If he opts to hold a resale, on the equilibrium path, he consistently believes that only B2 bidders are potential buyers; thus, when his own value is v, his expected payo from resale can be derived as 3.2 First Period w(v) = max r2[v;1] F m (r)v + mf m 1 (r)[1 F (r)]r + Z 1 r xf (2) m (x)dx (2) The analysis proceeds as follows: using backward induction, B1 bidders contingent payo s in the second stage can be derived, which can be used to construct the indi erence condition for a marginal 14 Although r 2(v) is expressed as a function, r, and (v) generates the same second-stage revenue when v = T H: 12

13 B1 bidder (whose value equals the cuto v); thus, the correspondence between r 1 and v can be derived. We then prove that any pair of r 1 and v linked through the indi erence condition can be supported on the equilibrium path. As illustrated in Section 2, the traditional one-to-one correspondence breaks down because of endogenous asymmetry. We will impose an intuitive equilibrium selection rule. In short, this rule assumes that all pivotal (de ned below) B1 bidders are the key players in selecting the cuto when there are multiple cuto s. We further prove that they prefer the same cuto Equilibrium Existence We track a B1 bidder with value v. The following de nitions are made: Definition 2 H(v) : H(v) = maxfv; w(v)g; which can be interpreted as the actual worth of the item v() : the unique solution to x = w(x) 15 ;or the point at which a winner is indi erent between holding a resale and consuming the item w (v; v) : the expected payo from dropping out at maxfh(v); H(v)g l (v; v) : the expected payo from dropping out at 0 v H and v L : the larger(smaller) cuto when a single r 1 induces two The next proposition addresses what his bid should be when he does not drop out at 0. We postpone the discussion of whether he is better o by dropping out at 0 to the proof of Proposition 3. Proposition 2 implies that in equilibrium, the symmetric bidding function () should be H(). Proposition 2 When other bidders drop out at H() if their values are no less than v, a B1 bidder should drop out at maxfh(v); H(v)g if not at 0. Proof. In the proof, we assume that this bidder mimics type ~v. Clearly, if he does not drop at 0, ~v has to be no less than v. We then prove that if v v, the best ~v is v, and thus, this bidder should drop out at H(v). For v > v, we prove that the best ~v is v by ruling out the overbidding and underbidding case, and thus, this bidder should drop out at H(v). The underbidding case is more di cult because even if he loses, he still has a chance of buying back the item through a resale if the winner holds one. 13

14 Details are relegated to the Appendix. Note that when v > v, in equilibrium, H(v) is the gross payo conditional on winning. However, if such a bidder loses in equilibrium, he has no hope of winning the resale, and thus, his payo conditional on losing is 0. Therefore, the intuition of Proposition 2 is straightforward: a B1 bidder with v > v bids the actual worth of the item in equilibrium. Clearly, this bidding strategy has the same avor as "sincere bidding" in a regular English auction, although it is not a weakly dominant strategy, and the proof is much more di cult. We next derive the indi erence condition for a marginal B1 bidder. The calculation of w (v; v) is simple, while the calculation of l (v; v) is very tedious: when this bidder loses, the contingent game could be a re-auction, a resale, or no resale. The detailed derivations of w (v; v) and l (v; v) are presented in the proof of Lemma 1. In equilibrium, the indi erence condition is w (v; v) = l (v; v) (3) The correspondence between v and r 1 can thus be derived, as characterized by Lemma 1. Lemma 1 De ne l(v; v) as this bidder s expected payo (undiscounted) from the re-auction when the initial auction fails. De ne l(v; v) + as the strictly positive part of l(v; v). As r 1 increases, it rst induces a single cuto, then two cuto s, and nally, a single cuto again, as described by the following system: 8 >< >: H(v) = r 1, when r 1 2 [w(0); H(T H) l(t H; T H) + ) H(v L ) = r 1, w(v H ) l(v H ; v H ) = r 1, when r 1 2 [H(T H) l(t H; T H) + ; H(T H)] Proof. See Appendix. w(v) l(v; v) = r 1, when r 1 2 (H(T H); 1 l(1; 1) + ] We call [H(T H) l(t H; T H) + ; H(T H)] the multi-cuto region. Before resolving the equilibrium selection issue, it is necessary to prove that any pair of (r 1 ; v) satisfying Lemma 1 can be supported on the equilibrium path. Proposition 3 formally presents the PBE. Proposition 3 Given r 1, the following strategies and beliefs constitute a PBE: all B1 bidders follow the proposed cuto strategy, where (v) = H(v) and the cuto v satis es Lemma 1. When there is 14

15 no winner, the auctioneer believes that all B1 bidders have values following the truncated distribution of F () over [0; v] and selects r 2 (v) as the reserve price; otherwise, the winner decides whether to hold a resale with the reserve price r(v). All losers in the initial auction do not proceed to resale. In the second-stage game, all bidders apply the sincere bidding strategy. All beliefs are consistently constructed. Proof. The proof is divided into two cases: v T H and v > T H. For v T H, the di cult part is to prove that a B1 bidder with v > v has no incentive to drop out at 0: even with this deviation, he may still have a chance in the re-auction or in the resale (if there is one). For v > T H, the di cult part is to prove that a B1 bidder with v v has no incentive to drop out at H(v): with this deviation, he may be able to become the winner in the initial auction and manages to earn a positive pro t from resale. Details are relegated to the Appendix Equilibrium Selection It is clear that the multi-equilibria phenomenon is irrelevant to the auctioneer s revenue concerns only when the optimal r 1 never falls in the multi-cuto region: namely, regardless of whether v L or v H is coordinated on, the optimal v corresponds to some r 1 outside that region. However, as illustrated in Picture 2 of Section 2, con rmation of the above pattern requires a full characterization of the expected revenue as a function of v. To avoid this generally complicated issue, we impose an equilibrium selection rule. The usual Pareto ranking rule cannot be easily applied because it still requires detailed examination of the payo functions of the auctioneer and B1 bidders. Nonetheless, the spirit of the Pareto rule can be borrowed to invent a novel rule. In our context of two equilibria, Pareto ranking requires the auctioneer and all B1 bidders to have the same top-rated equilibrium. However, since B1 bidders move after the auctioneer announces r 1, she cannot control which cuto they follow. Moreover, B1 bidders with v 2 [0; v L ) [ (v H ; 1] do not actually have the freedom to select the cuto : their strategies in the initial auction do not vary with the choice of v L or v H. Therefore, only B1 bidders with v 2 [v L ; v H ] are key players in determining the cuto. In the following, we call them pivotal to highlight their importance. We assume that all players follow the cuto that pivotal bidders prefer. The next concern is 15

16 whether all pivotal bidders interests coincide for any r 1 in the multi-cuto region. Proposition 4 shows that they do share the same interest. Fortunately, Proposition 4 Given r 1 2 [H(T H) pivotal bidder. l(t H; T H) + ; H(T H)], v H is always preferred to v L by any Proof. We track a bidder with value v 2 [v L ; v H ]. When the other n 1 bidders and the auctioneer follow v H but he deviates from dropping out at zero in the initial auction, according to Proposition 2, his best deviation is to drop out at H(v) and obtain a deviation payo of w (v; v H ). Clearly, this deviation payo should be less than his equilibrium payo l (v; v H ). Next, consider the case in which the other n 1 B1 bidders and the auctioneer follow v L. If this bidder also follows v L, in all of his winning events, he also wins when the other B1 bidders and the auctioneer follow v H but he deviates to v L. In fact, he has more winning events with this deviation because B1 bidders with values in between v and v H previously dropped out at zero but do not now. Moreover, in every winning event, his expected payment in the deviation case is weakly lower while the expected gross payo remains the same. The reason is that, with the deviation, his expected payment conditional on winning is always r 1. However, when v L is believed to be the cuto, there is a positive probability that there exists at least one B1 bidder with a value in between v L and v, resulting in a higher payment. Therefore, w (v; v H ) > w (v; v L ), where w (v; v L ) is the equilibrium payo when the other B1 bidders and the auctioneer follow v L. However, because l (v; v H ) is this bidder s equilibrium payo when the cuto is v H, l (v; v H ) w (v; v H ). By transitivity, l (v; v H ) > w (v; v L ). Therefore, any pivotal bidder prefers v H to be the equilibrium cuto. This completes the proof. We provide a rough intuition for Proposition 4 while xing non-pivotal B1 bidders values. For pivotal bidders, the choice of v H and v L leads to di erent layouts of the game. If v H is selected, a pivotal bidder cannot win in the initial auction. However, he still has a chance of winning in the re-auction, with a lower reserve price 16 but extra competition from B2 bidders. By contrast, if v L is selected, a pivotal bidder could win immediately with a payment of no less than r 1 and the resale 16 It is obvious that when v H is selected as the equilibrium cuto, r 2 is strictly smaller than r 1; otherwise, a marginal bidder faces a larger reserve price, competition from B2 bidders and the discount in the re-auction, in which case he cannot be indi erent. 16

17 option. Therefore, v H 0 s advantage is the lower reserve price, while v0 Ls advantage is that B2 bidders serve as a source for extracting surplus instead of rivals in competing for the item. However, the contingently optimal r 2 can be accurately predicted while B2 bidders exact values are not. certainty serves as the primary factor in determing the relative advantage of v H. As a result of Proposition 4, we impose the following selection rule to restore equilibrium uniqueness: Assumption 1 (Equilibrium Selection) When r 1 induces two equilibrium cuto s, we assume that the auctioneer and B1 bidders adopt v H, which generates a higher continuation payo for the 8rest of the game for pivotal bidders. This restriction implies that v is determined by r 1 according to < H(v) = r 1, when r 1 2 [w(0); H(T H) l(t H; T H) + ) : H(v) l(v; v) + = r 1, when r 1 2 [H(T H) l(t H; T H) + ; 1 l(1; 1) + ] According to this rule, some values of v can never be implemented. E ective cuto values lie in disjoint intervals: v 2 [0; H 1 (H(T H) l(t H; T H) + )] [ [T H; 1]. Thus, any r 1 generates a unique equilibrium cuto, which further induces a unique contingently optimal r 2. Therefore, the auctioneer s maximum revenue is determined by r 1. Although we establish this intuitive rule to avoid complications involved in a detailed characterization of the revenue function, it is possible that the rule has no e ect on the maximum revenue: rst, any r 1 such that the auctioneer s and B1 bidders interests diverge will never be chosen because the auctioneer can anticipate that B1 bidders will follow their preferred cuto ; second, v H may also be preferred by the auctioneer; and third, it is possible that the optimal r 1 always lies outside the multi-cuto region, regardless of which cuto we select over that interval, as in Section 2. This 3.3 Optimal Sequential Auction Because of equilibrium selection, nding the optimal r 1 is equivalent to nding the optimal v. Since values of v lie in two disconnected intervals after the selection, it su ces to nd the optimal cuto in each interval and compare the revenues that they generate. We seek to answer two questions by characterizing the optimal reserve price path. The rst question was already presented in Section 2: should the auctioneer include B1 bidders as potential buyers in the re-auction? The second question focuses on how the auctioneer should control a winner s possible gain from resale through the optimal r 1. 17

18 3.3.1 Second Chance for B1 Bidders? Unlike noncommitment studies with a xed set of bidders in which it is sequentially optimal to constantly give bidders more chances (as in McAfee and Vincent, 1997), there are pros and cons of doing so in this model. On the one hand, other things being equal, including more bidders improves revenue in the re-auction; on the other hand, including B1 bidders means a lower contingently optimal r 2, which reduces the expected surplus extracted from B2 bidders. It seems that the relative strength of these countervailing forces largely depends on n and m: if m is large relative to n, it may be optimal to exclude B1 bidders ex ante and vice versa. We make the following de nitions: Definition 3 r 1 (v) : the corresponding r 1 of v Rev(r 1 (v); v) : the expected revenue as a function of v v : the globally optimal cuto value The next proposition shows that values of n and m are irrelevant to the auctioneer s decision. Proposition 5 v T H, or equivalently, r 2 (v ) < v. Therefore, on the optimal reserve price path, B1 bidders are always included as potential buyers after they fail in the initial auction.. Proof. The sketch of the proof is as follows. We rst prove that Rev(r 1 (v); v) strictly increases in v for v T H. We then prove that there exists some v (2) > T H such that Rev(r 1(v (2) ); v (2) ) Rev(r 1 (v); v) for any v > T H; thus, v (2) is the maximizer when v > T H. Finally, we show that Rev(r 1 (v (2) ); v (2) ) Rev(r 1(T H); T H) strictly increases in and is positive at = 0. Therefore, v (2) is also the global maximizer v, implying that the auctioneer optimally gives B1 bidders a second chance in the re-auction. Details are relegated to the Appendix. The intuition for Proposition 5 is not about the question of "why" but the question of "how": if the auctioneer wants to preclude B1 bidders from the re-auction, how can she realize that? Note that since she excludes B1 bidders when her posterior belief about their values is pessimistic, and this belief is consistently determined by r 1, we can conclude that r 1 cannot be high to ex ante preclude 18

19 B1 bidders. However, this observation contradicts her intention: she has an incentive to exclude B1 bidders only when B2 bidders appear more attractive ex ante in which case she is motivated to serve them in the re-auction. Nonetheless, to guarantee a good chance of a re-auction, r 1 has to be high. This means that the attempt to exclude B1 bidders would cause a result that works against the auctioneer s desires in the rst place. The key is that the auctioneer s hands are tied: she can only control r 1, but there are two countervailing e ects that need to be realized. Since the intuition does not depend on n, m or, we believe that this result can be extended to any nitely many periods (with a batch of patient bidders arriving in every period), which may be a good starting point for future research regarding non-commitment and sequential arrival the Auctioneer s Impact on Resale The auctioneer can only control the reserve prices; thus, it seems that her impact on resale is limited. However, the optimal cuto v can play a critical role, to the extent that it can even prevent resale. To explain this point, note that the attractiveness of resale decreases with the winner s own value v. In equilibrium, v has to be higher than v. Since v() (the point where x = w(x)) is the threshold above which a B1 bidder does not hold a resale conditional on winning, resale is implicitly banned if v is higher than v(). However, it is generally impossible to verify whether v v() because v cannot be solved in closed form. The next proposition provides three independent su cient conditions such that resale does not occur under the auctioneer s revenue-maximizing incentive. Proposition 6 Any of the following conditions alone is su cient for implicitly banning resale : i) v() 2 [0; T H] ii) v() 2 (T H; r ]; R r(t H) T H (x 1 F (x) f(x) )df m (x) 0 iii) There exists some ~ su ciently close to 1 such that when 2 ( ~ ; 1], resale does not occur. Proof. Condition i): Proposition 5 shows that the optimal cuto is v = v (2) > T H. By transitivity, v > v(). A winner s value has to be higher than v in equilibrium; thus, resale is implicitly banned. Condition ii): By transitivity, it su ces to show that v = v (2) > r. Since Rev(r 1 (v); v) reaches its maximum at v (2), it su ces to show that Rev(r 1(v); v) increases in v for v 2 [T H; r ]. The 19

20 expression for Rev(r 1 (v); v) can be found at the beginning of the proof of Proposition 5 in the Appendix. We next discuss two cases: a) When v 2 [v(); r ], drev(r 1(v);v) dv > nf n 1 (v)f(v)f 1 F (v) f(v) vg(1 ) 0. b) When v 2 [T H; v()), a su cient condition for drev(r 1(v);v) dv > 0 when v minfv(); r g is R r(t H) T H (x 1 F (x) f(x) )df m (x) 0. Therefore, when condition ii) holds, drev(r 1(v);v) dv Condition iii) > 0, implying that v (2) > r v(). When = 1, clearly the auctioneer should wait to gather all n + m bidders in the second stage; thus, the optimal cuto should be 1 in the initial auction. By continuity, when is su ciently large, resale does not occur on the equilibrium path either. Condition i) is straightforward. When B1 bidders are very impatient, resale does not appear attractive, and thus, the winner forgoes the resale opportunity out of his own will. Condition ii) is more di cult. As B1 bidders become more patient, the resale opportunity is no longer neglectable, and thus, the winner has an incentive to hold a resale. However, the auctioneer is also more patient; thus, B2 bidders also appear more attractive to her. In this case, the auctioneer has an incentive to raise r 1 such that she is more likely to directly serve B2 bidders. The second part of condition ii) particularly adds to B2 bidders attractiveness because it partly represents the marginal revenue that the auctioneer can extract from the most competitive B2 bidder. Therefore, in contrast to condition i), we can say that B1 bidders are forced to forgo resale as a result of a higher r 1. Condition iii) is straightforward: when both parties are su ciently patient, the auctioneer has an incentive to set an extremely high r 1 to delay the sale. This r 1 eliminates any possible resale motivation in the event that there is a winner. It remains an open question whether the auctioneer s revenue-maximizing incentive can eliminate resale intention for any parameter values. The closest conclusion in the spirit of this conjecture was achieved by Ausubel and Cramton (1999) but with a xed set of bidders and complete information in resale. Garratt et al. (2009) also mention that controlling the reserve price can help dampen a speculator s resale incentive. An educated guess is that the auctioneer is able to prevent resale in the private-value model when she has the same information about new arrivals as do B1 bidders. In reality, there may be some exogenous shocks after the initial auction, the exact in uence of which cannot be fully predicted ex ante. For example, if the item auctioned is a house and the 20

21 government releases a policy reducing mortgage rates after the initial auction, additional demand could expand the potential market for resale. This type of event may incentivize a winner who does not bene t from resale ex ante. Although an auctioneer cannot prevent resale by designing the optimal reserve price in the initial auction, we believe that she can still partially indirectly extract some surplus. 4 Discussions and Concluding Remarks In this paper, we focus on how a sequentially rational auctioneer should sell an item in a timely fashion to a dynamic and patient bidder population, when intertemporal resale is possible. Our work contributes to optimal auctions with resale and to direct and indirect dynamic mechanism design with limited or no commitment. Although our model is stylized for tractability purposes, it nevertheless reveals new and critical properties that persist in a general setting. Endogenous asymmetry is crucial in the non-commitment counterpart of dynamic mechanism design problems such as Board and Skrzypacz (2016). Moreover, it is inevitably associated with the multi-equilibria phenomenon, which is also novel in the literature. This phenomenon creates an immediate di culty since the theoretically optimal direct mechanism may not be successfully implemented. Considering the popularity of similar settings such as Board and Skrzypacz (2016) in the mechanism design literature, our paper serves as an initial attempt to explore a new direction. The other direction that may be further explored is the competition between the auctioneer and current bidders when they all have the potential to reach future bidders; moreover, the competition incentive is not restricted to the auction mechanism. We show that in some circumstances, the auctioneer s revenue-maximizing incentive can prevent resale even though she does not have the executive power to do so. We make several assumptions, some of which can be relaxed. 1. Private-value To some extent, this is a usual assumption in the resale literature made for the sake of tractability 17. Real items normally have a common value part and a private value part. When values are a liated, a usual assumption is that the auctioneer has more accurate information about the veiled 17 For example, see Hafalir and Krishna (2008), Garratt et al. (2009), Pagnozzi (2009) and Xu et al. (2013). 21

22 "common-value-part" of the item than do bidders. The reserve price and decision to delay sale (which would require a secret reserve price) would thus have a signaling e ect 18. Moreover, when considering optimal auctions in this environment, it is almost necessary for the auctioneer to know the true value of the common value part, as in Horstmann and LaCasse (1997), otherwise her option value of keeping the item also depends on her posterior beliefs. Distributional assumptions also have to be made to keep the analysis tractable. Even so, the signaling e ect alone makes it very di cult to determine the optimal public or secret reserve prices in general. 2. Deterministic n and m In reality, n and m could be random: the auctioneer may only have a rough estimate of the actual numbers of arrivals. If n cannot be observed throughout, as long as B1 bidders and the auctioneer have the same information about m s distribution, the analysis would still hold. If n can be observed after the initial auction, the auctioneer needs to determine the optimal contingent r 2 for any possible n when deciding r 1, but the results would not change qualitatively. However, if the estimate of m becomes more optimistic between two auctions, a winner may change his opinion on resale ex post. This type of unpredictable good shocks would change the results in this paper. 3. Patient bidders If a subset of B1 bidders are supposed to leave regardless of the outcome after the initial auction, they would bid sincerely while other B1 bidders still take the resale opportunity into account. Another possibility would be random exits: every B1 bidder has an equal chance of leaving. In this case, bidding strategies in the initial auction would still be symmetric, but the reserve price in the reauction would depend on realization of the number of random exits, which then projects back onto the auctioneer s rst-stage problem. 4. Monotonic equilibrium bidding strategy We focus on symmetric monotonic bidding strategies in the initial auction, which leaves no unrealized surplus among B1 bidders. Garratt et al. (2009) consider implicit collusion among bidders and prove that collusion exists with any positive reserve price as long as is su ciently close 18 For example, see Horstmann and LaCasse (1997) and Cai et al. (2007). 22

23 to 1. Although their model does not have new bidders, it can still shed light on this aspect. In any tacit collusion equilibrium, it must be the case that the designated winner nds it optimal to include other B1 bidders as potential buyers (together with B2 bidders) in resale. However, the existence of B2 bidders increases the bene t of becoming the winner and decreases the attractiveness of waiting for resale; thus, it may destroy the collusive equilibrium. 5. Number of stages We assume that the game ends mandatorily after two stages, which is a special case of nitely many periods. 19 For a general T, the model can easily become very complicated. Take T = 3 as an example. In the initial auction, any B1 bidder needs to calculate his expected payo from winning, which is the maximum of his value and the expected payo from resale. However, resale may last for two periods, as the initial resale attempt (in the second stage) could fail. Therefore, any B1 bidder has to consider ex ante whether to keep the item after the second period or to run a resale again in the third period facing B2 bidders and B3 bidders (further, he needs to consider whether to include B2 bidders in the second resale). Complexity increases drastically for the initial auctioneer not only because the number of decision variables increases but also because the complexity of the bidders decision problem projects back to her. Analytical results can still be derived through backward induction, but it is likely that the features of the optimal reserve price path will not emerge as clearly as in the T = 2 model. However, since the basic intuition still holds, results should hold qualitatively Auction formats We restrict attention to the ascending English auction and second-price sealed-bid auction partly for tractability, as sincere bidding constitutes equilibrium in the re-auction and resale even when value distributions are ex post asymmetric. Moreover, variants of ascending English auctions are widely used in reality. In comparison, if a rst-price sealed-bid auction is employed, asymmetry in 19 Board and Skrzypacz (2016) provide many real-world applications as interpretations of a dynamic and patient buyer population with items that have an "expiry date". 20 Skreta (2015) also considers a two-stage model and predicts that the results are robust to any number of nite stages, although detailed analysis is restricted to the T = 2 case. 23

Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale

Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale Optimal Sequential Auctions with a Dynamic Bidder Population and Resale Xiaoshu Xu y March, 2018 Abstract In practice, when bidders arrive sequentially and resale cannot be banned, the auctioneer s re-auction

More information

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Joosung Lee Daniel Z. Li University of Edinburgh Durham University January, 2018 1 / 48 A Motivational Example A puzzling observation in mergers and acquisitions

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Jonathan Levin 1 Economics 285 Market Design Winter 2009 1 These slides are based on Paul Milgrom s. onathan Levin VCG Mechanisms Winter 2009 1 / 23 Motivation We consider

More information

Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs

Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs Guofu Tan and Okan Yilankaya January 2005 Abstract We investigate equilibria of sealed-bid second price auctions with bidder participation costs

More information

Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale

Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale Rod Garratt, Thomas Tröger, and Charles Zheng September 29, 2006 Abstract In second-price or English auctions involving symmetric, independent,

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL WORKING PAPER SERIES

CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL WORKING PAPER SERIES CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL WORKING AER SERIES Cardiff Economics Working apers Helmuts Āzacis and éter Vida Collusive Communication Schemes in a First-rice Auction E2012/11 Cardiff Business School Cardiff

More information

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Auctions with Synergy and Resale

Auctions with Synergy and Resale Auctions with Synergy and Resale Xiaoshu Xu, Dan Levin, and Lixin Ye March 21 Abstract We study a sequential auction of two objects with two bidders, where the winner of the package obtains a synergy from

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation joint work with Stephen Morris August 2009 Barcelona Introduction mechanism design and implementation literatures are theoretical successes mechanisms

More information

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Daron Acemoglu y Kostas Bimpikis z Asuman Ozdaglar x October 2008. Abstract This paper studies a simple model of experimentation and innovation. Our analysis suggests

More information

Entry in First-price Auctions with Signaling

Entry in First-price Auctions with Signaling Entry in First-price Auctions with Signaling Olivier Bos and Tom Truyts Abstract We study the optimal entry fee in a symmetric private value first-price auction with signaling, in which the participation

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) April 2001 Abstract

More information

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Geethanjali Selvaretnam Abstract This model takes into consideration the fact that depositors

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen 1 Bayesian Games So far we have assumed that all players had perfect information regarding the elements of a game. These are called games with complete information.

More information

Solving Extensive Form Games

Solving Extensive Form Games Chapter 8 Solving Extensive Form Games 8.1 The Extensive Form of a Game The extensive form of a game contains the following information: (1) the set of players (2) the order of moves (that is, who moves

More information

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions Some Lecture Notes on Auctions John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics Uniersity of California, Berkeley Preliminaries Perhaps the most fruitful area for the application of optimal

More information

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions Some Lecture Notes on Auctions John Morgan February 25 1 Introduction These notes sketch a 1 hour and 5 minute lecture on auctions. The main points are: 1. Set up the basic auction problem. 2. Derie the

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility May 30, 2013 Setup X : finite set of public alternatives X = {x 1,..., x K } Θ i : the set of possible types for player i, F i is the marginal distribution of θ i. We assume types are independently distributed.

More information

Discussion Paper #1541

Discussion Paper #1541 CMS-EMS Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics And Management Science Discussion Paper #1541 Common Agency with Informed Principals: Menus and Signals Simone Galperti Northwestern University June

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is.

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is. Problem 1: Choice models and assortment optimization Consider a MNL choice model over five products with prices (p1,..., p5) = (7, 6, 4, 3, 2) and preference weights (i.e., MNL parameters) (v1,..., v5)

More information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Alain Delacroix (UQAM) and Etienne Wasmer (Sciences-Po) September 4, 2009 Abstract Wage determination under asymmetric information generates ine ciencies

More information

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Jianqing Chen Andrew Whinston Web Appendix A Heterogeneous Consumer Valuation In the baseline model, we assumed that consumers

More information

Dynamic Mechanism Design:

Dynamic Mechanism Design: Dynamic Mechanism Design: Revenue Equivalence, Pro t Maximization, and Information Disclosure Alessandro Pavan, Ilya Segal, Juuso Toikka May 2008 Motivation Mechanism Design: auctions, taxation, etc...

More information

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory Dirk Bergemann and Johannes Hoerner Department of Economics Yale Uniersity Final Exam (Solution) Economics 5b Microeconomic Theory May This is a closed-book exam. The exam lasts for 8 minutes. Please write

More information

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 John Nachbar Washington University May 2, 2017 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 1 Introduction. The Revenue Equivalence Theorem gives conditions under which some very different auctions generate the same

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

Exclusive contracts and market dominance

Exclusive contracts and market dominance Exclusive contracts and market dominance Giacomo Calzolari and Vincenzo Denicolò Online Appendix. Proofs for the baseline model This Section provides the proofs of Propositions and 2. Proof of Proposition.

More information

Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs

Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs Second Price Auctions with Differentiated Participation Costs Xiaoyong Cao Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, TX 77843 Guoqiang Tian Department of Economics Texas A&M University

More information

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Rabah Amir Department of Economics, University of Arizona Giuseppe De Feo y CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain February 2007 Abstract This paper addresses the issue

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: Signalling Games In general, a dynamic game of incomplete information is any extensive form game in which at least one player is uninformed about some

More information

Bounded Rationality Lecture 4

Bounded Rationality Lecture 4 Bounded Rationality Lecture 4 Mark Dean Princeton University - Behavioral Economics The Story So Far... Introduced the concept of bounded rationality Described some behaviors that might want to explain

More information

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Games and Economic Behavior 38, 19 27 22 doi:116 game21879, available online at http: wwwidealibrarycom on Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Sushil Bihchandani 2 Anderson Graduate School

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) October 2000 Abstract

More information

Monopoly with Resale. Supplementary Material

Monopoly with Resale. Supplementary Material Monopoly with Resale Supplementary Material Giacomo Calzolari Alessandro Pavan October 2006 1 1 Restriction to price offers in the resale ultimatum bargaining game In the model set up, we assume that in

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen Strategic Form Games In this part we will analyze games in which the players choose their actions simultaneously (or without the knowledge of other players

More information

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Gagan Ghosh Bingchao Huangfu Heng Liu October 19, 2017 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: COMMENTS WELCOME) Abstract We study wars of attrition between two bidders who

More information

Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design

Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design Makis Arsenis National Technical University of Athens April 216 Makis Arsenis (NTUA) AGT April 216 1 / 41 Outline 1 Social Choice Social Choice

More information

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Matthias Kräkel y Anja Schöttner z Abstract It is well-known that, in static models, minimum wages generate positive worker rents and, consequently, ine ciently

More information

Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy

Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy Shahar Dobzinski Department of Computer Science Cornell Unversity shahar@cs.cornell.edu Robert Kleinberg Department of Computer Science Cornell Unversity

More information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Pei-yu Lo 1 Introduction Recap: BoS. Look for all Nash equilibria. show how to nd pure strategy Nash equilibria. Show how to nd mixed strategy Nash equilibria.

More information

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) A Game in Normal (strategic) Form consists of three components. A set of players. For each player, a set of strategies (called actions in textbook). The interpretation

More information

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** WP-AD 2008-12 Corresponding author: R. Fauli-Oller Universidad de Alicante,

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Volume 30, Issue 3 Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Abstract The Milgrom-Shannon single crossing property is essential for monotone

More information

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1846 EFFICIENT AUCTIONS AND INTERDEPENDENT TYPES Dirk Bergemann, Stephen Morris, and Satoru Takahashi

More information

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2 Answers Answer for Q (a) ( pts:.5 pts. for the de nition and.5 pts. for its characterization) The de nition of PE is standard. There may be many ways to characterize the set of PE allocations. But whichever

More information

Ex-Post Full Surplus Extraction, Straightforwardly

Ex-Post Full Surplus Extraction, Straightforwardly Ex-Post Full Surplus Extraction, Straightforwardly Vlad Mares 1 and Ronald M. Harstad 2 1 Olin School of Business, Washington University in St. Louis, 1 Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130-4899 USA (email:

More information

Game Theory. Solutions to Problem Set 4

Game Theory. Solutions to Problem Set 4 1 Hotelling s model 1.1 Two vendors Game Theory Solutions to Problem Set 4 Consider a strategy pro le (s 1 s ) with s 1 6= s Suppose s 1 < s In this case, it is pro table to for player 1 to deviate and

More information

Monopoly with Resale

Monopoly with Resale Monopoly with Resale Giacomo Calzolari Alessandro Pavan July 2004 Abstract his paper illustrates the intricacies associated with the design of revenue-maximizing mechanisms for a monopolist who expects

More information

Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS. Heng Liu

Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS. Heng Liu Working Paper EQUILIBRIUM SELECTION IN COMMON-VALUE SECOND-PRICE AUCTIONS Heng Liu This note considers equilibrium selection in common-value secondprice auctions with two bidders. We show that for each

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008

Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information. November 14, 2008 Lecture 6 Games with Incomplete Information November 14, 2008 Bayesian Games : Osborne, ch 9 Battle of the sexes with incomplete information Player 1 would like to match player 2's action Player 1 is unsure

More information

Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions

Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions Matthew O. Jackson September 21, 2005 Forthcoming: Review of Economic Design Abstract A simple example shows that equilibria

More information

Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach

Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach Jeongmeen Suh y KIEP Murat Y lmaz z Bo¼gaziçi University March 29 Abstract This paper analyzes open innovation projects and their e ects on incentives for innovation.

More information

A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle

A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle A Simple Example to Illustrate the Linkage Principle Daniel Quint University of Wisconsin April 06 Abstract. I present a numerical example illustrating the revenue-superiority of an open over a closed

More information

Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit

Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit Pauli Murto Helsinki School of Economics and HECER

More information

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Ilan Guttman, Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz Stanford Graduate School of Business November 2011 1 Introduction

More information

THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS. A Dissertation XIAOYONG CAO

THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS. A Dissertation XIAOYONG CAO THEORIES ON AUCTIONS WITH PARTICIPATION COSTS A Dissertation by XIAOYONG CAO Submitted to the Office of Graduate Studies of Texas A&M University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

Advanced Microeconomics II

Advanced Microeconomics II Advanced Microeconomics Auction Theory Jiaming Mao School of Economics, XMU ntroduction Auction is an important allocaiton mechanism Ebay Artwork Treasury bonds Air waves ntroduction Common Auction Formats

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE) EconS 3 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE). Based on MWG 9.B.3 Consider the three-player nite game of perfect information depicted in gure. L R Player 3 l r a b

More information

On Overdissipation of Rents in Contests with Endogenous Intrinsic Motivation. Volker Schlepütz

On Overdissipation of Rents in Contests with Endogenous Intrinsic Motivation. Volker Schlepütz On Overdissipation of Rents in Contests with Endogenous Intrinsic Motivation Volker Schlepütz Diskussionsbeitrag Nr. 421 Februar 2008 Diskussionsbeiträge der Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft der FernUniversität

More information

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games

Chapter 2. Equilibrium. 2.1 Complete Information Games Chapter 2 Equilibrium Equilibrium attempts to capture what happens in a game when players behave strategically. This is a central concept to these notes as in mechanism design we are optimizing over games

More information

Asymmetric Information and Bank Runs

Asymmetric Information and Bank Runs Asymmetric Information and Bank uns Chao Gu Cornell University Draft, March, 2006 Abstract This paper extends Peck and Shell s (2003) bank run model to the environment in which the sunspot coordination

More information

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801 Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 880 Larry E. Jones Introduction The basic reference for these notes is: Thomas, J. and T. Worrall (990): Income Fluctuation and Asymmetric Information: An Example

More information

Delay and Information Aggregation in Stopping Games with Private Information

Delay and Information Aggregation in Stopping Games with Private Information ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Delay and Information Aggregation in Stopping Games with Private Information Pauli Murto Helsinki School of Economics

More information

Asymmetric Common-Value Auctions with Applications to Private-Value Auctions with Resale

Asymmetric Common-Value Auctions with Applications to Private-Value Auctions with Resale Asymmetric Common-Value Auctions with Applications to Private-Value Auctions with Resale Harrison Cheng and Guofu Tan Department of Economics University of Southern California 36 South Vermont Avenue Los

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems CSCI699: Topics in Learning and Game Theory Lecture 4 Lecturer: Shaddin Dughmi Scribes: Haifeng Xu,Reem Alfayez 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems Example 1: Single Item Auctions. There is a single

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill remium Ariel Burstein UCLA and NBER Jonathan Vogel Columbia and NBER April 22 Abstract In this Addendum we set up a perfectly competitive version

More information

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics.

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics. Puri cation 1 Stephen Morris Princeton University July 2006 1 This survey was prepared as an entry for the second edition of the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. In a mixed strategy equilibrium of

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information

Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information Zhuozheng Li, Huanxing Yang, and Lan Zhang y JEL Classi cation: D3, D74, D8 Keywords: Cheap talk, Coordination game, Centralization,

More information

Auctions with Dynamic Populations: Efficiency and Revenue Maximization

Auctions with Dynamic Populations: Efficiency and Revenue Maximization MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Auctions with Dynamic Populations: Efficiency and Revenue Maximization Maher Said Yale University 27. April 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/14988/ MPRA

More information

Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets

Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets Jidong Zhou y June 2010 Abstract This paper presents an ordered search model in which consumers search both for price and product tness. I construct an equilibrium

More information

Prices and Quality Signals

Prices and Quality Signals Prices and Quality Signals Mark Voorneveld Department of Economics Stockholm School of Economics P.O. Box 650 3 83 Stockholm, Sweden Jörgen W. Weibull Department of Economics Boston University 270 Bay

More information

Working Paper Series. Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes. Jun Xiao. June Research Paper Number 1151

Working Paper Series. Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes. Jun Xiao. June Research Paper Number 1151 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Jun iao June 212 Research Paper Number 1151 ISSN: 819 2642 ISBN: 978 734 451 Department of Economics The

More information

Cheap Talk in the Decentralized Market for Lemons

Cheap Talk in the Decentralized Market for Lemons Cheap Talk in the Decentralized Market for Lemons KyungMin Kim y October, 28 (Job Market Paper) Abstract This paper develops a decentralized market structure where sellers have private information about

More information

Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes

Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Asymmetric All-Pay Contests with Heterogeneous Prizes Jun iao y May 212 Abstract This paper studies complete-information, all-pay contests with asymmetric players competing for multiple heterogeneous prizes.

More information

Strategies under Strategic Uncertainty

Strategies under Strategic Uncertainty Discussion Paper No. 18-055 Strategies under Strategic Uncertainty Helene Mass Discussion Paper No. 18-055 Strategies under Strategic Uncertainty Helene Mass Download this ZEW Discussion Paper from our

More information

Training, Search and Wage Dispersion Technical Appendix

Training, Search and Wage Dispersion Technical Appendix Training, Search and Wage Dispersion Technical Appendix Chao Fu University of Wisconsin-Madison October, 200 Abstract This paper combines on-the-job search and human capital theory to study the coexistence

More information

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006 Economics 301 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 0, 006 Lecture 11 Topics Problem Set 9 Extensive Games of Imperfect Information An Example General Description Strategies and Nash Equilibrium Beliefs

More information

Interdependent Value Auctions with Insider Bidders

Interdependent Value Auctions with Insider Bidders Interdependent Value Auctions with Insider Bidders Jinwoo Kim November 2003 Abstract I study auctions in which there exists an asymmetry in bidders knowledge about their interdependent valuations. Bidders

More information

A Principal-Agent Model of Sequential Testing

A Principal-Agent Model of Sequential Testing A Principal-Agent Model of Sequential Testing Dino Gerardi y Lucas Maestri z July 2011 Abstract This paper analyzes the optimal provision of incentives in a dynamic information acquisition process. In

More information

Optimal Signals in Bayesian Persuasion Mechanisms with Ranking

Optimal Signals in Bayesian Persuasion Mechanisms with Ranking Optimal Signals in Bayesian Persuasion Mechanisms with Ranking Maxim Ivanov y McMaster University August 2015 (First version: October 2013) Abstract This paper develops a novel approach based on the majorization

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

Second-Price Auctions with Different Participation Costs

Second-Price Auctions with Different Participation Costs Second-Price Auctions with Different Participation Costs Xiaoyong Cao Department of Economics University of International Business and Economics Beijing, China, 100029 Guoqiang Tian Department of Economics

More information

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance DORON LEVIT and NADYA MALENKO The Internet Appendix has three sections. Section I contains supplemental materials

More information

Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units

Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units Economic Theory (2006) 29: 197 211 DOI 10.1007/s00199-005-0009-y RESEARCH ARTICLE Indranil Chakraborty Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units Received: 26 April 2004

More information

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics Benoit S Y Crutzen and Nicolas Sahuguet y September 20 Abstract This paper studies an electoral competition game between two candidates,

More information

Game Theory: Spring 2017

Game Theory: Spring 2017 Game Theory: Spring 2017 Ulle Endriss Institute for Logic, Language and Computation University of Amsterdam Ulle Endriss 1 Plan for Today In this second lecture on mechanism design we are going to generalise

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

Lecture Notes on Bargaining

Lecture Notes on Bargaining Lecture Notes on Bargaining Levent Koçkesen 1 Axiomatic Bargaining and Nash Solution 1.1 Preliminaries The axiomatic theory of bargaining originated in a fundamental paper by Nash (1950, Econometrica).

More information