Structural holes in social networks

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Structural holes in social networks"

Transcription

1 Structural holes in social networks Sanjeev Goyal Fernando Vega-Redondo Preliminary version: July 2004 Abstract We consider a setting where every pair of players can interact (e.g. exchange goods) and this interaction yields a fixed surplus. An interaction can take place only if the players involved have a connection. This connection may be direct, in which case the two players split the surplus equally. But the interaction could also be indirect (i.e. involving more than two players in the path), and then every player essential to the connection is assumed to get an equal share of the surplus. In the model, the incentives to forming links derive from the possibilities they avail in three respects: () the creation of new interaction opportunities; (2) the rents that can be attained from essential intermediation; (3) the payment of rents that can be avoided by circumventing intermediaries. We focus on an equilibrium notion in which pairs of players may jointly coordinate on the (possibly simultaneous) creation and destruction of the links they control. Our main conclusion is that, so long as costs of forming links are not very small, all (non-empty and strict) equilibrium networks are stars. In such networks, a single agent is essential for all bilateral interaction and there is significant inequality in payoff distribution. We end the paper by showing that the main gist of the analysis is essentially maintained if commitment is ruled out and bilateral deviations are required to be internally consistent. Department of Economics, University of Essex, sgoyal@essex.ac.uk. Department of Economics, Universidad de Alicante, University of Essex, and Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas, vega@merlin.fae.ua.es.

2 Introduction There is a growing consensus among social researchers that a proper understanding of many socio-economic phenomena cannot be dissociated from the underlying social network in which they are embedded. This pertains to a wide variety of problems ranging from labor markets (Granovetter, 973), to industrial R&D (Gulati et al., 2000), technological diffusion (Valente, 996), scientific collaboration (Newman, 200 and Goyal et al., 2004), modern inter-industrial trade (Kranton and Minehart, 200)), or even trade in historical times (Greif, 994). In all these cases, the aim of the research has been to understand how the underlying pattern of connections (i.e. the architecture of the social network) impinges on the outcome of the process employment, trade, or the scope for technological diffusion. Clearly, one of the features of network architecture that will have an important bearing on the network benefits accruing to the different individual concerns their relative importance in connecting others. Thus, for any particular agent, one would expect that the payoff she is able to muster would depend on how indispensable she is in bridging valuable connections among other individuals. These ideas are at the heart of the notion of structural holes introduced by Ronald Burt (992). Over the past decade, Burt and several others have elaborated on this notion in both theoretical and empirical terms. In particular, there is extensive empirical work done on this subject. This work may be summarized as follows. Even after controlling for individual characteristics, we are left with a substantial variance in individual performance in organizations (measured in terms of salaries and promotions). The differences in structural location of otherwise similar individuals in particular whether they bridge structural holes in the social network explains a significant part of this variance. Given the substantial rewards from network positioning, it seems natural to postulate that an individual will make investments to become a bridge (critical to the interconnectedness of the network) while other individuals have an incentive to prevent this from happening by forming alternative routes to interaction. In this paper, 2

3 we ask what will be the shape of networks when (ex-ante identical) individuals can rationally form links and therefore create positional advantages for themselves while others have an equal incentive to prevent them from acquiring this positional power. We develop a simple model of network formation to address this question. We consider a setting where it is costly to form links but every pair of connected players can interact (say exchange goods or communicate) and this yields a fixed surplus. The interaction can take place only if the players have a connection, direct or indirect. If the connection is direct (i.e. without intermediaries), the two players split the surplus equally. Otherwise, the interaction occurs through an indirect connection and other additional players are required to generate the surplus. This leads us to introducing the idea of essential players. A player k is said to be essential to an interaction between i and j if k lies on every path between i and j in the network. In general, of course, there may be more than one essential player on a path. Under the assumption that any essential player has the power to block the interaction, we invoke a standard bargaining approach to postulate that the surplus generated by some i and j is split equally between all the players (including i and j) essential for the connection. This formulation gives rise to three types of incentives. The first incentive is the standard access advantage: individuals would like to join the network so as to create exchange possibilities which in turn create surpluses. The second incentive is related to the rewards from being essential: players would like to place themselves between unconnected others in order to extract rents from intermediation. The third incentive arises out of the desire to avoid sharing surpluses with intermediaries; in other words, individuals will try to circumvent essential players to retain more of the surplus to themselves. In this setup we consider a model of network formation where links are formed by bilateral agreement and any pair of players can jointly deviate to form (and possibly destroy, simultaneously) the links that affect them. Our main result is that, as long as costs are not very low, all non-empty equilibrium 3

4 networks define a star, with a single individual acting as an essential intermediary to all bilateral connections. There are two aspects of the result that we would like to stress: the uniqueness of the equilibrium network and the significant inequality it entails among the payoffs of players who are ex-ante identical. Thus an extreme version of strategic positioning with attendant payoff differences is the only possible outcome in a setting with ex-ante identical individuals. We now briefly sketch the main logic underlying this finding. The basic arguments derive from the incentives mentioned above. A first simple insight is that, due to the role played by access benefits, an equilibrium network must be either empty or connected (i.e. display a single component). Thus, among non-empty networks, we only need to check which connected networks are stable to both unilateral and bilateral deviations. If the network is minimally connected (i.e. has no cycles), long paths cannot be stable. This happens because extremal players benefit from connecting to a central player in order to save on intermediation costs (cutting path lengths) and, on the other hand, a central player is also ready to incur the cost of an additional link because this enhances her intermediation payoffs. Thus there is a natural tendency for minimally connected networks to become agglomerated around central players. But what about the possible existence of cycles? In principle, a cycle containing all players appears to be very attractive. No player is essential in such a network and each of them can access every other. Such a cycle network, however, is vulnerable to the pressures towards becoming essential and reaping the entailed intermediation benefits. To see this, consider two players that are far apart in the cycle and establish a direct link. By simultaneously breaking one link each, they can produce a line and become central in it. Certainly, this means that they must then pay some intermediation costs (which were previously absent, since no player is essential in a full cycle), but their prominent centrality more than offsets those costs through even larger intermediation benefits. A similar argument can be used to break any cycle, thus leaving the star network (i.e. the minimally connected network with shortest distances) as the unique non-empty equilibrium network. 4

5 Our paper is related to research conducted in both economics and sociology during the last decades. In particular, much attention has been recently devoted by economists and game theorists to the theory of network formation. In this respect, the principal contribution of the present paper is to provide a new model of network formation that embodies two novel ideas, introduced for concreteness within the general framework of the connections model (Jackson and Wolinsky, 996; Bala and Goyal, 2000). The first idea is that the total value generated in the network must be distributed in a rival fashion among different individuals, i.e. a larger share enjoyed by one individual must be obtained at the expense of what others get. The second idea pertains to the notion of essentialness. This notion determines which players are critical for a certain fruitful interaction and allocates to them the value thus generated. We now briefly relate our paper to the work in sociology on structural holes. The large body of empirical work on economic advantages of networks positions which we cited earlier generated a natural question: how is it that such advantages arise in organizations and that they remain stable over time in a setting with rational actors who can figure out the rewards from structural positions? Our paper shows that this state of affairs is consistent with a model of rational players who strategically seek to create positional advantages for themselves and also have an incentive in preventing others from becoming central. To the best of our knowledge our model is the first formal model to illustrate the strategic stability of structural holes and the large inequality in payoffs that go with it. [[The paper is organized in four sections. The next section lays out the basic model. Section 3 presents the main results on equilibrium networks where both single players as well as any pair of players can implement any deviation. Section 3 briefly explores robustness of the main results to an alternative notion of strategic stability where bilateral commitment is not presumed. Section 4 concludes.]] Early work includes Aumann and Myerson (988); for more recent work see Dutta, van Den Nouweland and Tijs (995), Jackson and Wolinsky (996), and Bala and Goyal (999). 5

6 2 The Model 2. Link formation game Let N = {, 2,..., n} denote a finite set of ex-ante identical players. We shall assume that n 3. Every player makes an announcement of intended links. An intended link s i,j {0, }, where s ij = means that player i intends to form a link with player j, while s ij = 0 means that player i does not intend to form such a link. Thus a strategy of player i is given by s i = [s ij ] j N\{i}. Let S i denote the strategy set of player i. A link between two players i and j is formed if and only if s ij = s ji =. We denote the formed (undirected) link by g i,j g j,i = and the absence of a link by g i,j g j,i = 0. A strategy profile s = (s, s 2,..., s n ) therefore induces a network g(s). For expositional simplicity we shall often omit the dependence of the network on the underlying strategy profile. A network g = {(g i,j )} i,j N is a formal description of the pair-wise links that exist between the players. We let G denote the set of all possible networks (i.e. all undirected graphs with n vertices). We also let N i (g) = {j N : j i, g ij = } be the set of players with whom player i has a link in the network g, and have η i (g) = N i (g) denote the cardinality of this set. Given a network g, g + g i,j denotes the network obtained by replacing g i,j in network g by g i,j =, while g g i,j denotes the network obtained by replacing g i,j in network g by g i,j = 0. There exists a path between i and j in a network g if either g i,j = or if there is a distinct set of players {i,..., i n } such that g i,i = g i,i 2 = g i2,i 3 = = g in,j =. We shall say that a player k is essential for i and j if player k lies on every path that joins i and j in the network. Let E(j, k; g) stand for the set of players who are essential to connect j and k in network g, where we shall often write simply E(j, k) thus dispensing with the reference to g when there is no risk of ambiguity. Correspondingly, we denote by e(j, k; g) = E(j, k; g) the cardinality of this set. To illustrate matters, note that the number of essential players between j and k is zero if the players have a direct link or, alternatively, if players are located around a circle in the latter case, for every pair of players 6

7 j and k the and every other player i, there is always a path joining j and k that does not include i. On the other hand, in a star every pair of peripheral players has a single and common essential player, namely the center of the star. In our framework, we posit that there are two types of advantages that players get from being part of a network. First, there is the direct advantage from being able to access others; second, there is the indirect advantage that arises from being an essential intermediary between others. We assume that the precise determination of these direct and indirect advantages is settled, through bargaining among all agents involved (independently across different surplus units). Specifically, consider any pair of players j and k that are connected by some network path and may thus can generate a unit of surplus. In general, this unit may be divided among all agents in N according to some vector of non-negative shares z jk = (z jk i ) i N. In the language of Cooperative Game Theory, such a vector defines an imputation for the coalition game associated to the surplus produced by j and k. We shall be interested in the imputation ẑ jk that represents the unique selection of the Core of such coalition game induced by the Kernel (Davis and Maschler (965)). Implicitly, this outcome reflects a bargaining process among the agents in which, eventually, only the players j and k as well as all those in E(j, k) who are essential in establishing the desired connection obtain a positive share of the surplus. In fact, this share happens to be equal for all since every agent l E(j, k) {j, k} has an equal bargaining power, i.e. any of them can similarly block the generation of the unit of surplus. The formal details of the approach are included in the Appendix. When traslated into payoffs, it gives rise to a payoff function that, for every strategy profile s = (s, s 2,..., s n ), defines the (net) payoffs to player i as follows: Π i (s i, s i ) = j N i (g) e(i, j; g) j,k N where c is the fixed cost payed per link by each player. I {i;j,k} e(j, k; g) + 2 η i(g)c, () 7

8 2.2 Equilibrium analysis We study the architecture of networks that are strategically stable and assess their efficiency. Our notion of strategic stability is a refinement of Nash equilibrium that allows for coordinated two-person deviations. Definition A strategy profile s is a Bilateral Equilibrium (BE) if the following conditions hold: for any i N, and every s i S i, Π i (s ) Π i (s i, s i ); for any pair of players i, j N, and every strategy pair (s i, s j ), Π i (s i, s j, s i j) > Π i (s i, s j, s i j) Π j (s i, s j, s i j) < Π j (s j, s j, s i j). We apply the term bilateral equilibrium to a strategy profile where no player or pair of players can deviate (unilaterally or bilaterally, respectively) and benefit from the deviation (at least one of them strictly, for bilateral deviations). This notion refines the original formulation of pair-wise stability due to Jackson and Wolinsky (996) by allowing pairs of players to form and delete links simultaneously. Our analysis will focus on a refinement of BE that we call strict. It rules out the existence of deviations (unilateral or bilateral) that have some consequence (i.e. affect the network) but nevertheless are payoff indifferent for the agents involved. In part, the motivation of this equilibrium concept is dynamic: a gradual adjustment process that allows pairs of players to revise the network in sequence will (only) be absorbed by equilibria of this sort see below for an elaboration. Definition 2 A strategy profile s is a Strict Bilateral Equilibrium (SBE) if the following conditions hold: for any i N, and every s i S i such that g(s i, s i ) g(s ), Π i (s ) > Π i (s i, s i ); 8

9 for any pair of players, i, j N and every strategy pair (s i, s j ) with g(s i, s j, s i j ) g(s ), Π i (s i, s j, s i j) Π i (s i, s j, s i j) Π j (s i, s j, s i j) < Π j (s j, s j, s i j). Finally, we introduce the notion of efficiency considered. In line with the assumption that the setup involves transferable utility, different networks g are assessed in terms of the total surplus generated, W (g) i N Π i(g). Definition 3 A network g is efficient if W ( g) W (g) for all g G. 2.3 Networks A network is connected if there exists a path between any pair i, j N. A network, g g, is a component of g if for all i, j g, i j, there exists a path in g connecting i and j, and for all i g and k g, g i,k = implies k g. A component g g is complete if g i,j = for all i, j g. Two networks g and g are said to have the same architecture if one network can be obtained from the other by a permutation of the players labels. We shall say that a network is symmetric if every player has the same number of links, i.e., η i (g) = η(g) i N. Then we refer to η as the degree of the network. It should be noted that if the number of players is even, then a symmetric network of every degree is possible; this is not true when the number of players is odd. In some parts of the analysis, we explore symmetric networks and then we will be (implicitly) assuming that the number of players in the game is even. The complete network, g c, is a symmetric network in which η = n, i N, while the empty network, g e, is a symmetric network in which η = 0, i N. Another example of a symmetric network is a cycle where η = 2 and the whole set of nodes can be ordered in a list i, i 2,...i n with g i,i 2 = g i2,i 3 =... = g in,i =. We shall say that a network is asymmetric if there is at least one pair of players who have different number of links. One important example is the star 9

10 where there is a single node, i c, with η(i c ) = n while η(i) = for all other i i c. An interesting mixture is what we shall call the hybrid cycle-star network where there is a subset of k nodes C = {i, i 2,...i k } arranged in a cycle and some particular player i x C such that g j,ix = for all j N\C. 3 Results We start by characterizing efficient networks. Proposition If c < n/4 then an efficient network is minimally connected, while if c > n/4 then an efficient network is empty. Proof: It is easy to see that an efficient network cannot be partially connected and that it must be minimal. The aggregate payoff from a minimally (fully) connected network is (n )[n/2 2c], while the payoff from the empty network is 0. It then follows that a minimal connected network is efficient if and only if c < n/4, while an empty network is efficient if c > n/4. We now turn to the study of equilibrium networks, i.e. the networks induced by (S)BE which are simply labelled (S)BE networks. Our first finding is that an equilibrium network is either connected or empty. Proposition 2 A BE network is either empty or connected. The proof of this result makes use of the following technical result which is of independent interest. For any link g i,j = in g, define M i (g i,j ; g) = Π i (g) Π i (g g i,j ). Lemma Consider any network g. If g i,j = and the link is critical then M i (g i,j ; g) = M j (g i,j ; g). Proof: By hypothesis g i,j is critical, and so it follows that i and j lie in different components in the network g g i,j. Let C i (g), C j (g) be the components that contain i and j, respectively, where we shall usually dispense with an explicit 0

11 account of the dependence and simply write C i and C j. The marginal payoff of the link ij for player i, is given by: M i (g i,j ; g) = 2 + k C j \{j} e(i, k) l C i \{i} k C j \{j} e(l, k) l C i \{i} e(l, j) + 2 c where the first two terms refer to access benefits while the latter two terms refer to essentiality benefits. player j form link g i,j as: Similarly, we can write the marginal payoffs of M j (g i,j ; g) = 2 + l C i \{i} e(j, l) l C i \{i} k C j \{j} e(l, k) k C j \{j} e(i, k) + 2 c It follows then that M i (g i,j ; g) = M j (g i,j ; g) and the proof is complete. Equipped with this lemma we can now complete the proof of the connectedness result. Proof of Proposition 2: Let g be a non-empty BE network, and suppose it is not connected. Let Ĉ be the largest component in g. If Ĉ contains 2 players then it is immediate that both players in this component have a strict incentive to form a link with any other player not in the component. Given Lemma it follows that every player outside Ĉ in g also has an incentive to form a link with these players. Thus in the rest of the proof we concentrate on the case where Ĉ contains more than 2 players. This also means that there is at least one player (say) i Ĉ such that η i 2. Let Ni m (g) = {j C i : e(i, j) = m)} be the players whom i accesses via m essential players and let η m i payoffs of this player i in network g are then given by: η 0 i (g) 2 + η i (g) 3 + η2 i (g) 4 m (g) = Ni (g). The ηr i (g) L + 2 η i(g)c (2)

12 for some r n 2. Since g is an equilibrium, it follows then [ η 0 i (g) + η i (g) + η2 i (g) ηr i (g) ] c. (3) η i (g) r + 2 Now let us examine marginal returns for player j / Ĉ from forming a link with some player i. Suppose, for simplicity, that player j is a singleton component. Then the marginal returns to j are given as follows: η 0 j (g + g i,j) 2 + η j (g + g i,j) 3 + η2 i (g + g i,j) ηr i (g + g i,j) r + 2 c. (4) Note now that for every k Ĉ\{i}, e(j, k; g + g i,j) = e(i, k; g) +. Thus ηj m(g + g i,j) = η m i (g) for every m and ηj 0(g + g i,j) =. Using these facts we can write the marginal returns of player j from the link with j as follows: Now we argue that 2 + η0 i (g) + η i (g) ηr i (g) c. (5) 3 4 L + 3 c 2 + η0 i (g) + η i (g) 3 4 > [ η 0 i (g) 2 2 η i (g) + η i (g) 3 [ η 0 i (g) ηr i (g) L η i (g) 3 + η2 i (g) 4 + η2 i (g) ηr i (g) ] r ηr i (g) r + 2 The first inequality is immediate, while we use η i (g) 2 in deriving the second inequality and equation (3), in deriving the final inequality. We now apply Lemma to conclude that player i also has a strict incentive to form a link with j, given that all existing links are retained. But note that given that link g i,j is formed, player i has no incentive to delete any of his erstwhile links since (roughly speaking) the marginal returns from each of these links ] 2

13 has actually increased. Thus players i and j have a strict incentive to form an additional link and this link is a credible two-person deviation. These arguments extend directly to cover the case where j belongs to a non-singleton component. Thus g is not a BE network, a contradiction that completes the proof. We now look more closely at the architecture of equilibrium networks. The following result gives examples of two simple networks that arise in equilibrium. Proposition 3 If /6 < c < /2 + (n 2)/6 then a star is a BE network, while if c > /2 then the empty network is a BE network. Proof: We first prove that the star is a BE network for the parameter range specified. First consider the incentives of the center. The payoffs of the center are given by n 2 + (n )(n 2) (n )c. (6) 3 2 Note that the payoffs from a subset of links k are given by k 2 + (k)(k ) kc. (7) 3 2 It can be verified that the marginal payoffs are increasing with respect to k, and so the optimal number of links is either zero or n. It follows then that center maintains all links if c < /2+(n 2)/6. We next examine the incentives of peripheral players. Their payoff in the star is given by /2 + (n 2)/3 c. The payoffs from having two links are given by /2 + /2 + (n 3)/3 2c. It then follows that the peripheral player will choose to maintain one link with the center if /6 < c < /2 + (n 2)/3. This proves that the star is a BE network if /6 < c < /2 + (n 2)/6. It is straightforward to see that the empty network can be supported by a BE for c > /2. The star is a BE network for a wide range of parameters and this is due to the fact that centrality generates large payoffs from essentialness. However, a star also exhibits an extreme form of essentialness, with only one player being 3

14 essential for all pairs of players. This raises the question: are there other perhaps more egalitarian network architectures that can arise in BE? The following results provide a complete answer to this question, for large societies. Theorem Suppose that n is large. If /6 < c < /2 then any SBE network is a star while if /6 < c < /2 + (n 2)/6 then any non-empty SBE network is a star. Finally, if c > /2 + (n 2)/6 then the unique BE network is empty. This result provides a complete characterization of SBE networks for large societies. The proof proceeds through five steps. The first step shows that any minimally connected BE network is a star, for large n. The second step shows that there cannot be two or more cycles in an SBE network. The third step shows that there cannot be a single cycle containing all players in equilibrium. The fourth step shows that a non-empty SBE network with a cycle must be a hybrid cycle-star network. The final step shows that a hybrid cycle-star network cannot be SBE for large n. This means that for large n the only candidates for SBE networks are the star and the empty network. Lemma 2 Given c, there exist some ˆn(c) such that if n ˆn(c), any BE network that is minimally connected is a star. Proof: Consider a g that is minimally connected (thus, a tree) but not a star. Then, there are two players, say i and j, such that (a) E(i, j; g) 2; (b) they are end players, i.e. η i (g) = η j (g) =. Then, it readily follows that for at least one of them, say i, the following holds: There is a player x with e(i, x; g) = (thus, x is two steps away from i in g) and the set of players k for whom x is essential in connecting i and k has a cardinality that is at least (n 4)/2, i.e. {k N : x E(i, k; g) (n 4)/2. We argue that such a network g cannot be induced by an equilibrium. To see this, first note that, given the linking cost c, the number of essential players that can be supported in equilibrium between any two players has some (finite) upper bound ê(c), independent of n. Consider then the possibility that i and x 4

15 were to form a link. The gross gains, π i and π x, induced by that change for i and x (if all other links were to remain in place) is bounded below as follows: min{ π i, π x } (n 4)/2 ê(c) (n 4)/2 ê(c) = n 4 2ê(c)(ê(c) ). This expression is larger than c if n is large enough, which implies that both i and x benefit from a deviation that creates a link between them and keeps all other links. [[Argument for bilateral-proofness: Consider now the possibility that either i or x would want to delete some of their other links, simultaneously with the creation of the link between them. Would that alter their incentives to create that link? On the one hand, it is clear that x cannot profit from deleting any link, in particular the link to the single player y that was required to connect x to i in the network g. (Note that this link generates gross benefits to x that are again proportional to n.) Instead, it could be optimal for player i to remove the link to y, as she establishes the new link to x. This removal, however, can only decrease gross payoffs of x by /6, that of course cannot affect the optimality of creating the link for i if n is large.]] We now consider non-minimal networks. The following result shows that there cannot be more than one cycle in a strict equilibrium. Lemma 3 There can be at most one cycle in a SBE network. Proof: Suppose g is an equilibrium network and there are two or more cycles in it. Let χ = (i, i 2,...i n ) be ordered set of players in one cycle, and let χ 2 = (j, j 2,...j m ) be those in the other cycle. Since g is connected it follows that there are two possibilities: () cycles have common players and (2) cycles have no common players. We take these up in turn. (). Cycles have players in common: If there is a single common player i in the two cycles then it is easy to see that the partners of i (say) i 2 χ and j 2 χ 2 have a strict incentive to delete their links with i and instead form a link with 5

16 each other. (Throughout, we shall abuse notation and write i χ if i is one of the nodes in the ordered collection of nodes specifying χ.) Consider next the case with two or more players in common. Let (i, i 2,...i k ) be the players in common. Suppose that k 3; the case of k = 2 is simple and omitted. Then there exist players i, i x, and j y with the following properties: i x χ but i x / χ 2, while j y χ 2 and j y / χ and g i,i x = g i,j y = g i,i 2 =... = g ik,i k =. Note also that like player i, i k must again have links with a player who belongs to one of χ and χ 2 only. It then follows that i k and j y have at least a weak incentive to delete their current link with i k and i respectively and instead form a link with each other. It then follows that g cannot be sustained by a SBE. (2). Cycles have no common players. Since g is a SBE network it is connected and so there exists a path between the two cycles. Let (i, i 2,..., i k ) be members of such a path with i χ while i k χ 2. Suppose g i,i x = and g ik,j y =, where i x χ and j y χ 2. Now it is easy to use a variant of the earlier argument for case above to show that players i x and j y have a strict incentive to delete their link with i and i k and instead form a link with each other. The proof of the lemma is complete. We now turn to the networks with a single cycle. Lemma 4 Suppose n 4. 2 in a BE. A cycle containing all players cannot be sustained Proof: Consider two player i and j who are furthest apart in terms of geodesic distance in the cycle. Now consider the deviation in which each of the players deletes one link and they form a link with each other in such a way that they create a line. Assume, for simplicity, that n is even, so that there are (n 2)/2 players to one side of player i and (n 2)/2 players to the other side of player j in the line created. We now show that players i and j will strictly increase their payoff with this coordinated deviation. 2 We note that for n = 3 a complete network can be sustained in equilibrium for c < /6. 6

17 We proceed in two steps: the first step is to show that individual payoffs are strictly increasing as we move toward the center in the line. The payoffs of an individual player consist of two components, the returns from accessing others and the returns from being essential on paths between pairs of other players. Number the players on a line as, 2,...n. We show that the payoffs of player l + are greater than the payoffs of player l, where 2 l < n/2. The access returns to player l are given by l + l n l + while the access returns to player l + are given by (8) l + + l n l It now follows that access returns for player l + are larger than access returns for player l if l < n/2. We now turn to the returns from being essential. The returns to player l from being essential consist of two parts: the returns from being essential to pairs of players i and j where i < l and j > l +, and a second part which consist of returns from being essential for pairs i < l and player l +. The essentialness payoff to player l can be written as follows: (9) l n i= j=l+2 l e(i, j) i= e(i, l + ) + 2 (0) Similarly, the essentialness payoffs to player l + consist of two parts: those that arise out of linking players i < l with players j > l + and those that arise out of linking player l with players j > l +. These payoffs can be written as follows: l n i= j=l+2 e(i, j) n j=l+2 e(l, j) + 2 () 7

18 The first part of the essentialness payoffs to the two players are equal, while the second part of the payoffs are greater for player l + if l < n/2. Note that players < l < n all have two links in a line network and hence have the same costs. Combining the payoffs from access and essentialness we can then conclude that payoffs to player l + are greater than payoffs to player l, so long as < l < n/2. A similar argument shows that payoffs to player k are larger than payoffs of player k + if n/2 k < n. This completes our argument that payoffs are increasing as we move toward the center of the line. Let g C and g L denote the networks prevailing before the contemplated deviation and after it (i.e. the cycle and the line with i and j at the center, respectively). To show that i and j indeed obtain higher payoffs under g L, note that the aggregate gross payoffs obtained in both cases are the same. Let H W (g C ) + nc = W (g L ) + (n )c denote this common value. The above argument implies that i and j enjoy a higher share of H under g L than under g C. Thus, they also obtain higher gross payoffs under g L. Since their linking cost is the same in both cases (i.e. 2c), it follows that they obtain higher net payoffs as well, which completes the proof. We now move to the fourth step of the proof and show that any equilibrium network with a cycle must be a hybrid star-cycle network. Lemma 5 Consider an equilibrium network which has a cycle. It must then have the hybrid star-cycle architecture for large enough n. Proof: Suppose that g is a non-empty network sustained by a SBE. Then we know from Proposition 2 and Lemma 3 that it has at most one cycle and the rest of players belong to (possibly different) trees with a root at some node in the cycle or all belonging to a single tree if there is no cycle. Let x be the number of players who are outside the cycle, while y = n x is the number of players in it. Note that y 4 since y = 3 cannot be sustained in equilibrium 8

19 given that c > /6. Next we argue that, for any such c, there is a y(c) such that y y(c) in equilibrium. To prove this claim, first we note that, in view of Lemma 4, there must be at least one nondegenerate tree in the network g, with the root given by some player i and this player having a link to some other player j who does not belong to the cycle. Suppose now that the cycle is non-degenerate and let k be one of the nodes in the cycle that are connected to i. Clearly, player k always profits from shifting to j the link that connected it to i. On the other hand, j also benefits from such an adjustment if (y )/6 > c. So given a c, in order for the cycle to be stable, we must have the converse inequality, which implies that y y(c) 6c +. Now we argue that all nodes that do not belong to the cycle must be connected to a single node in the cycle. The initial observation is that, if n is large enough, there cannot be two distinct trees with different roots lying in the cycle. To see this, consider one of those subtrees that has a number of nodes at least equal to [n y(c)] /y(c) = (n/y(c)). At least one such tree must exist since there are at most y(c) nodes in the cycle. Let i be the root of this tree and i 2 be the root of any other cycle. Now consider any node j in the second tree different from its root, i 2. A straightforward adaptation of the arguments used in the proof of Lemma 2 lead to the conclusion that, if n is large, j and i can both profit from forming a link, whether or not j maintains its link with i 2. The reason is that, since the number of essential players e(l, l ) for any pair of players, l and l, is bounded by some ê(c), independently of n, the gross gains from the link between j and i grow linearly with n for both players, independendently of whether player j maintains the link to i 2. (Clearly, i cannot profit from destroying any of its links.) Once established that there can be at most one tree connected to the cycle through its root, again relying on the arguments introduced in Lemma 2 we arrive at the conclusion that, for any two nodes in the tree, u and v, the number of essential players e(u, v). This still leaves open the possibility that the tree consists of a star with a center at some node i c that is not part of the cycle but 9

20 has a link to some other node k in the cycle. But, in that case, the node i c and any of the neighbors of k in the cycle, say k, can jointly profit from establishing a direct link, even if k destroys the link with k. The final step in the proof shows that the hybrid cycle-star network is not an equilibrium for large n. Lemma 6 Suppose that c > /6. The star is the unique non-empty equilibrium, for large n. Proof: Suppose that g is non-empty equilibrium network and it has the hybrid cycle-star structure. As in the proof of Lemma 5, let x denote the number of peripheral players in the star, while y = n x stands for the number of players in the cycle. As explained, it may be assumed that y y(c) for a function y(c) that is independent of n. Thus, fixing some c, consider the class of hybrid networks g in which y y(c). Let i be the player in the center of the star and suppose that j and k are the players in the cycle who are connected to i. We show that players j and k have a strict incentive to form a link if the set of peripheral players x n y(c) is sufficiently large. The payoffs of players j and k in the hybrid network g H are given by π j (g H ) = π k (g H ) = x 3 + y 2 2c (2) Now consider a deviation by players j and k in which player k deletes his link with player i and player j deletes his link with player m in the cycle and instead players j and k form a link with each other. The resulting network is a minimal network g in which there are x peripheral players and a line starting with player i which consists of y players. The payoffs of player j in g are given by π j (g ) = x 3 + y 2 + k=2 These payoffs are bounded below by y+ k + x k=4 y k + k=3 2c (3) k x 3 + xy 2 2c = M (4) y + 20

21 Next note that M > x/3 + (y )/2 2c if x > y y + 2 y 2 (5) Since y 4, the right hand side is increasing in y and bounded above by [y(c) ][y(c)+]/2[y(c) 2]. The final step is to note that x = n y n y(c) and so (5) applies for sufficiently large n. Thus player j has a strict incentive to switch links to player k for large n. We now turn to the incentives of player k. The payoffs of player k in g are given by π k (g ) = x y k=2 These payoffs are bounded below by Note that M > x/3 + (y )/2 2c if y+ k + x k=5 y k + k=4 2c (6) k x 4 + xy 3 y + 2c = M (7) x :>: 6(y )(y + ) y 37 (8) Since y 4, the right hand side is positive and increasing in y and so is bounded above by 6[y(c) ][y(c) + ]/[y(c) 37]. Note that x = n y n y(c) is larger than this term for sufficiently large n. Thus player k has a strict incentive to switch links to player j, for sufficiently large n. The proof is complete. 4 Extension: Two-person coalition proof networks In our analysis so far we have assumed that a deviation by two players is credible so long as it yields higher payoffs to both players. We have not looked at profitable deviations from the agreed upon deviation, in the spirit of the standard notion of coalition proofness. In this section we will examine the implications of 2

22 this further requirement, which of course can only enlarge the set of equilibria in general, only a subset of bilateral deviations qualify as valid. We start with a definition of bilateral proofness in our context, focusing directly on the strict version of this concept. Definition 4 A strategy profile s is a Strict Bilateral-Proof Equilibrium (SBPE) if the following conditions hold:. for any i N, and every s i S i such that g(s i, s i ) g(s ), Π i (s ) > Π i (s i, s i ); 2. For any pair of players i, j N, and every strategy pair (s i, s j ) with g(s i, s j, s i j ) g(s ) and Π i (s i, s j, s i j ) Π i(s i, s j, s i j ), one of the following two conditions hold: (a) Π j (s i, s j, s i j ) < Π j(s j, s j, s i j ) (b) k, l {i, j}, k l, and some s k S k, such that Π k ( s k, s l, s k l ) > Π k (s k, s l, s k l ). Most of the insights obtained in Section 3 through the SBE concept are maintained if we consider the the less demanding SBPE concept. (Note that SBPE requires valid bilateral deviations to be internally consistent, which can only enlarge the set of equilibria as compared with the SBE notion.) Indeed, reviewing the Propositions and Lemmata that underlie the proof of Theorem, it is straightforward to check that all of them continue to apply for the SBPE concept, except for Lemma 4 and Lemma 6. results in turn. We next address each of these First, Lemma 4 rules out that a single cycle involving all players may define a SBE network. This network architecture can no longer be ruled out as a SBPE network, as established by the next result. Proposition 4 Given any c > 0, there exists an n(c) such that for all n n(c), a cycle containing all players is a pcp-equilibria. 3 3 The stability of the cycle which is not minimal is an instance of the inefficiency discussed in Jackson (2003) where players will over-connect to avoid positional disadvantages. 22

23 Proof: In a cycle, all players are symmetrically located, so we need only consider the incentives for a typical player, say some player i. First note that the payoffs of player i in a cycle are (n )/2 2c. The payoffs from deleting both links are 0 and clearly for a given c, there is always a large enough n such that deleting both links is not optimal. Consider next the deviation of deleting one link. If player i deletes one link and keeps the other link as in the cycle then he becomes an end-player of the line network. In this network his payoffs is given by n k=2 The payoff from both links in cycle are higher if n 2 k c (9) n k=2 k > c (20) Clearly this inequality holds for large enough n. We next consider the deviation in which player i deletes both links but forms a new link (say) with the center of the line network that arises. Again, a variation of the above argument shows that for large n this reduces payoffs. We finally consider deviations by player i in which player i maintains one of the links as is but changes the partner of the other link. Suppose that in the cycle he has a link with i and i +. In the deviation, he maintains the link with i but deletes the link with i + and instead forms a link with some player k. If player k retains all his links as in the cycle, it is easy to see that the payoffs of the player go down strictly since the costs remain the same (he maintains two links) while the gross payoffs decline since player k is essential for accessing at least one player, namely i +. So this deviation is not profitable. If player k deletes both his links then the payoffs from the deviation are still lower and so it clearly not profitable. We turn to the final case, where players i and k coordinate and link up with each other but delete a link each so that the new network is a line. From Lemma 4 it follows that players such a deviation is profitable. However, now we need to check whether this deviation is credible: 23

24 do the players have an incentive to actually delete one of their links? We show that for large n, at least on the players has a strict incentive to retain their links in the cycle. Number the players in the line as, 2..., n, from left to right. So there are i players to the left of player i while there are n k players to the right of player k in the line. Suppose without loss of generality that i n k. Player k gets a payoff i+ l=2 /l in the line network from these players, 2..., i. The payoffs can be increased to i/2 if player k forms a link with player. Clearly, it is profitable for player k to deviate from the deviation and form a link with player, if n is large. It is similarly possible to show that player would have an incentive to form a link with player k, if n is large. Thus the deviation in which i and k deviate to create a line is not two-person coalition proof. Finally, we note that starting from a cycle it is not profitable for player i to form any additional links. The proof for cycle being a SBPE network is complete. Secondly, we note that the proof of Lemma 6 crucially depends on the fact that players are not allowed to deviate unilaterally from a bilateral deviation. (Specifically, observe that this proof contemplates a joint deviation by two players in the cycle that is not in the interest of any one of them, under the assumption that the other abides by it.) In fact, it is not difficult to construct examples where a full-fledged hybrid cycle-star network is SBPE for a large enough population. As a brief outline of matters, consider some such network where there are r nodes involved in the cycle. We know from the proof of Lemma 5 that, in order for such a configuration to be an equilibrium, it must be that r < 6c +. Under the latter inequality, it is clear that no (bilateral) deviation involving a player outside the cycle can be profitable for this player. Thus, we are left with deviations involving pairs of non-neighboring players in the the cycle, as those considered in the proof of Lemma 6. Let i and j be any such players. The only way in which they can gain is by attempting to become central. This must involve establishing a link between them and, simultaneously, destroying one of their respective links to the cycle. Now we argue that any such deviation is 24

25 not inmune to a unilateral omission by at least one of the players in her link deletion. By keeping her link, there is at least one of the players, say i, half of the players in the cycle without any intermediation costs. Thus, for large r, the gain Π i from retaining the link (assuming j abides by the deviation) can be approximated as follows: Π i r 2 2 ln r 2 c. Now suppose r = c/α for some α (/6, /4). Then, we have Π i > 0, while still maintaining the condition that r < 6c +. This confirms that, under high enough costs and a large population, there is a SBPE that supports a hybrid cycle-star network. The above discussion indicates that, under the requirement of bilateral proofness, a richer set of network architectures can be supported at equilibrium specifically, the cycle and a hybrid cycle-star network are also possible, in addition to full stars. Thus, in this sense, the force towards polarization that proved so acute under unqualified bilateral stability becomes mitigated when we insist that bilateral deviations be internally consistent. We now argue, however, that such alternative architectures (a cycle and a hybrid cycle-star) are, in effect, rather fragile. Specifically, they should not be expected to last under the pressure of occasional perturbations that affect some of the links. A natural way of formulating precisely this idea is to check the performance of some suitably modelled dynamics of adjustment under the pressure of ocassional random mutations. In what follows, we outline such a dynamic model and explain the gist of the argumen. While we dispense with the formal details, they are available from the authors upon request. Consider a dynamic process of bilateral adjustment in which, at every point in (discrete) time t =, 2,..., a pair of players is selected at random and are given the option to create a link between them (if this link is not already in place) and, simultaneously, destroy any subset of the existing links whose maintenance they control. In line with the considerations that underlie the SBPE concept, 25

26 let us suppose that, in evaluating any joint move by the two players involved in the adjustment, only those that are internally consistent are admitted as valid. That is, joint moves are only judged valid if they are inmune to a unilateral deviation (that, in this case, would always involve keeping a link that should otherwise be maintained under the contemplated move). In addition to this adjustment dynamics, suppose that there is also a slow dynamics of link decay. Specifically, postulate that, at (the end of) every t, each of the existing links vanishes with some probability ε, conceived as small. The dynamics just described may be parametrized by ε. If ε = 0, we simply have an adjustment dynamics, whose stationary points are SBPE networks these include cycle, hybrid cycle-star, or star networks, as well as the empty network if c > /2. Let us now ckeck the dynamic robustness of each of the non-empty architectures if one of the existing links, randomly selected, simply vanishes. The implicit assumption here is that such a perturbation is very infrequent so that no more than one instance of it may occur with significant probability before the adjustment dynamics restores the stationarity of the situation. Consider first the case of the cycle or a hybrid cycle-star. For concreteness, let us focus on the latter case, the (pure) cycle network, since the second one is analogous. Suppose that one of the links in the cycle vanishes. Then we argue that (if the population is large enough) there is chain of bilateral-proof adjustments that lead to the star, where the dynamics is eventually absorbed. After the deletion of the link, the resulting network is a line, and let players be indexed consecutively from one end to the other, i =, 2,..., n, with n odd for simplicity. Suppose that player n 3 2 (who is linked to player n 2 ) is given the option of linking to the central player in the line, n+ n 3 2. Player 2 is indifferent to do so (in which case she will delete the link to n n+ 2 ) but player 2 strictly benefits. This is the case for any c, provided n is large enough, and the entailed adjustment is bilateral-proof. Now we may proceed iteratively with players that are two steps apart from the central player in the current network (e.g. either player n 5 2 or n+3 2 at the next iteration) until a star centered at player n+ 2 is 26

Structural holes in social networks

Structural holes in social networks Structural holes in social networks Sanjeev Goyal Fernando Vega-Redondo This version: January 005 Abstract We consider a setting where every pair of players that interact (e.g. exchange goods or information)

More information

MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS

MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS JAN-PETER SIEDLAREK ABSTRACT. Economic and social networks often combine high levels of clustering with short distances between pairs of agents.

More information

Departament d Economia Aplicada, Universitat de les Illes Balears, Campus UIB, Palma de Mallorca, Spain;

Departament d Economia Aplicada, Universitat de les Illes Balears, Campus UIB, Palma de Mallorca, Spain; games Article Structural Holes in Social Networks with Exogenous Cliques Antoni Rubí-Barceló ID Departament d Economia Aplicada, Universitat de les Illes Balears, Campus UIB, 0722 Palma de Mallorca, Spain;

More information

No THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION. By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi. May 2003 ISSN

No THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION. By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi. May 2003 ISSN No. 2003 53 THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi May 2003 ISSN 0924-7815 The Role of Trust in Costly Network Formation Robert P. Gilles Sudipta Sarangi

More information

An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks. Lecture 4, Part II

An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks. Lecture 4, Part II An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks Lecture 4, Part II Michael D Ko nig University of Zurich Department of Economics 12 13 June 2017 Outline Strategic Network Formation Pairwise Stability Nash

More information

6 Evolution of Networks

6 Evolution of Networks last revised: March 2008 WARNING for Soc 376 students: This draft adopts the demography convention for transition matrices (i.e., transitions from column to row). 6 Evolution of Networks 6. Strategic network

More information

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models pascal billand a, christophe bravard a, sudipta sarangi b a CREUSET, Jean Monnet University, Saint-Etienne, France. email: pascal.billand@univ-st-etienne.fr

More information

TI /1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper One-way Flow Networks: the Role of Heterogeneity. Andrea Galeotti. Institute.

TI /1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper One-way Flow Networks: the Role of Heterogeneity. Andrea Galeotti. Institute. TI 2004-031/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper One-way Flow Networks: the Role of Heterogeneity Andrea Galeotti Econometric Institute, Faculty of Economics, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, and Tinbergen

More information

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden 1 Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning Jason R. Marden Abstract A learning rule is completely uncoupled if each player s behavior is conditioned only on his own realized

More information

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models pascal billand a, christophe bravard b, sudipta sarangi c a CREUSET, Jean Monnet University, Saint-Etienne, France. email: pascal.billand@univ-st-etienne.fr

More information

Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model

Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model Omid Atabati 1 and Babak Farzad 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Calgary, Calgary, AB T2N 1N4, Canada oatabati@ucalgary.ca 2 Department

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Undirected Networks

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Undirected Networks DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Undirected Networks Pascal Billand Gate, Jean Monnet University Christophe Bravard Gate, Jean Monnet University

More information

On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Two-way Flow Models*

On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Two-way Flow Models* On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Two-way Flow Models* pascal billand a, christophe bravard a, sudipta sarangi b a Université de Lyon, Lyon, F-69003, France ; Université Jean Monnet,

More information

Heterogeneity in Nash Networks*

Heterogeneity in Nash Networks* Heterogeneity in Nash Networks* pascal billand a, christophe bravard a, sudipta sarangi b a CREUSET, Jean Monnet University, Saint-Etienne, France. email: pascal.billand@univst-etienne.fr, christophe.bravard@univ-st-etienne.fr

More information

1 Introduction In recent years, several authors have examined the role of interaction structure different terms like network structure, neighborhood i

1 Introduction In recent years, several authors have examined the role of interaction structure different terms like network structure, neighborhood i Learning, Network Formation and Coordination Sanjeev Goyal Λ Fernando Vega-Redondo y Econometric Institute Report 9954/A. November 1999.This version: December 10th, 1999. Abstract In many economic and

More information

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Mariagiovanna Baccara Leeat Yariv August 19, 2012 1 Introduction In this Appendix we study the information sharing application analyzed

More information

Tilburg University. Social Network Formation with Consent Gilles, R.P.; Sarangi, S. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Social Network Formation with Consent Gilles, R.P.; Sarangi, S. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Social Network Formation with Consent Gilles, R.P.; Sarangi, S. Publication date: 2004 Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Gilles, R. P., & Sarangi, S. (2004).

More information

FROM BILATERAL TWO-WAY TO UNILATERAL ONE-WAY FLOW LINK-FORMATION

FROM BILATERAL TWO-WAY TO UNILATERAL ONE-WAY FLOW LINK-FORMATION FROM BLATERAL TWO-WAY TO UNLATERAL ONE-WAY FLOW LNK-FORMATON by Norma Olaizola and Federico Valenciano 2014 Working Paper Series: L. 83/14 Departamento de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico Ekonomi Analisiaren

More information

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly Frédéric DEROÏAN FORUM Abstract In a vertically differentiated oligopoly, firms raise cost reducing alliances before competing with

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Heterogeneity and Link Imperfections in Nash Networks. Pascal Billand Jean Monnet University

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Heterogeneity and Link Imperfections in Nash Networks. Pascal Billand Jean Monnet University DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Heterogeneity and Link Imperfections in Nash Networks Pascal Billand Jean Monnet University Christophe Bravard Jean Monnet University Sudipta Sarangi Louisiana

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Modeling Resource Flow Asymmetries using Condensation Networks

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Modeling Resource Flow Asymmetries using Condensation Networks DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Modeling Resource Flow Asymmetries using Condensation Networks Pascal Billand Universite de Lyon, Universite Jean Monnet & CNRS, GATE Lyon St. Etienne Christophe

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models. Pascal Billand CREUSET, Jean Monnet University

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models. Pascal Billand CREUSET, Jean Monnet University DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models Pascal Billand CREUSET, Jean Monnet University Christophe Bravard CREUSET, Jean Monnet University Sudipta

More information

Contractually Stable Networks

Contractually Stable Networks Contractually Stable Networks (very preliminary version) Jean-François Caulier CEREC, FUSL Jose Sempere-Monerris University of Valencia Ana Mauleon FNRS and CEREC, FUSL and CORE, UCL Vincent Vannetelbosch

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

A model of Myerson-Nash equilibria in networks

A model of Myerson-Nash equilibria in networks A model of Myerson-Nash equilibria in networks Paolo Pin 1 Dipartimento di Economia - Universitá Ca Foscari di Venezia Cannaregio 873-3011 Venezia pin@unive.it Summary. The paper studies network formation

More information

EFFICIENT PARTNERSHIP FORMATION IN NETWORKS

EFFICIENT PARTNERSHIP FORMATION IN NETWORKS EFFICIENT PARTNERSHIP FORMATION IN NETWORKS FRANCIS BLOCH, BHASKAR DUTTA, AND MIHAI MANEA Abstract. We analyze the formation of partnerships in social networks. Players need favors at random times and

More information

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts Advanced Microeconomic Theory: Economics 521b Spring 2011 Juuso Välimäki Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts The setup is similar to that of a Bayesian game. The ingredients are: 1. Set of players, i {1,

More information

Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation

Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation Elliot Anshelevich and Bugra Caskurlu Computer Science Department, RPI, 110 8th Street, Troy, NY 12180 {eanshel,caskub}@cs.rpi.edu Abstract.

More information

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency Subhadip Chakrabarti and Supanit Tangsangasaksri Queen s University Management School, Queen s University

More information

Building Social Networks

Building Social Networks Building Social Networks Robert P. Gilles Sudipta Sarangi May 2006 Abstract We examine the process of building social relationships as a non-cooperative game that requires mutual consent and involves reaching

More information

Price of Stability in Survivable Network Design

Price of Stability in Survivable Network Design Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Price of Stability in Survivable Network Design Elliot Anshelevich Bugra Caskurlu Received: January 2010 / Accepted: Abstract We study the survivable

More information

INFORMATION AS PUBLIC GOOD IN NETWORKS

INFORMATION AS PUBLIC GOOD IN NETWORKS INFORMATION AS PUBLIC GOOD IN NETWORKS PAPIYA GHOSH AND RAJENDRA P. KUNDU Abstract. The importance of understanding individual and collective human behaviour in designing various schemes and programmes

More information

An axiomatic characterization of the position value for network situations

An axiomatic characterization of the position value for network situations An axiomatic characterization of the position value for network situations Anne van den Nouweland Marco Slikker September 22, 2011 Abstract Network situations as introduced by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996)

More information

Confirming Information Flows in Networks

Confirming Information Flows in Networks TI 2012-019/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Confirming Information Flows in Networks Pascal Billand 1 Christophe Bravard 1 Jurjen Kamphorst 2 Sudipta Sarangi 3 1 Université de Lyon, Université Jean

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari and Mohsen Mosleh and Kia Dalili School of Systems and Enterprises, Stevens Institute

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India November 2007

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India November 2007 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India November 2007 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY 6. Other Solution Concepts Note:

More information

The formation of partnerships in social networks

The formation of partnerships in social networks The formation of partnerships in social networks Francis Bloch Bhaskar Dutta Stéphane Robin Min Zhu September 12, 2016 Abstract This paper analyzes the formation of partnerships in social networks. Agents

More information

Network formation and anti-coordination games

Network formation and anti-coordination games Int J Game Theory (2004) 33: 1 19 DOI 10.1007/s001820400178 Network formation and anti-coordination games Yann Bramoulle y, Dunia Lo pez-pintado z, Sanjeev Goyal x and Fernando Vega-Redondo { y LEERNA,

More information

A Unifying Model of Strategic Network Formation

A Unifying Model of Strategic Network Formation A Unifying Model of Strategic Network Formation By Norma Olaizola y and Federico Valenciano z March 26, 2015 Abstract We provide a model that merges two basic models of strategic network formation and

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

Volume 31, Issue 3. Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal

Volume 31, Issue 3. Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal Volume 31, Issue 3 Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal Ali Kakhbod University of Michigan, Ann Arbor Demosthenis Teneketzis University of Michigan, Ann Arbor Abstract Within the context

More information

Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal

Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal Ali Kakhbod Demosthenis Teneketzis November 13, 2017 arxiv:1001.3896v4 [cs.gt] 9 Feb 2012 Abstract Within the context of games on networks S. Goyal

More information

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks Gizem Korkmaz European University Institute December, 2011 Market Sharing Agreements In recent years, the scope for explicit or implicit market sharing agreements

More information

A hierarchical network formation model

A hierarchical network formation model Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Electronic Notes in Discrete Mathematics 50 (2015) 379 384 www.elsevier.com/locate/endm A hierarchical network formation model Omid Atabati a,1 Babak Farzad b,2

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari a, Mohsen Mosleh a, Kia Dalili b arxiv:1504.06634v3 [q-fin.ec] 11 Dec 2015 a School of Systems and Enterprises,

More information

Bargaining in Global Communication Networks

Bargaining in Global Communication Networks Bargaining in Global Communication Networks Abstract We study a Rubinstein-Stahl two-player non-cooperative bargaining game played by n players connected in a communication network. We allow the players

More information

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies 1 Shaun Lichter, Terry Friesz, and Christopher Griffin arxiv:1108.4114v1 [math.oc] 20 Aug 2011 Abstract Recently, it has been shown that networks

More information

Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation

Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation Noname manuscript No. will be inserted by the editor) Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation Elliot Anshelevich Bugra Caskurlu Received: December 2009 / Accepted: Abstract

More information

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 David Pérez-Castrillo 2 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona David Wettstein 3 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev April 2005 1 We gratefully

More information

Time allocation in friendship networks

Time allocation in friendship networks Time allocation in friendship networks Leonie Baumann 14th December 2014 I am grateful to Arno Apffelstaedt, Berno Büchel, Henning Bruhn-Fujimoto, Anke Gerber, Matthew Jackson, Ariel Rubinstein, Asher

More information

The Stability and Eciency of Directed. Communication Networks. Bhaskar Dutta and Matthew O. Jackson. Revision: February 20, 2000.

The Stability and Eciency of Directed. Communication Networks. Bhaskar Dutta and Matthew O. Jackson. Revision: February 20, 2000. The Stability and Eciency of Directed Communication Networks Bhaskar Dutta and Matthew O. Jackson Revision: February 20, 2000 Forthcoming in the Review of Economic Design Abstract This paper analyzes the

More information

An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set

An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set By Parkash Chander * May 2015 Revised: November 2015 Abstract In this paper, we first introduce and characterize a new and general concept of a credible deviation in

More information

Inequality and Network Structure

Inequality and Network Structure Inequality and Network Structure Garud Iyengar Willemien Kets Rajiv Sethi Sam Bowles SFI WORKING PAPER: 2008-08-034 SFI Working Papers contain accounts of scientific work of the author(s) and do not necessarily

More information

Weak Dominance and Never Best Responses

Weak Dominance and Never Best Responses Chapter 4 Weak Dominance and Never Best Responses Let us return now to our analysis of an arbitrary strategic game G := (S 1,...,S n, p 1,...,p n ). Let s i, s i be strategies of player i. We say that

More information

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * by Magnus Hatlebakk ** Department of Economics, University of Bergen Abstract: We present a new subgame perfect equilibrium

More information

Decentralized bargaining in matching markets: online appendix

Decentralized bargaining in matching markets: online appendix Decentralized bargaining in matching markets: online appendix Matt Elliott and Francesco Nava March 2018 Abstract The online appendix discusses: MPE multiplicity; the non-generic cases of core-match multiplicity

More information

Entropic Selection of Nash Equilibrium

Entropic Selection of Nash Equilibrium Entropic Selection of Nash Equilibrium Zeynel Harun Alioğulları Mehmet Barlo February, 2012 Abstract This study argues that Nash equilibria with less variations in players best responses are more appealing.

More information

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication)

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Nikolaus Robalino and Arthur Robson Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 2 This appendix contains the proof of Theorem

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen Strategic Form Games In this part we will analyze games in which the players choose their actions simultaneously (or without the knowledge of other players

More information

Treading a Fine Line : (Im)possibil Title Implementation with Partially-hones. Author(s) Lombardi, Michele; Yoshihara, Naoki

Treading a Fine Line : (Im)possibil Title Implementation with Partially-hones. Author(s) Lombardi, Michele; Yoshihara, Naoki Treading a Fine Line : (Im)possibil Title Implementation with Partially-hones Author(s) Lombardi, Michele; Yoshihara, Naoki Citation Issue 2016-08 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL

More information

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013 SF2972 Game Theory Exam with s March 5, 203 Part A Classical Game Theory Jörgen Weibull and Mark Voorneveld. (a) What are N, S and u in the definition of a finite normal-form (or, equivalently, strategic-form)

More information

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games International Journal of Mathematics and Soft Computing Vol.5, No.2 (2015), 197-212. ISSN Print : 2249-3328 ISSN Online: 2319-5215 Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

More information

Other-Regarding Preferences: Theory and Evidence

Other-Regarding Preferences: Theory and Evidence Other-Regarding Preferences: Theory and Evidence June 9, 2009 GENERAL OUTLINE Economic Rationality is Individual Optimization and Group Equilibrium Narrow version: Restrictive Assumptions about Objective

More information

CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash

CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash Equilibrium Price of Stability Coping With NP-Hardness

More information

Job Contact Networks JET Antoni Calvó-Armengol

Job Contact Networks JET Antoni Calvó-Armengol Job Contact Networks JET 2004 Antoni Calvó-Armengol About half of jobs are filled through contacts networks of personal contacts and word-of-mouth communication play a central role in many labor markets

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

The Efficiency and Evolution of R&D Networks

The Efficiency and Evolution of R&D Networks The Efficiency and Evolution of R&D Networks DRAFT Please do not distribute nor quote without permission of the authors. M.D. König a S. Battiston a M. Napoletano a,b F. Schweitzer a a Chair of Systems

More information

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem MS&E 336 Lecture 8: Supermodular games Ramesh Johari April 30, 2007 In this lecture, we develop the theory of supermodular games; key references are the papers of Topkis [7], Vives [8], and Milgrom and

More information

Opting Out in a War of Attrition. Abstract

Opting Out in a War of Attrition. Abstract Opting Out in a War of Attrition Mercedes Adamuz Department of Business, Instituto Tecnológico Autónomo de México and Department of Economics, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Abstract This paper analyzes

More information

Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies

Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman February 2006 (revised March 2007) Abstract We consider two-sided markets with a continuum of agents and a finite

More information

Introduction Benchmark model Belief-based model Empirical analysis Summary. Riot Networks. Lachlan Deer Michael D. König Fernando Vega-Redondo

Introduction Benchmark model Belief-based model Empirical analysis Summary. Riot Networks. Lachlan Deer Michael D. König Fernando Vega-Redondo Riot Networks Lachlan Deer Michael D. König Fernando Vega-Redondo University of Zurich University of Zurich Bocconi University June 7, 2018 Deer & König &Vega-Redondo Riot Networks June 7, 2018 1 / 23

More information

BARGAINING AND EFFICIENCY IN NETWORKS

BARGAINING AND EFFICIENCY IN NETWORKS BARGAINING AND EFFICIENCY IN NETWORKS DILIP ABREU AND MIHAI MANEA Department of Economics, Princeton University, dabreu@princeton.edu Department of Economics, Harvard University, mmanea@fas.harvard.edu

More information

Endogenous Formation of Multiple Social Groups

Endogenous Formation of Multiple Social Groups Endogenous Formation of Multiple Social Groups Ngoc Minh Nguyen Lionel Richefort Thomas Vallée LEMNA - University of Nantes March 23, 2018 Abstract In this paper, we propose a model of group formation

More information

Housing Markets with Indifferences: a Tale of Two Mechanisms

Housing Markets with Indifferences: a Tale of Two Mechanisms Housing Markets with Indifferences: a Tale of Two Mechanisms Haris Aziz, Bart de Keijzer Institut für Informatik, Technische Universität München, 80538 München, Germany CWI Amsterdam, 1098 XG Amsterdam,

More information

Multiple Equilibria in the Citizen-Candidate Model of Representative Democracy.

Multiple Equilibria in the Citizen-Candidate Model of Representative Democracy. Multiple Equilibria in the Citizen-Candidate Model of Representative Democracy. Amrita Dhillon and Ben Lockwood This version: March 2001 Abstract De Sinopoli and Turrini (1999) present an example to show

More information

On the existence of Pairwise stable weighted networks

On the existence of Pairwise stable weighted networks On the existence of Pairwise stable weighted networks Philippe Bich, Lisa Morhaim To cite this version: Philippe Bich, Lisa Morhaim. On the existence of Pairwise stable weighted networks. 017.

More information

Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games

Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games Willemien Kets October 12, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the robustness of symmetric equilibria in anonymous local games to perturbations of prior beliefs.

More information

A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects

A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects Herbert Hamers a Flip Klijn b Marco Slikker c Bas van Velzen d September 2004 Abstract We consider the allocation of a finite number of

More information

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA MARIA GOLTSMAN Abstract. This note shows that, in separable environments, any monotonic social choice function

More information

On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks

On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks Philippe Bich and Lisa Morhaim Monday 4 th July, 017 Abstract We provide the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks under assumptions similar

More information

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints Gagan Ghosh Bingchao Huangfu Heng Liu October 19, 2017 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: COMMENTS WELCOME) Abstract We study wars of attrition between two bidders who

More information

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017 Supplementary Materials for Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games Jin Yeub Kim Myungkyu Shim March 10, 017 Abstract In Online Appendix A, we examine the conditions under which dispersion

More information

Efficient Random Assignment with Cardinal and Ordinal Preferences: Online Appendix

Efficient Random Assignment with Cardinal and Ordinal Preferences: Online Appendix Efficient Random Assignment with Cardinal and Ordinal Preferences: Online Appendix James C. D. Fisher December 11, 2018 1 1 Introduction This document collects several results, which supplement those in

More information

Incentives to form the grand coalition versus no incentive to split off from the grand coalition

Incentives to form the grand coalition versus no incentive to split off from the grand coalition Incentives to form the grand coalition versus no incentive to split off from the grand coalition Katsushige FUJIMOTO College of Symbiotic Systems Science, Fukushima University, 1 Kanayagawa Fukushima,

More information

STOCHASTIC STABILITY OF GROUP FORMATION IN COLLECTIVE ACTION GAMES. Toshimasa Maruta 1 and Akira Okada 2

STOCHASTIC STABILITY OF GROUP FORMATION IN COLLECTIVE ACTION GAMES. Toshimasa Maruta 1 and Akira Okada 2 STOCHASTIC STABILITY OF GROUP FORMATION IN COLLECTIVE ACTION GAMES Toshimasa Maruta 1 and Akira Okada 2 December 20, 2001 We present a game theoretic model of voluntary group formation in collective action

More information

Networks: Theory and Applications. by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University)

Networks: Theory and Applications. by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University) Networks: Theory and Applications by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University) General description It has been recognized for a long time that non-market interactions, i.e. interactions between agents that are

More information

Supplementary appendix to the paper Hierarchical cheap talk Not for publication

Supplementary appendix to the paper Hierarchical cheap talk Not for publication Supplementary appendix to the paper Hierarchical cheap talk Not for publication Attila Ambrus, Eduardo M. Azevedo, and Yuichiro Kamada December 3, 011 1 Monotonicity of the set of pure-strategy equilibria

More information

Stability of Jurisdiction Structures under the Equal Share and Median Rules

Stability of Jurisdiction Structures under the Equal Share and Median Rules Stability of Jurisdiction Structures under the Equal Share and Median Rules Anna Bogomolnaia Michel Le Breton Alexei Savvateev Shlomo Weber April 2005 Abstract In this paper we consider a model with multiple

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT November 4, 2009 1 Introduction Outline The role of networks in cooperation A model of social norms

More information

5.2 A characterization of the nonemptiness of the core

5.2 A characterization of the nonemptiness of the core Computational Aspects of Game Theory Bertinoro Spring School Lecturer: Bruno Codenotti Lecture 5: The Core of Cooperative Games The core is by far the cooperative solution concept most used in Economic

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Introduction to Game

More information

Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend?

Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend? Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend? Antonio Cabrales, Antoni Calvó-Armengol, Yves Zenou January 06 Summary Introduction The game Equilibrium

More information

The formation of partnerships in social networks

The formation of partnerships in social networks The formation of partnerships in social networks Francis Bloch Bhaskar Dutta Stéphane Robin Min Zhu January 2, 2017 Abstract This paper analyzes the formation of partnerships in social networks. Agents

More information

Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation (Supporting Information)

Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation (Supporting Information) Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation Supporting Information Ankur Mani 1, Iyad Rahwan 1,2, Alex Sandy Pentland 1 1 MIT, 2 Masdar Institute 1 Model of Externalities Consider a set of agents, N,

More information

Network Formation: Bilateral Contracting and Myopic Dynamics

Network Formation: Bilateral Contracting and Myopic Dynamics Network Formation: Bilateral Contracting and Myopic Dynamics Esteban Arcaute 1, Ramesh Johari 2, and Shie Mannor 3 1 Institute for Computational and Mathematical Engineering, Stanford University. arcaute@stanford.edu

More information

Mutual Insurance Networks in Communities

Mutual Insurance Networks in Communities Mutual Insurance Networks in Communities Pascal Billand a, Christophe Bravard b, Sudipta Sarangi c December 19, 2012 a Université de Lyon, Lyon, F-69007, France ; CNRS, GATE Lyon Saint-Etienne, Ecully,

More information

Observations on Cooperation

Observations on Cooperation Introduction Observations on Cooperation Yuval Heller (Bar Ilan) and Erik Mohlin (Lund) PhD Workshop, BIU, January, 2018 Heller & Mohlin Observations on Cooperation 1 / 20 Introduction Motivating Example

More information

Communication Networks with Endogeneous Link Strength

Communication Networks with Endogeneous Link Strength Communication Networks with Endogeneous Link Strength Francis Bloch, Bhaskar Dutta y April 1, 2005 Abstract This paper analyzes the formation of communication networks when players choose endogenously

More information