An empirical study of regional convergence, inequality, and spatial dependence in the enlarged European Union

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An empirical study of regional convergence, inequality, and spatial dependence in the enlarged European Union"

Transcription

1 An empirical study of regional convergence, inequality, and spatial dependence in the enlarged European Union John Källström August, 2012 NEKN01, Master Thesis I Department of Economics, Lund University Supervisor: Joakim Gullstrand

2 Abstract This thesis deals with regional convergence and the spatial dynamics of regional incomes in the enlarged EU. The aim is to build on prior work in the field, to investigate convergence dynamics of regions in the newest EU member states and to look at the importance of country and spatial effects in the convergence process. Examining per-capita income growth among 1309 NUTS 3- regions across the EU over , very slow rates of both β- and σ-convergence is found. Spatial data analysis reveals strong spatial dependence and clustering of regional incomes and growth rates across EU regions. By spatial econometric methods it is found that the spatial dependence in the convergence process is mainly contained to regions within the same country. Thus, regional growth spillovers seem to a large extent stop at country borders. Moreover, convergence in the old member states over the sample period is found to be mainly due to growth among low-income regions. Conversely, no significant convergence can be found among the newest member states. Rather these countries show evidence for increasing income inequality. This is found to be mainly attributed to increasing within-country regional income disparities. Keywords: regional income inequality, β-convergence, σ-convergence, spatial econometrics, exploratory spatial data analysis, spatial dependence, European Union. 1

3 Table of contents 1. Introduction Theoretical foundation Neoclassical theory and regional convergence Neoclassical convergence hypotheses Spatial dependence in the neoclassical setting Endogenous growth and new economic geography New economic geography Agglomeration and regional growth Methodological aspects β-convergence Spatial dependence Nuisance spatial dependence Substantive spatial dependence Prior research The regression approach Spatial dependence and regional convergence The distributional approach Data Analysis The regional income distribution Inequality patterns Transition dynamics Polarization patterns Exploratory spatial data analysis Global spatial autocorrelation Local spatial autocorrelation Regression results

4 OLS-estimations Spatial econometric estimations Conclusions References Appendix I Appendix II Appendix III Appendix IV List of figures 6.1. Entropy indices, EU Share of between- and within-country component of regional inequality, EU Entropy indices, EU Share of between- and within-country component of regional inequality, EU Entropy indices, NMS Share of between- and within-country components of regional inequality, NMS Density function for EU28 relative per-capita GRP 1995 and Density function for EU15 relative per-capita GRP 1995 and Density function for NMS relative per-capita GRP 1995 and Moran scatterplot per-capita GRP 1995, EU Moran scatterplot growth rates , EU Local spatial autocorrelation per-capita GRP 1995, EU Local spatial autocorrelations growth rates , EU List of tables 6.1. Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , EU Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , EU Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , NMS Moran s I-test of global spatial autocorrelation, EU OLS estimation, SEM estimation, SLM estimation,

5 1. Introduction The entry of ten new member states 1, many from the former Soviet bloc, into the EU in 2004 meant that income disparities doubled in the union. The average per-capita incomes of the new member states (NMS) amounted to about 50% of the old members (Niebuhr and Schlitte 2004). In 2007 two additional former Eastern bloc countries Romania and Bulgaria with a below average incomes joined the union. Thus, between-country inequalities in the enlarged EU are large. However, income disparities are even larger within countries than between. For example, in 2009 West Inner-City London, in the United Kingdoms, had a per-capita gross regional product (GRP) of measured in Purchasing Power Standard (PPS). This amounts the highest per-capita income in the union, about six times the EU average. At the same time, the region of Vaslui in Romania had a GRP per capita of 5500 PPS, about one fourth of the EU average. Thus, regional inequalities within EU-countries are even more pronounced than between. However, if the disparities are growing or if poorer regions are catching up, converging, to the richer ones is a more debatable issue. Many theoretical and empirical contributions stress the importance of economic integration in reducing economic inequality. For example, neoclassical theory predicts that intensified economic integration will lead to poorer regions converging to richer ones. In this view, decreased trade barriers facilitate the equalization of factor returns and proportions and technological diffusion, which in turn contributes to capital deepening and technological growth and thus to per-capita income growth. On the other hand, insights from endogenous growth models and new economic geography show that regional convergence need not be a definite outcome of economic integration and that geographical location matter for economic outcome. Instead these views stress that integration allows economic activity to cluster by agglomerative and cumulative processes driven by externalities with a strong spatial dimension. As a result, the geographical distribution of economic activity is spatially dependent and persistent: regions with low (high) incomes are surrounded by other regions with low (high) incomes and tend to remain so over time. Following Ertur et al. (2006), a couple of stylized facts on regional convergence in Europe can be drawn from the empirical literature. First, the convergence rate seems to be very slow among European regions. Second, regional income disparities seem persistent despite the ongoing integration process. To this can be added that the regional income disparities in Europe show a distinct and persistent geographical core-periphery pattern (see e.g. Bräuninger and Niebuhr 1 Cyprus, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia 4

6 2005; Fischer and Stirböck 2006; Battisti and Di Vaio 2008). That is to say, poor and regions are clustered in space with other poor regions and rich with other rich regions. Investigating convergence and spatial interaction between regions is of great importance if the European integration process is to be fully understood. Are poorer regions catching-up to richer ones and how is the ongoing European integration process affecting this? Are incomes in the NMS catching up to the old pre-2004 members (EU15)? In light of the suggested importance of geography, how important is regional neighborhood compared to country for determining the convergence process of EU regions? That is, do spatial dependence matter more for a regions growth performance than country effects? All these questions have large policy implications. Particularly as one of the stated goals of the EU, stated in both the Maastricht-treaty and Single Market act, is increased regional income cohesion. However, how well the EU work to foster this process is debatable. This thesis hopes to bring some clarity and new insights to this area. Early studies of regional convergence failed to explicitly account for spatial dependence, instead treating each region as separate units. However, recent developments in spatial econometrics allow regional spatial interactions to be accounted for. Moreover, critique against conventional convergence analysis based on cross-section regressions stress that to fully appreciate if convergence is accompanied with lessened inequality the dynamics of the entire income distribution must be taken into account (see e.g. Quah 1993a, 1993b). In light of these results, this thesis will investigate the link between agglomeration, spatial spillovers, and growth in the context of European regions taking both a parametric spatial econometric approach and a nonparametric distributional approach. Most previous studies focus on either the one or the other approach. But this thesis argues that to get the full picture of regional income convergence both traditional regression analyses and distributional analysis should be accounted for. The thesis has three aims. First, it builds and extends on the prior work in the field of regional income convergence and spatial dependence. This is done by employing a comparably larger cross-section of European regions over the period In addition, the regional data is at a lower geographical aggregation level than what has commonly been used in previous studies. Following the discussion above, complementary to the traditional regression analysis a distributional analysis of regional incomes will also be performed. Second, the thesis aims at identifying differences in the convergence dynamics among regions in the new and old member states. This is done to investigate if the NMS are converging to the EU-average. This can be viewed as an implicit way to investigate if joining the EU facilitates convergence among poorer regions. Third, the aim is to tentatively appraise if spatial dependence in the convergence processes in the EU mainly is a national or neighborhood phenomenon. Previously, Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008) and Bräuningen and Niebuhr (2005) among others have shown the 5

7 importance of country-specific effects in the regional convergence process of Europe, a similar analysis will be carried out here. If spatial dependence and clustering is found to mainly be an outcome determined by neighborhood this could be viewed as implicit evidence that agglomeration economies brought on by the European integration process is more important than national characteristics in creating clusters of economic activity. Thus, the thesis could be viewed as an evaluation of the extent of integration forces and their effect on regional income convergence in the EU. As mentioned above, increased regional cohesion is one of the main pillars of the European integration so evaluating this process has important policy implications. Moreover, since the eastward expansion of the EU, income disparities within the union have increased markedly. Hence, to evaluate if incomes in the NMS are growing should be of outmost importance. The disposition of the thesis is as follows. In chapter 2 the theoretical foundations underlying the notion of regional convergence and spatial dependence are stated. Following this in chapter 3 some methodological aspects of the convergence analysis and spatial dependence are covered. In chapter 4 a description of the current state of research is given. Next, in chapter 5, the employed dataset is discussed. Then, in chapter 6, the empirical analysis of the thesis is given. First, a distributional analysis is preformed to account to for regional income disparities. Second, the data is described by means of spatial data analysis. Third, the rate of regional convergence and the importance of spatial- and country-effects is estimated by means of a spatial econometric analysis. Lastly, in chapter 7, the main findings are summarized and some concluding remarks, policy implications and suggestions for future research are given. 2. Theoretical foundation The theoretical predictions on the effects of economic integration on regional income convergence are varied. The neoclassical theory predict that as trade barriers between countries and regions fall the returns to factors equalize, which will lead to income convergence and decreasing disparities. On the other hand, in the so called endogenous growth models and in new economic geography (NEG), integration need not bring about convergence. Instead, it can result in increased regional income disparities and divergent growth trends Neoclassical theory and regional convergence Neoclassical growth provides a rationale for economic integration resulting in regional percapita income convergence. Following Magrini (2004) and Aghion and Howitt (2004), in this set of models, growth is determined by the marginal productivity of production factors, e.g. capital or labor, and the exogenous given technological growth rate. 6

8 Neoclassical convergence hypotheses In neoclassic models, economic integration fosters trade and factor mobility, which in turn fosters income convergence. The prediction of convergence in the neoclassical setting comes from the assumption of diminishing returns to production factors. This implies that economies with a relative scarce endowment of a specific factor will have a higher marginal return to this factor. Typically it is assumed that economies with a relatively low capital-labor ratio will have a lower per-capita output, but higher growth rate, as a lower capital stock means higher marginal productivity and returns to capital (Magrini 2004: p.2745). So, increasing trade or the mobility of factors leads to faster equalization of both factor proportions and returns. That is to say, poorer (low capital-labor ratio) economies will grow faster than richer (higher capital-labor ratio), eventually catching up with these. In the long run all regions will be at the same incomelevel and grow at the exogenous given rate of technological progress. This state is referred to as the steady state of the economy. The prediction that the only thing separating rich economies from poor is the capital stock and that poorer economies eventually will catch-up with their richer counterparts when enough capital has been accumulated is known as the unconditional convergence hypothesis. On the other hand, convergence in income levels or growth rates conditioned on the underlying structural characteristics of an economy or differences in production technologies is known as the conditional convergence hypothesis (Aghion and Howitt 2004: p.56). According to the conditional convergence hypothesis economies with different factor endowment, preferences technology, institutions etc. will converge to different steady-states. Moreover, if groups (clubs) of economies with similar characteristic converge to the same per-capita income-level and growth rate in the long-run, conditional converge is often referred to as club-convergence. Note that there need be no convergence between clubs (Martin 2001). Explanations for regional club-convergence range from the endowment of a wide range of production factors (e.g. human capital formation, public infrastructure, R&D activity) to local preferences or government policies (Canova 2004). Moreover, as Bräuninger and Niebuhr (2004) point out, the club-convergence hypothesis provides an rationale for the influence of national policies, legislation etc. on the regional convergence-process. Thus from this perspective, country-specific effects are expected to be a very influential factor in the regional convergence process Spatial dependence in the neoclassical setting One of the conditions for unconditional income convergence is evenly spread technology. This is arguably a rather strong assumption. As is argued in this thesis and others, regional incomes 7

9 appear to be strikingly unevenly distributed and geographical location seems to matters for economic outcome. López-Bazo et al. (2004), Egger and Pfaffermayr (2006) and Ertur and Koch (2007) all present examples of neoclassical models that take geographical location into account and shows how spatial interaction can affect the growth and convergence process. Specifically, they assume regional interdependence through spatially-bounded externalities in (human or physical) capital accumulation. Generally, the implication stemming from accounting for regional interdependence is that economies need no longer perfectly share technology. In turn this implies that a region s capital accumulation now also depends on the capital accumulation of its neighbors. In a neoclassic setting this gives that economic activity and incomes no longer need to be evenly distributed. As for example Fischer and Stirböck (2006: pp.694-5) argues, if such interdependence is bounded geographically they can give rise to convergence clubs conditioned on spatial neighborhoods. From López-Bazo et al. (2004), Egger and Pfaffermayr (2006) and Ertur and Koch (2007), a few general conclusions from considering spatial externalities in capital accumulation can be drawn. First, technological diffusion has a positive effect on the capital intensity of a region. From the assumption of diminishing returns to capital, the rate of investment in physical and human capital is still a decreasing function of the internal capital stock, but now an increasing function of the external capital stock of neighbors. This relationship gives that the investment and accumulation of physical and human capital will be higher in those regions surrounded by other regions with relatively large capital stocks. Secondly, the models give that the growth rate still is inversely related to the internal capital intensity, but that it now also depends on the productivity and growth rates of neighbors, which can counteract the internal diminishing returns. This implies that the growth rates of two economies with identical internal characteristics can still differ if they have different neighbors. Thirdly, the rate of convergence could either be slowed down or spurred on by growth spillovers from neighboring regions. Hence, by considering technological interdependence between regions a heterogeneous spatial distribution of both income levels and growth rates can be explained. Neighborhoods of capitalintensive regions with high incomes and low growth rates are geographically clustered because of spatial externalities in capital accumulation. Of course the opposite holds for neighborhoods of low capital-intensity, low incomes and high growth rates. Note how extending the neoclassical setting to account for spatial spillovers does not change the basic prediction of neoclassic theory. That is, capital-scarce economies exhibit higher growth rates than capital-intensive economies and eventually catch up to these. Instead, the extensions give what could be called a geographical conditional-convergence hypothesis, where the neighborhood dictates the steady state and growth path of a region. Neighborhoods of similar regions will then converge to the 8

10 same steady state. Thus, as argued by López-Bazo et al. (2004: p.44), even and uneven economic development is possible and depends on the relative strength of returns both internal to the economy and external spillovers from neighbors Endogenous growth and new economic geography In the above discussion regions converged because of the diminishing returns to capital. However, the assumptions of diminishing returns have been questioned, see e.g. the discussion in Aghion and Howitt (2004: pp.56-60). Instead, if investments in innovation (R&D) are considered, the return on these investments work against the diminishing returns and the economy can sustain ever increasing technological growth and increasing returns to factors, as shown by Romer (1986) and Lucas (1988). These kinds of models, incorporating innovation and thus endogenizing technological growth, have become known as endogenous growth models (Aghion and Howitt 2004: p.47). As argued by Coe and Helpman (1995: p.860): In a world with international trade in goods and services, foreign direct investment, and an international exchange of information and dissemination of knowledge, a country s productivity depends on its own R&D as well as the R&D of trade partners. Certainly, if regions are considered more open than countries, this importance should be even more valid between regions than between countries. Note how endogenous models need not predict convergence between rich and poor economies as in the neoclassical theory. Instead, by investing in human capital and R&D, high-income regions can keep up a higher growth rate indefinitely. Furthermore, as stressed by NEG, other pecuniary externalities than the typical Marshallian technological and knowledge spillovers, considered in neoclassical and endogenous models, might be present. Following the work by Krugman (1991), Krugman and Venables (1995), Puga and Venables (1996) and Fujita et al. (1999), in this set of NEG-models increasing returns to scale at the firm-level, factor mobility and trade cost work together to induce agglomerations of economic activity at the aggregate level New economic geography In NEG-models demand linkages create a causal circularity of centrifugal and centripetal forces that divide the economy into a high-income core and a low-income periphery. Centrifugal forces are forces that work toward the geographical dispersion of economic activity. Any costs (both pecuniary costs and negative externalities) that can be associated with living or running a business in an economic center such as housing prices, congestion or local competition are centrifugal forces. Centripetal forces, on the other hand, work toward the spatial agglomeration 9

11 of economic activity through what is sometimes referred to as forwards- and backwardslinkages. 2 First consider the case of forward linkages. Firms wish to locate in regions with good access to large markets to realize scale economies and minimize transport costs. Consequently, firms will locate as close to large-market regions, so that they can sell goods to as many as possible and incur minimal transport costs. Subsequently, they will also attract workers, who in turn will spend their income locally, further increasing market size (thus demand) and in turn attracting even more firms wanting to exploit further increasing returns to scale. The backwards linkages, on the other hand, work through the vertical production chain between firms. In a world of transport costs, if firms are clustered it is much cheaper to buy inputs, intermediates etc. from nearby suppliers. Thus, firms will locate near suppliers since the cost of intermediates are lower there. This tendency for firms to want to shorten input-linkages creates a propensity for firms to cluster is space. Hence, if backward- and forward-linkages are strong enough i.e., if firms can exploit sufficiently large scale economies; demand is large enough; and, trade costs are adequately low the NEG-models gives a demand-linked circular causality that creates what Krugman (1991) dubbed a core-periphery pattern. That is, following Baldwin and Martin (2004) and letting capital be the only mobile factor 3, firms will cluster together in the region with the initial larger capital stock, this in turn increases their profits and the return to capital in that region. Subsequently, as capital flows into the region, the return to capital rises, raising real incomes, which in turn increases market size and demand further, attracting even more firms. Thus, capital-intensive industries will agglomerate to the economically larger region, the core, pushing up incomes, leaving the other region, the periphery, with lower incomes. Hence, history and endowments determines which region can exploit the demand-circular causality and end up as the core region, where industry agglomerates Agglomeration and regional growth Bringing the predictions of endogenous growth theory to a NEG-framework, a self-reinforcing process between growth and agglomeration is commonly found. That is to say, growth brings about agglomeration and agglomeration brings about growth. However, if these models predict 2 It is also possible to add labor-market pooling to this list. That is, it is much easier for employers to find specialized labor if the labor market is pooled in one location. However, this reason for firms and workers to agglomerate is not included by Krugman (1991). 3 This assumption is made so that the equilibrium will be stable, assuming labor mobility would have created an unstable equilibrium (Baldwin and Martin 2004: pp ). To avoid a catastrophic outcome where all economic activity agglomerates to one region, NEG models often assumes that one factor is mobile and the other immobile. 10

12 regional convergence or divergence crucially depend on the assumptions made (Baldwin and Martin 2004). Generally, the analyses can be divided between models that assume global technological spillovers and models that assume local technological spillovers (Bräuninger and Niebuhr 2005: p.3). For instance, following Martin and Ottaviano (1999) and Baldwin and Martin (2004), when spillovers are of global reach geography do not affect growth. In this perspective higher growth is associated with convergence since the factors that increase endogenous growth (R&D-investments, education, etc.) also decrease income disparities. On the other hand, when spillovers are assumed to be of local character the geographical concentration of economic activity is found to increase both growth and income disparities. Note how there is a trade-off between regional income equity and growth, as agglomeration in these models reduces the cost of innovating in the core but increases the growth rate for the entire economy. Thus, with localized spillovers an increase in the spatial concentration of economic activity can be beneficial to growth rates in both the core and the periphery. This means that a more uneven economic geography is not necessarily bad for the periphery. Nevertheless, note that for a given geography of production, less localized (i.e. more global) spillovers implies a lower overall cost of innovation and a higher aggregate growth rate for the entire economy. Generally the NEG and endogenous growth models underlines the importance of the barriers to the spatial diffusion of technological and knowledge spillovers. Paraphrasing Baldwin and Martin (2004), if barriers to the diffusion of technology and innovation are sufficiently low the periphery can break the vicious demand-linked causality and instead enter a virtuous circle. That is, start investing, attract industry and thus increase incomes and growth rates. Hence, as spillovers become less localized the market size of the periphery increases, the cost of innovating falls and incomes between the core and the periphery will converge. The endogenous growth and NEG models show that factor mobility and economic spillovers are important aspects of economic integration. In particular, these can either lessen or extenuate the centrifugal and centripetal forces implied by freer trade in traditional NEG-models. If spillovers are localized, the continual lowering of trade costs can produce an uneven spatial development, as real incomes rises in the core and falls in the periphery. However, now the emergence of regional imbalances may be accompanied by faster growth in all regions. This creates a tension between static losses due to income reallocation and dynamic gains due to higher aggregate growth. Thus from a welfare perspective, while the core is made unambiguously better off by agglomeration, the welfare effects in the periphery are more ambiguous. Consequently, regional policies that seek to hinder geographic concentration may cost a country as a whole in terms of growth. 11

13 Furthermore, note that there are large differences between core and periphery when it comes to industrial agglomeration, human capital endowment, R&D activity, and infrastructure etc. Hence, the NEG and endogenous growth models reinforces and complements the theoretical predication of geographically conditioned club-convergence from the neoclassical models discussed above. Instead, the models open up the black box of neoclassical convergence and describe a certain aspect of how spatial spillovers affect the convergence process. 3. Methodological aspects Traditionally, empirical tests of the neoclassical convergence hypotheses follow from Baumol (1986). Baumol implements a simple cross-section regression with the average growth rate as the dependent variable and initial GDP as the independent variable. Drawing from the predictions of the neoclassical convergence hypotheses, economies with low initial GDP are expected to grow faster than economies with higher initial GDP. Thus, a negative estimated coefficient in Baumol s specification is interpreted as unconditional convergence. Following Baumol s original work, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991, 1992) extend the analysis to the conditional convergence-hypothesis by allowing economies to converge to different steady states. These approaches of testing unconditional and conditional convergence have by Barro and Sala-i-Martin been labeled β-convergence regressions. Moreover, as discussed in chapter 2, spatial dependence is predicted to be an important factor when regional convergence is considered. Recent developments in spatial econometrics have been incorporated in the traditional β-convergence analysis. By means of these approaches the strength and significance of spatial externalities can indirectly be estimated β-convergence The point of departure of the empirical analysis is the unconditional β-convergence crosssection of Baumol (1986). Specifically the following model is specified, ( ), (3.1) where is per-capita GRP for region i at time t, so that (3.1) gives the relation between initial per-capita GRP at time t as the independent variable and the average growth rate between time t and T as the dependent variable. The variable represents the error term. Using OLSestimations it is assumed that is identical and independently distributed with zero mean and constant variance. Moreover, and are parameters to be estimated. The parameter is the intercept. As discussed in section 2, neoclassical growth theory predicts that the growth rate of 12

14 an economy is positively related to the distance from its steady state. So, whenever the independent variable,, shows a negative relationship this is interpreted as β-convergence. In other words, regions with lower initial per-capita GRP are expected to exhibit relatively higher average growth rate. The annual rate of β-convergence is obtained from,. From this the half-life, i.e. the necessary time for half the differences in per-capita incomes to disappear, can be obtained from. However, as noted in section 2 the steady-state can differ across economies, being conditioned on underlying characteristics specific to each economy. Specifically to this thesis, countryspecific characteristics will be accounted for, so that regions belonging to different countries will be allowed to converge to different steady states. Thus in addition to the unconditional convergence model in (3.1), conditional β-convergence is tested on the following cross-section model, ( ) (3.2) where represents country dummy-variables, so that if region i belongs to country j and otherwise. Similar to above, if is found to be negative this is interpreted as conditional convergence Spatial dependence The theoretical prediction from chapter 2 gives that the regional convergence process should exhibit a strong spatial component. However, if the regional convergence process exhibits spatial interdependence this implies that that the assumption of observational independence no longer holds (Rey and Montouri 1999). Thus, if the spatial dependence is not sufficiently explained by the independent variables the error terms are no longer independently distributed, but dependent across space. The definite consequence of this misspecification depends on the form of the spatial dependence. Anselin (1988) and Anselin and Rey (1991) differentiate between two types of spatial dependence: nuisance and substantive. The former type relates to dependence working through the error process, so that the errors from different regions displays covariance. The latter kind, substantive spatial dependence, reflects economic linkages and externalities between regions. That is to say, spatial dependence corresponding to the discussion in chapter 2. Spatial dependence invalidates the inferential basis of OLS-estimation, 13

15 namely uncorrelated errors. To account for spatial dependence of both forms different spatial econometric methods can be applied Nuisance spatial dependence Nuisance or spatial error dependence occurs when disturbances in cross-section models are not independently distributed across space. For example, it can emerge from measurement errors, such as a wrongly specified regional system that do not reflect the spatial structure of the economy adequately. 4 Nuisance dependence can also be related to an omitted variables problem. Given that the omitted variable and the dependent variable are both spatially correlated, spatial error dependence can emerge (Fischer and Stirböck 2006: p.701). Moreover, as for example Rey and Montouri (1999), Niebuhr (2001) and Le Gallo et al. (2006) point out, in the case of regional growth models spatial error dependence can also have an economic interpretation. Namely, a random shock introduced to a region will not only affect growth rates in the respective region. Instead the shock will propagate through the regional system disturbing the growth rates and thus the convergence processes among regions in the entire regional neighborhood. However, regardless of the cause the effect will be that errors are not independently distributed. As a result OLS estimations of the β-convergence models in (3.1) and (3.2) will be inefficient. However, note that the OLS-estimates themselves will remain unbiased (Fischer and Stirböck 2006). Following Le Gallo et al. (2005) and Fischer and Stirböck (2006), consider the following firstorder autoregressive spatial error model,, (3.3) where y is the vector of observations on a dependent variable; X is the matrix of independent variables; are the vector of associated parameters to be estimated; is a spatially correlated error vector; is a spatial autoregressive parameter measuring the strength of spatial spillovers; and is a spatial weight matrix 5 that assigns a neighborhood to each location. The consequence of the spatial correlated error vector is that the elements of the variance-covariance matrix no longer independent and uncorrelated. Instead it becomes, [ ] [ ] where is the nth-order identity matrix. As Fischer and Stirböck (2006) points out, it is well known that in the presence of non-spherical errors OLS yields unbiased but inefficient estimates 4 See chapter 5 for further discussion of this problem, specifically referred to as MAUP. 5 For specification of the spatial weight matrix employed in this thesis see Appendix I. 14

16 of the parameters variance. Thus, in the presence of error dependence inference based on OLSestimation of (3.1) and (3.2) will be misleading. Instead, Le Gallo et al. (2005) and Fischer and Stirböck (2006) among others following Anselin and Bera (1998) suggest using a maximum likelihood approach to obtain efficient estimates in the presence of spatial error dependence. Now, applying the spatial error model to the unconditional β-convergence model of (3.1) (though the same of course applies to (3.2)) the following model can be specified, ( ), (3.4) which for the reasons discussed above needs to be estimated by means of maximum likelihood. In (3.4) spatial dependence is restricted to the error terms and per-capita income growth is explained adequately by the convergence hypothesis and unmodeled effects. Moreover, movements away from the steady-state growth path induced by a shock are no longer restricted to the respective region, but propagates through a neighborhood of adjacent regions assigned by. Whenever (3.4) reduces to the OLS-specification in (3.1) Substantive spatial dependence Substantive or spatial lag dependence derives from spatial economic externalities between regions. That is, in the case of regional convergence, such spatial dependence that is discussed in chapter 2. Thus, in the case of substantive spatial dependence, the growth of per-capita regional income is not adequately explained by the convergence process. Instead, neighboring regions growth rates must be accounted for to explain the convergence process. Ignoring the substantive dependence yield biased OLS-estimates and all inference based on OLS will be incorrect. An indirect way to account for substantive spatial dependence is to include a spatially lagged dependent variable in estimations (Anselin 1988). This can be specified as a spatial lag model,, (3.5) where,,, and are defined as above. The parameter is the spatial autoregressive coefficient and measures the extent of spatial externalities. That is, a significant spatial lag term in (3.5) indicates substantive spatial dependence. Due to the endogeniety introduced by the spatial lag, the spatial lag model estimated by OLS will be inconsistent and (3.5) need to be estimated using a maximum likelihood approach or other approach that accounts for the endogenity (ibid). In the case of β-convergence a spatial lag model can be specified as, 15

17 ( ) [ ( )]. (3.6) Note that the specification in (3.6) no longer corresponds to the unconditional convergence model of (3.1). Instead, in the spatial lag model regional growth rates are conditioned on the growth rate of neighbors. However, whenever (3.6) reduces to the unconditional convergence specification in (3.1). Following Rey and Montouri (1999), Anselin and Bera (1998) and Niebuhr (2001), the model in (3.6) has several interpretations. First, from a technical perspective the spatial lag model can be viewed as a filter controlling for spatial dependence either in growth rates and initial per-capita income or in convergence. That is to say, (3.6) either controls if the spatial dependence in growth rates is a by-product of spatial clustering of initial incomes. Alternatively (3.6) checks whether the negative relationship between growth and initial income is robust when spatial dependence is controlled for (Rey and Montouri 1999; Niebuhr 2001). Additionally, the spatial lag model can be interpreted through data generating process. In this view, the regional growth rates are not only affected by its own initial incomes, but also by income growth in neighboring regions (cf. López-Bazo et al. 2004; Egger and Pfaffermayr 2006; Ertur and Koch 2007). In other words, on average local income growth is not only explained by the local level of income, but also by income growth in the entire regional system. 4. Prior research The β-convergence regression approach has come under some criticism. For example, as Quah (1993a, 1993b) among others have pointed out, a regression of GDP growth rates over initial levels runs the risk of committing Galton s fallacy of regressions toward the mean. As Magrini (2004: p.2750) explains, a negative relation between initial GDP and the growth rate does not necessarily prove decreasing within-sample inequality. In other words, β-convergence need not necessarily imply a reduction of the variance in regional incomes. Instead the concept of σ- convergence is sometimes used. Specifically, σ-convergence implies a decline in in-sample dispersion of income levels over time. Thus, σ-convergence is often tested by appreciating the entire income distribution. Consequently, following Magrini (2004), most previous research in the field of regional convergence can be divided into studies taking a parametric β-regression approach and studies taking a (often) nonparametric distributional approach. The former tests the predictions of the unconditional or conditional convergence hypotheses, while the latter looks at the entire crosssection distribution of regional incomes. Here both studies taking the classical regression 16

18 approach to β-convergence and studies taking the distributional approaches to σ-convergence will be reviewed. The review will to a large extent be limited to studies in the European context The regression approach Following their work on β-convergence Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991, 1992) are able to report the existence of unconditional convergence across several European countries and conditional convergence across a sample of European regions for the period Generally, the authors find an average convergence rate of 2% per annum across their samples, both between countries and for regions within countries. However, as argued by for example Armstrong (1995), the countries in the studies by Barro and Sala-i-Martin can be considered too homogenous in GDP and growth rates to really constitute different convergence clubs. As an alternative, Armstrong (1995) extends the sample of Barro and Sala-i-Martin to all pre-1995 EU-members and the period reviewed is extended to By accounting for country-specific effects as well as various structural variables, Armstrong is able to account for different steady states across the considered sample, now finding a yearly convergence rate of 1%. Armstrong also points out that within-country convergence is found to have peaked in the subperiod and has since fallen. Generally, within-country convergence is found to be much lower than between-country convergence for the entire sample period. Following Armstrong (1995) other studies have investigated the convergence process among EU-regions using similar methods. For example, Neven and Gouyette (1995), Martin (2001), Cuadro-Roura (2001) and Niebuhr and Schlitte (2004) all find evidence of conditional convergence in different constellations of EU regions over different time periods. Some general observations can be noted, there seem to have been conditional convergence until the late 1970s, this weakened during the 1980s, to reappear again in the 1990s, albeit in a weaker form than in the 1970s. However, as pointed out by Magrini (2004: p.2749), these results are very sensitive to what countries that are included in the sample, the disaggregation level of the data and what (if any) additional explanatory variables that are added. Nevertheless, the impression from these early studies is that regional convergence in Europe is rather weak compared to elsewhere and is stricken by considerable country-specific components Spatial dependence and regional convergence The regional convergence studies reviewed above used country dummies or structural variables to account for different convergence clubs and spatial dependence. However, as discussed in chapter 3, if there exists spatial dependence and it is not sufficiently explained by the 17

19 independent variables the estimations might be miss-specified. Instead as discussed in chapter 3 spatial econometric methods, accounting for the spatial dependence, can be employed and applied to the β-convergence regressions. The first study to incorporate spatial econometric methods to en empirical analysis of regional income convergence, and thus explicitly addressing the effect of spatial externalities on the convergence-process, is Rey and Montouri (1999). The authors examine a cross-section of USstates during the period and find evidence for spatial error dependence. Thus, the spatial dependence between US states is of the nuisance type, so that a shock originating in one state will propagate through its neighborhood complicating the convergence process. Following Rey and Montouri s (1999) findings, a wide range of studies on regional convergence using spatial econometric methods in the European context has been published (see e.g. Niebuhr 2001; López-Bazo et al. 2004; Bräuninger and Niebuhr 2005; Ertur, et al. 2006; Fischer and Stirböck 2006; Egger and Pfaffermayr 2006; Dall erba and Le Gallo 2008; Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008; Battisti and Di Vaio 2008; Ramajo et al. 2008; Tselios 2009; Arbia et al. 2010). These studies find evidence of spatial dependence, so that regions that exhibit high (low) growth rates seem to cluster together in space, the same goes for cluster of high (low) initial GDP per capita. Some common findings of the studies are worth noting. First, allowing for spatial dependence seems to yield a lower rate of convergence than what usually is found in ordinary OLSregression β-convergence studies. Depending on the countries, aggregation level and time period considered, a yearly convergence rate of around 1-3% is typically found. Moreover, most studies agree that the spatial dependence prevalent in the EU is mainly of the substantive kind. Only Ertur et al. (2006) find robust evidence for nuisance dependence. However, as can be drawn from López-Bazo et al. s (2004) robustness checks, the results are very sensitive to model specifications and the aggregation level of the data. Furthermore, those studies investigating the existence of spatial convergence-clubs (e.g. Bräuninger and Niebuhr 2005; Ertur et al. 2006; Fischer and Stirböck 2006; Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008; Dall erba and Le Gallo 2008; Battisti and Di Vaio 2008), find evidence for the presence of strong neighborhood effects in Europe. The rate of convergence within such neighborhoods is faster than the rate of convergence across the neighborhoods. This finding can be interpreted as different geographical neighborhoods of regions converging to different steady states. A few studies also investigate if neighborhoods effects are more important than country effects for convergence. Dividing a sample of 108 regions, over the period , into within- and between-country components, López-Bazo et al. (2004) are able to show substantive spatial 18

20 clustering of similar values within countries. Moreover, the results in the between-country case points more toward nuisance dependence. This would imply that substantive dependence is mainly a within-country phenomenon. Furthermore, using country-specific dummies to capture national effects, Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008) and Bräuningen and Niebuhr (2005) find that, even though there is strong spatial dependence between regions, the regional convergence process in Europe is mainly driven by national factors. In other words, spatial dependence is found to matter less across national borders. Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008) point out that national factor have been particularly important in the transition process of the Eastern- European countries among the NMS, when going from a planned to a market-based economy. Arbia et al. (2010) find that country-specific institutions (captured by an institutional quality index) matter and is positively correlated with the growth rate of a region. Some regional convergence studies using alternative methods to the spatial β-convergence cross-section are worth noting. For example, Meliciani and Peracchi (2006) uses a spatial panel approach over the period and finds evidence for both strong spatial clubconvergence, with faster convergence within countries compared to between. On account of this, the authors speculate that technological diffusion might be easier within than between countries despite the continuing European integration process. Moreover, also using a spatial panel approach, Badinger et al. (2004) find a speed of convergence of 7% in a sample of 196 EUregions over the period This estimate is much higher than what most other studies have found. Although, as mentioned above the results in these kinds of studies are sensitive to which regions are included in the sample The distributional approach Some examples of studies investigating the distribution of per capita income and σ-convergence in a European regional context are: Quah (1996); López-Bazo et al. (1999); Villaverde (2003); Maza and Villaverde (2004); Ezcurra et al. (2006, 2007a, 2007b); Geppert and Stephan (2008); and, Chapman and Meliciani (2011). Generally, from the 1970s and onwards, EU regions seem to have converged into different poles, polarizing into three distinct modes of high-, average- and low-income clusters. The studies reviewed here also point to the importance of country-specific effects and that often between-country convergence is associated with within-country divergence. Asking if the main determinants of per-capita income distribution dynamics across European regions are EU-factors, nation-specific characteristics or neighborhood spillovers, Quah (1996) examines the distribution of regional per-capita incomes relative the averages of the suggested determinants over the 1980s. Quah finds that there is σ-convergence in the EU-relative 19

21 distribution. In other word, the intra-distributional dispersion of regional per-capita incomes is declining relative the EU-average. Moreover, the neighborhood-relative distribution is found to be less disperse than both the nation-relative and the EU-relative distributions. From this Quah draws the conclusion that neighborhood-effects, and thus spatial spillovers, are the most important determinant of σ-convergence of the considered determinants. Looking at the regional per-capita income distribution conditioned on the EU-average over the period , López-Bazo et al. (1999) find contrary evidence to Quah (1996). That is to say, σ-divergence or, in other terms, increased disparities over the period. The authors explain this by noting that their sample contains more diverse regions in terms of GRP per capita compared to Quah (1996). López-Bazo et al. also note a bimodal distribution of regional GRP per capita, one subset of regions where inequality has lessened and one where it has increased relative to the EU-average. This, the authors speculate, could be evidence of two different convergence clubs. Furthermore, looking at a sample consisting of regions from the pre-1995 EU-members over the period , Villaverde (2003) notes that regional per-capita income inequality have lessened over the period. However, so has the speed of convergence and the upwards mobility of income. That is to say, the income ranking of regions has grown more persistent over the sample period. Maza and Villaverde (2004) find similar evidence as those of Villaverde (2003). In addition similar to previous studies, the authors find a noticeable polarization pattern of regions into high- and low-income clubs. In contrast, in a series of papers Ezcurra, Pascual and Rapún (2006, 2007a, 2007b) employing a larger dataset over a longer time-period than Villaverde (2003) and Maza and Villaverde (2004), instead find decreasing polarization but increasing inequality between EU regions 6. Looking at sample of 197 EU-regions over the period , Ezcurra et al. (2006, 2007b) find a bimodal pattern of the regional per-capita income in the beginning of their sample period. One main pole is found around the EU-average and one pole located at the lower end of the distribution. However, this pattern change over time and at the end of their sample period a new local maximum has appeared at the upper end of the distribution. Even though the difference between the modes has decreased over time, the relative size of them has increased. That is to say, more regions are found to either belong to the high-income mode or the low-income mode, so that regional income inequality has increased while polarization has decreased over time. 6 Note the possible difference between increased polarization and increased inequality. As Ezcurra et al. (2006: p.460) point out, consider that regions in a country are converging to two distinct clubs, one with high-income and one with low-income. As the regions within the two clubs grow more alike it will register as a decrease by most inequality-measures, while it is an increase in polarization. 20

22 Ezcurra et al. (2006, 2007a) also note the importance of spatial location for the outcome of regions. Moreover, investigating the importance of country-specific effects, Ezcurra et al. (2006) condition the regional per-capita income distribution on national averages, finding that distributional density now is more concentrated around the mean (as opposed to the multimodal distributions found when looking at the EU-relative distributions). The authors take this finding as an indication of the importance of the national component in determining the outcome of regional income. Investigating the distributional dynamics of a sample of NMS-regions from Central and Eastern European countries over the period , Ezcurra et al. (2007b) find between-country convergence, but within-country divergence. That is to say, at the country-level Eastern Europe is catching-up with Western Europe, however, at the same time within-country disparities have increased, so that the catching-up mainly reflect the behavior of a few high-income regions. These high-income regions are mainly found to be urban-centers and regions close to the EU15- border. Echoing other studies reviewed here, the authors also stress the importance of countryspecific effects in explaining within-country disparities in regional per-capita incomes. Chapman and Meliciani (2011) find overall σ-convergence, but increasing within-country disparities with strong, but falling, spatial correlation in a sample of regions from the EU15 over the period. The authors consider socio-economic, geographical, and industrialspecialization clusters as conditioning factors behind the within-country disparities. Generally, the evidence point to that industry-specialization and, particularly, socio-economic clusters have good explanatory power if a region end-up in a low-income or high-income cluster. This would imply that country-specific factors are more important than geographical factors. However, as the authors note, this does not imply that spatial factors are unimportant. Rather, the authors argue, the findings should be interpreted as agglomeration alone fails to explain the regional income dynamics and need to be complemented with additional explanatory factors. 5. Data The dataset employed in this thesis consist of data on per-capita GRP expressed in PPS. The set contains data from 1309 European regions at the NUTS 3-level of aggregation over the time period of The data is compiled from the Eurostat-REGIO database 8 and from OECD s 7 For a detailed list of all included countries, regions and groupings see Appendix II

23 OECD.Stat 9 regional database. The dataset constitutes a larger sample of NUTS 3-regions from a wider range of countries than has been employed in previous studies using NUTS 3-level data (see e.g. Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008). Additionally, the dataset constitutes an extension of the time period covered in previous studies to include more recent years. The regions included in the dataset are from all current 27 EU member states with the addition of Croatia, who is expected to become the 28 th member on 1 st of July Thus, the dataset consist of a total of 28 countries, in turn including a total of 1309 regions 10. Even though Croatia is not yet a full member of the EU, including the country is not deemed a problem since it already should be well underway in implementing the required policies regarding tariffs, capital and labor mobility etc. necessary for EU-membership. Furthermore, since one of the aims of this thesis is to explore the convergence dynamics of the NMS the data set will be split to account for this. That is, complementary to the analysis of the entire 28-country dataset, both all pre-2004 members (the EU15) and all new member states (NMS) that joined post-2004 will be given a separate analysis when this is deemed relevant. Additionally, the division closely follows that of the official EU classification, separating between EU27 (all members), EU15 (all pre-2004 members) and the EU12 or NMS (all post-2004 members) (see e.g. EU Commission 2010) so the split is also interesting from a policy perspective. Following Eurostat (2007), the NUTS-system (Nomenclature of Territorial Units of Statistics) is a hierarchal regional classification system with three regional levels; NUTS-0, -1, -2 and -3 (NUTS 0 being the least disaggregate regional data level, corresponding to that of member state, and NUTS 3 the most disaggregated level). The system was established by Eurostat to provide a comparable regional breakdown of the EU member states. The NUTS regional system is set up after three principles. First, it is set within a specific population threshold (minimum and maximum inhabitants for the NUTS 3 classification). Second, for practical reasons the NUTS regulations also tries to follow the member states national administrative units to as large extent as possible. Lastly, the NUTS regulation follows suitable natural geographical units. The three distinctions are made to keep the regional units within as functional economic units as possible, while still retaining as much of the national administrative divisions of each member state It should be noted that there is a possibility that the inclusion of 429 German NUTS 3 regions might bias the estimates, as these are more numerous and smaller than the NUTS 3 regions from other countries. Other studies using NUTS 3 level data prefer using German planning-regions (Raumordnungsregionen) to avoid this potential problem (Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008). However, after investigating the matter and accounting for the German NUTS 3 regions, it was found that the inclusion of the German NUTS 3 regions did not change the results in any substantial way. 22

24 However, the sometimes arbitrary division of the NUTS regional system poses a problem known as the modifiable areal unit problem (MAUP) (Openshaw 1984). Specifically, in the case relevant to this thesis, a too high aggregation level might hide several functional economic units, missing important spatial interaction. On the other hand, a too low aggregation level can divide the functional units making the detected spatial autocorrelation an artifact of slicing homogenous areas into separate units. Substantive spatial dependence would then be missed and the detected dependence would instead show up as nuisance dependence. As pointed out by Geppert et al. (2008: p.10), this can be especially problematic when metropolitan areas are divided into their own units, potentially separating them from their economic neighborhood. The risk of slicing functional economic units is deemed particularly problematic when using NUTS 3-level data. Aside from estimating the true functional economic-geographical areas, something that is not possible in the European context today given the current data availability, there is no real way to account for this problem. However, even though there are some potential problems associated with using NUTS 3-level data, most previous studies employ NUTS 2-level of data or a mixed set of regions at various NUTS-levels. 11 Thus, arguably, using NUTS 3-data might reveal previous unfound relationships, missed when employing data at a higher aggregation level. Moreover, since EU regional policy is based on the NUTS regional classification system, analysis at the NUTS 3-level also has policy implications. Furthermore, since the interest to this thesis concerns regional spatial dependence and convergence dynamics in the EU, overseas regions are dropped from the dataset. These regions are considered too geographically remote from mainland Europe to be affected by spatial spillovers. Moreover, these regions often constitute extreme low-income outliers in the dataset, so including them could seriously bias the estimates downwards. The dropped regions are: El Hiero (ES), Fuerteventura (ES), Gran Canaria (ES), La Gomera (ES), La Palma (ES), Lanzarote (ES), Tenerife (ES), Ceuta (ES), Melilla (ES), Guadeloupe (FR), Martinique (FR), Guyana (FR), Réunion (FR), Acores (PT), and Madeira (PT). Next, the remaining data is tested for outliers using the method of Hadi (1992, 1994) and five additional potential candidates are found. However, removing these does not affect the results in any substantial way. Hence, to not unnecessarily reduce the number of observations in the dataset the five potential outlier regions are included in the final estimations. It is possible that the data show such a strong trend that the estimates are unaffected by the outliers. Another notable discussion in the literature is if GRP should be expressed in PPS or in euros. Data in PPS are adjusted for differences in national price-levels and some prior work (e.g. Ertur 11 The exception being Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008) who also use NUTS 3 level data, although with a smaller datasets compared to the one employed in this thesis. 23

25 and Le Gallo 2003; Ertur et al. 2004; Fischer and Stirböck 2006) has pointed to that GRP expressed in euros should be preferred since prices differ substantially within European countries. However, as Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008), this thesis argue that even though there are large within-country disparities in price levels, using PPS is more appropriate unit since prices differ even more substantially between countries when including all NMS regions. 6. Analysis So far the theoretical models discussed in chapter 2 and empirical works reviewed in chapter 4 have pointed to that the regional convergence process is influenced by considerable spatial dependence. Hence, as discussed in chapter 3, to avoid miss-specifications spatial dependence need to be explicitly accounted for in the convergence analysis. Drawing from theoretical and empirical findings, it also seems possible that convergence clubs are conditioned on geographical location. So that high-income regions tend to cluster with other high-income regions and low-income regions with low-income regions. As some studies reviewed in chapter 4 suggested differences in the convergence process between the EU15 and the NMS the possibility of the groups constituting different convergence clubs must be accounted for. Moreover according to the endogenous growth and NEG models of section 2.2, if the spatial spillovers are sufficiently localized poorer regions need not converge to the richer ones at all. Instead regional income and growth rates could have a core-periphery distribution. To account both for the possibility of a core-periphery pattern and for spatial spillovers in the analysis of regional per-capita income convergence exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial econometric models are employed. Furthermore, as discussed in chapter 4, the parametric approaches to study incomeconvergence have met some critique. In short, β-convergence can be stated as a necessary but not sufficient condition for σ-convergence. Hence, to fully account for income convergence the entire cross-section distribution must be appreciated. Thus, complementary to the parametric regression approaches a nonparametric distributional analysis is first performed. These two approaches has previously, with a few exceptions (see e.g. Geppert and Stenphen 2008; Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008), been separated. Thus, in view of the sharp criticism against the regression approaches it seems appropriate to take the distributional analysis into account as a complement to the more traditional convergence analysis The regional income distribution The analysis will now consider the external shape and inter-distributional dynamics of the dataset. That is to say, the entire cross-section distribution of per-capita GRP will be investigated 24

26 by accounting for regional income inequality, transition and polarization dynamics. First by doing this, as pointed out by Quah (1993a, 1993b, 1996), the risk of committing Galton s fallacy of regressions toward the mean can be avoided. Moreover, the distributional analysis is a good complement to the regression approach and gives an indication if the possibility of β- convergence is followed by σ-convergence. The analysis also follows from Ezcurra et al. (2006), who as mentioned in section 4.2 point to that decreased disparities need not necessarily imply decreased polarization. To investigate σ-convergence, first a range of inequality measures will be employed to investigate inter-distributional regional income inequality. Also, the within- and betweencountry contribution to regional per-capita income disparities is estimated. Next, both transition tables and kernel density estimations are employed to account for the dynamics of the regional income distribution Inequality patterns To measure regional income inequality generalized entropy (GE) indices are employed. According to Brülhart and Traeger (2005) and Novotny (2007) this class of inequality measures has an advantage, compared to other popular inequality measures such as the Gini-coefficient, in being additively decomposable into a within- and between-component of some basic unit or subgroup of basic units. In this case the basic unit translates into regions and sub-groups to countries. Hence, it is possible to estimate how much of the detected regional income inequality (entropy) in the dataset that is due to within- and between-country disparities. The two GEindices considered in this thesis are the GE(1)- and GE(2)-indices. The GE(1)-index correspond to the Theil index of inequality and the GE(2)-index corresponds to the half-squared coefficient of variation. Higher values of the measures imply more inter-distributional inequality. Moreover, it should be noted that the GE(1)-index is more sensitive to inequality among low-income regions. Conversely, the GE(2) index is more sensitive to inequality among high-income regions. Following Brülhart and Traeger (2005), generally the GE(1)-index is preferred for decomposition. Hence, only the within- and between-component of the GE(1)-measure is considered in this thesis. 12 Figure 6.1, below, plots the GE(1)- and GE(2)-indices of regional per-capita GRP of the EU28-set over the period. As can be seen, besides the period , when inequality increased somewhat, regional per-capita income inequality has steadily fallen over the period. In other words, according to the indices there is less inter-distributional dispersion in regional incomes in 2009 than in As the GE(2)-measure should be more sensitive to inequality 12 For a more detailed discussion of generalized entropy indices see Appendix III. 25

27 among high-income regions and the GE(1)-measure to inequality among low-income regions, no substantial difference in the development of regions at the different ends of the distribution can be reported from the figure. Fig Entropy indices, EU28 0,12 0,11 0,1 0,09 0,08 0,07 GE(1) GE(2) 0,06 0,05 However, turning to the dynamics of fig a more detailed picture emerges. Fig. 6.2., below, plots the shares of the within-country and the between-country contribution to the regional income inequality in the EU28. As is evident from looking at the figure, the within-country contribution to regional inequality has steadily risen over the sample-period. In 1995 approximately 50% of all regional income inequality was due to within- and between-country dispersion, respectively. In 2009 the share of within-country contribution to dispersion is increased to 60%. That is to say, on the country level per-capita incomes are more equal in 2009 compared to 1995, however this equality hides a larger share of within-country dispersion of regional per-capita incomes. Fig Share of between- and within-component of regional inequality, EU28 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% GEb(1) GEw(1) 0% 26

28 Taken together with fig. 6.1., fig paints a picture of decreasing regional income disparities. However, this reduction is accompanied by a relative increase of the importance of withincountry inequality. In other words, a larger portion of the still existing inequality in the EU seems to be due to inequality within countries. It is possible that these results pick up on the findings reported above (Ezcurra et al. 2007b; Geppert and Stephen 2008; Chapman and Melciani 2011; Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008) of σ-convergence but increasing within-country dispersion of regional incomes. If this is the case, what is driving the decreased inequality in the EU28 on the country-level is the behavior of a few high-income regions among the NMS, who has converged to the EU28-mean, leaving laggard low-income regions behind. This would certainly explain why within-country inequality has increased, while overall inequality decreased. To further investigate if there is any difference in the behavior of regions among the NMS and the rest of the EU, the EU28-set is divided into a subset consisting of the EU15-regions and one consisting of NMS-regions. First in fig. 6.3., below, the GE(1) and GE(2) inequality measures of the EU15 over the sample-period is plotted. As can be seen, the development of regional income inequality is generally stable in the subset, lessening somewhat over the period. What can be noted is that the GE(1)-measure has decreased relatively more than the GE(2)-measure. Since the GE(1)-measure should be more sensitive to dispersion among regional incomes in the lower tail of the income distribution, it is possible that inequality among low-income regions has decreased somewhat more relative inequality among high-income regions in the EU15. Fig Entropy indices, EU15 0,075 0,07 0,065 0,06 GE(1) GE(2) 0,055 0,05 Now, consider the shares of between- and within-country contribution to overall income inequality in the EU15. Below fig shows how the lion s share of regional income inequality in the EU15 is made up of within-country dispersion. In other words, the EU15-countries show somewhat equal per-capita income levels across countries, while the dispersion of regional 27

29 incomes that do exist is mainly due to within-country inequality. However, the development is quite stable, so it does not explain the decline of overall inequality and the rise of within-country inequality that was found when considering the EU28-set. Fig Share of between- and within-component of regional inequality, EU15 100% 95% 90% 85% 80% GEb(1) GEw(1) 75% Turning to the development among the NMS, below fig plots the GE(1)- and GE(2)-indices for the NMS-set over the sample-period. Looking at the figure, regional per-capita income inequality first increased during the 1990s, then stabilized and level off somewhat during 2000s. Generally, considering the values of the indices, regional inequality is more pronounced in the NMS than in the EU15. Also note how the indices increased in 2004, when a large group of NMScountries joined the EU, to later decrease somewhat again. Fig Entropy indices, NMS 0,14 0,13 0,12 0,11 0,1 0,09 0,08 0,07 0,06 0,05 GE(1) GE(2) Plotted in fig. 6.6., below, are the shares of between- and within-country contribution to the regional per-capita income inequality in the NMS. A clear increase in the share of within-country 28

30 inequality over the sample-period is visible. In 1995 around 60% of inequality among the NMSregions was due to differences between countries, while in 2009 this share is closer to 30%. This finding confirms those found above, as well as those found by Ezcurra et al. (2007b) Geppert and Stephen 2008, Chapman and Melciani 2011 and Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008), of σ- convergence at the country level, but increased disparities within the NMS. Thus, the results here seem to confirm the story of a few NMS-regions converging to the rest of the EU, while the rest diverge or at best hold their position. Fig Share of between- and within-component of regional inequality, NMS 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% GEb(1) GEw(1) 0% To sum up this section, inequality in the EU is marked by a substantial within-country component. Thus, when considering overall inequality in the EU28, disparities between countries are less important than disparities within. Considering the subsets of EU15 and NMS regions seem to confirm that what is mainly driving the decrease in overall inequality is decreases in between-country inequality. Looking at the EU15 and the NMS, within-country income inequality is either stable or increasing. Thus, the findings seem to confirm that on a country level the EU is characterized by σ-convergence but that this is accompanied by increasing within-country inequality. Considering the results of the analysis of the NMS-set, the increasing overall within-country inequality seems to be mainly due to the behavior of regions in this set. Hence, the results here seem to confirm the findings of Ezcurra et al. (2007b) and Paas and Schlitte (2007, 2008). Though, as discussed by Ezcurra et al. (2006), it is possible that the inter-distributional dynamics differ from the overall distributional dynamics. Then regions would converge to different poles on the income-distribution giving the illusion of decreased overall disparities. Thus, an overall decrease in inequality is accompanied by increased polarization. To further 29

31 investigate if this is the case the analysis now turns to consider the transition and distribution dynamics of regional per-capita incomes over the sample period Transition dynamics Now, the transition dynamics of the entire distribution of per-capita regional incomes is considered. This is done by applying transition tables to the EU28-set, as well as the EU15 and NMS subsets. Below, in table 6.1., a transition table of per-capita GRP relative the EU28-mean between 1995 and 2009 is presented. The table is interpreted as follows. Each range corresponds to a specific category of mean-relative GRP. Ranges are listed both across the row and column of the table, so that each cell corresponds to a pair of ranges. The number in each cell is the (transition) probability that any region starting in the column range in 1995, ends up in the corresponding row range in Since every region ends up somewhere each row sums up to a 100% 13. The number of observations in each range in 1995 is labeled n. For example, looking at table 6.1., below, in regions are confined to the lowest-0.75 range, in % of these remained, while 20% had moved to the range and 3% moved to the range. Thus, the diagonal (marked with bold text) is interpreted as the share of regions that remained within the same range of relative per-capita income as they began with in the beginning of the period. Thus, any cells to the right of the diagonal represent regions that increased per-capita income relative the EU28-mean and cells to the left of the diagonal are regions that decreased in relative per-capita income in Hence, the transition tables show where in the EU28 income distribution a region is located and how regions moved between some discrete ranges. Table 6.1. Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , EU ranges of relative per-capita GRP (%) 1995 ranges n lowest highest lowest % 20% 3% % 69% 15% 2% % 55% 13% 1.25-highest 276-1% 27% 72% Table 6.2. Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , EU ranges of relative per-capita GRP (%) 1995 ranges n lowest highest lowest % 32% 2% % 71% 15% 1% % 65% 11% 1.25-highest 164-1% 22% 77% 13 Note that percentages are rounded to the nearest integer. 30

32 Table 6.3. Transition table of relative per-capita GRP , NMS 2009 ranges of relative per-capita GRP (%) 1995 ranges n lowest highest lowest % 13% 1% % 60% 15% 5% % 33% 33% 30% 1.25-highest % 75% Looking at table 6.1., above, it is clear that the overall dynamics of the regional EU28 per-capita income distribution is rather persistent. A majority of regions that started in a specific range in 1995 also ended up in the same range. Moreover, it is evident that the mobility between ranges is much higher around the EU28-mean than in the two extreme ranges. Thus, the relatively poorest regions and the relatively richest regions tend to remain in their respective range to a larger degree than the mid-range regions. However, there is evidence for some σ-convergence, as about 23% of low-income regions in 1995 moved upwards toward the EU28-mean and 28% of high-income regions moved closer to the mean over the sample period. Thus, the number of regions in the extreme ranges has decreased in This indicates some small degree of falling dispersion in the income distribution. However, this is to counteracted by a small increase in dispersion among the mid-ranges, where 17% and 13% of and ranges, respectively, moved to one of the extreme ranges. Overall, the picture of the per-capita income distribution in the EU28-set is one of persistence, some mobility among mid-range regions and some σ-convergence among the extreme ranges. Thus, so far the findings here confirm the findings above. That is, in this case the reduction in regional inequality is accompanied by distributional convergence. Moving on, table 6.2., above, shows the transition table for the EU15-subset. The restricted sample shows similar dynamics as the EU28-set, a large degree of persistence in ranking and the regions in the mid-ranges being the most mobile. However, one notable characteristic of the EU15-ditribution is the converging low-income regions. Relatively more of the low-income regions seem to be moving toward the mean, reducing disparities. Around 34% of low-income regions in 1995 increased their per-capita incomes and moved to the mid-ranges in This is in line with the finding from the inequality measures of relatively more decreasing inequality among low-income regions. However, this is offset somewhat by a small increase in dispersion in the range. Lastly consider table 6.3. above, which is the transition table for the NMS subset. Notable here is the comparably larger persistence of high- and low-income regions. Moreover, the distribution actually shows signs increasing disparities over the time period. That is to say, more regions are 31

33 found either in the highest or lowest-range in 2009 compared to This would indicate a polarization pattern among regions in the NMS. Also among the mid-ranges a larger share of regions are moving to the extreme ranges compared to the EU15-set. Thus, the NMS-set shows signs of a much more mobility and polarization compared to the EU28- and EU15-sets. This is also in line with the findings of increased regional income inequality between 1995 and 2009 in the NMS-set from the inequality measure, reported above. So far the distributional analysis by means of transition tables have reveled large persistency in the ranking of per-capita regional incomes over time when the entire EU28-set is considered. The same applies to the EU15-set. Both the EU28- and EU15-distribution showed most mobility among mid-range regions and signs of some σ-convergence among the extreme ranges. On the other hand, the NMS-distribution showed more of a polarizing pattern, where more regions are found in the extreme ranges in 2009 compared to This is in line with the findings from the entropy indices reported above and from previous studies on income inequality in the NMS (Ezcurra et al. 2007b; Paas and Schlitte 2007, 2008). That is to say, convergence among the NMS at the country-level is accompanied with increased inequality at the regional level. Thus, while per-capita inequality decreased over the considered time period, within-country disparities have simultaneously increased, seemingly being driven by a polarization of NMS-regions into modes of high and low per-capita incomes Polarization patterns Transition tables can only reveal that much about the distributional dynamics of regional incomes. The table is inherently weak to the choice of ranges and thus runs the risk of missing important dynamics. An alternative and complementary approach is to plot the probability density of the entire distribution by means of kernel density estimation. A kernel estimator is a non-parametric method to estimate a probability density function. By plotting the density functions at the beginning of the time period and comparing this to the distribution at the end of the period the entire distributional dynamics can better be appreciated. A kernel density function can be compared to a smoothed histogram. However, by smoothing the data by means of a kernel function the problem of choosing bins to discretely divide the data into is avoided. Accordingly, to investigate the external shape and the dynamics of regional per-capita income distribution a kernel density estimator is employed to derive the univariate (two-dimensional) probability density function for per-capita GRP for the years 1995 and The results of the density estimations depend crucially on the choice of kernel function (smoothing function) and on the bandwidth selection (smoothing parameter) (Silverman, 1986). In this thesis the estimates are based on the Gaussian kernel function common to the literature (see e.g. Ezcurra 32

34 et al. 2006, 2007a, 2007b; Geppert and Stephan 2008; Chapman and Meliciani 2011) and the bandwidth selection follows the adaptive method suggested by Fox (1990). 14 Below, in fig. 6.7., the estimates of per-capita GRP distribution relative the EU28 mean are shown. As can be observed in the figure the 1995-distribution is characterized by two modes. Besides the main mode at the mean, another mode at the lower-end of the distribution is noticeable. This would indicate that in 1995 low-income regions converged to a lower per-capita GRP level than the rest of the sample. This finding is similar to previous findings that investigated the European regional income distribution around the same time period (see e.g. Ezcurra et al., 2006, 2007a, 2007b). However, what is notable is that the low-income mode is diminished in In fact much more distributional mass is found in the main mode in 2009 compared to 1995, indicating a lessening of income dispersion and thus σ-convergence. This is in line with the findings reported from the inequality measures and transition tables above. However, it is also noteworthy that the mass on the extreme upper part of the distribution has increased in 2009, skewing the distribution left of the mean. This implies that the regions with the absolutely highest per-capita incomes have increased their per-capita GRP relative to the EU28-mean over the sample period. Thus, overall the per-capita income distribution of the EU28-set show signs of some σ-convergence but also by relatively higher per-capita income levels in the extreme upper-end distribution of regions. Turning to the EU15-set, the distribution of the set s per-capita GRP is plotted in fig. 6.8, below. As can be observed in the figure the distributional mass is more concentrated near the main mode in 2009 than in 1995, implying some σ-convergence. Also, generally the EU15-distribution is less disperse than the EU28, indicating less regional income disparities in the subset. Moreover, the distribution shows a similar skewness as the EU28 in 2009 on account of extreme high-income regions. Overall these findings confirm the previous ones reported above of a somewhat persistent income distribution in the subset. Lastly, consider the distribution of per-capita GRP in the NMS-set. The distribution is plotted in fig below. As can be seen the distribution differs markedly from the EU28- and EU15- distributions. Instead of evidence of σ-convergence the distribution shows signs of increasing disparities and thus σ-divergence. A larger mass is found in both tails of the distribution and the kurtosis of the main mode is increased in 2009 compared to This is in line with the evidence found both when considering the inequality measures and the transition table of the NMS-set. Thus, regional incomes in the NMS seem to diverge. Especially the extreme upper-tail has increased relative to the mean 14 For a more detailed description of the specifics of the kernel estimator employed in this thesis see Appendix IV. 33

35 Fig Density function for EU28 relative per-capita GRP 1995 and 2009 GRPpc1995 GRPpc GRP per-capita, EU28=1 Note: Gaussian kernel with adaptive bandwidth Fig Density function for EU15 relative per-capita GRP 1995 and 2009 GRPpc1995 GRPpc GRP per-capita, EU15=1 Note: Gaussian kernel with adaptive bandwidth 34

36 Fig Density function for NMS relative per-capita GRP 1995 and 2009 GRPpc1995 GRPpc GRP per-capita, NMS=1 Note: Gaussian kernel with adaptive bandwidth To summarize the findings in the distributional analysis. Firstly, it can be noted that overall the EU28 is marked by declining regional per-capita income inequality. However, the contribution of within-country disparities to overall inequality has increased over the considered period. Moreover, the decline in inequality is accompanied with a lessening of dispersion in the regional per-capita income distribution, so that the entire EU28-set shows evidence of weak σ- convergence. The EU15-set also shows evidence of declining inequality and distributionaldispersion in per-capita incomes. Also striking about the regional income dynamics in the subset is its persistence over the considered time period. One interpretation of these findings is that the detected convergence is mainly due to income growth among low-income EU15-regions, while high-income regions show a large degree of persistence. Also noteworthy of the EU15 is that inequality in the subset is marked by a considerable within-country component. The dynamics of NMS distribution differ from the EU15 in that it show signs of increasing income inequality and dispersion of regional per-capita GRP over the sample period. Thus, per-capita income in the NMS is more unevenly distributed across regions in 2009 compared to This finding is in line with previous research. Hence, the decline in overall inequality reported in section seems to be mainly driven by σ-convergence in the distribution of EU15-regions. Furthermore, this thesis finds no evidence of the bimodal or a multimodal polarization patterns reported in several previous studies in section 3.2. Instead, a unimodal pole is found in all considered distributions in 2009 and only the thickness of the tails of the distribution differs when 35

37 considering different regional sets. Thus it seems possible that the multimodality of the income distribution has disappeared over time Exploratory spatial data analysis The analysis now turns to consider the spatial dimension of the distribution of regional percapita incomes and growth rates. To do this exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) techniques are used. Following Dall erba (2005: p.126), ESDA is a set of techniques to describe, visualize spatial distributions and to identify patterns of spatial clustering. Following Anselin (1988, 1995), in the subsequent analysis ESDA-techniques to detect spatial dependency over the entire dataset (global spatial autocorrelation) and local clusters of spatial dependence (local spatial autocorrelation) of both regional per-capita GRP and growth rates are employed. Spatial autocorrelation is similar to temporal autocorrelation in that geographical units need not be independent across space. However, while temporal autocorrelation is one-dimensional and one-directional, spatial autocorrelation can be two-dimensional and multi-directional. By measuring the spatial autocorrelation the degree of regional spatial dependence can be estimated. A related topic is that of spatial heterogeneity, meaning that the spatial distribution is uneven and bounded across space, so that local clusters of similar or dissimilar values emerge. Thus, if regions of similar values in initial per-capita GRP or average growth rates are found to be clustered together in space, this is interpreted as support for geographically conditioned convergence-clubs Global spatial autocorrelation Following Dall erba (2005: p.130f.), spatial autocorrelation can be defined as a spatial clustering of similar values of some variable. If similar values are clustered in space there is positive spatial correlation. Conversely, dissimilar clustered values are interpreted as negative spatial autocorrelation. To measure the spatial autocorrelation in the dataset Moran s I statistic is computed (Moran, 1950). This statistic captures global spatial autocorrelation of the variables of interest. Specifically, the Moran s I statistic for region i is given by,, (6.1) where is the ijth-element of the specified spatial-weight matrix 15, is the variable of interest in region i and is the mean of this variable, so that the variable is expressed as mean- 15 The spatial weight matrix is defined in Appendix I. 36

38 deviations. Thus, Moran s I measures the degree of linear dependency between its value at one location and the spatially weighted average of neighboring values. If the value of Moran s I is larger than its expected value the statistic indicates positive spatial correlation. Conversely, a value of Moran s I less than the expected value is interpreted as negative spatial autocorrelation. The null-hypothesis is the absence of spatial autocorrelation and an insignificant statistic implies that geographical location does not matter. Conversely, a significant statistic means that the spatial distribution of some variable is significantly different from the normal distribution and similar (dissimilar) values are clustered in space to larger extent than what randomly can be expected. 16 Below, table 6.4. gives the computed statistics of the Moran s I-test for global spatial autocorrelation for per-capita GRP in 1995 and average growth rates for the period for different critical distance cut-off points. As can be seen the statistic for both per-capita GRP and growth rates is positive and significant at 1%-level for all considered distances except the 100 km cut-off point for growth rates, which is significant at the 5%-level. This indicates that positive global spatial autocorrelation is present in dataset. In other words, regions with similar values of the respective variables tend to be clustered in space. Table 6.4. Moran's I-test for global spatial autocorrelation, EU28 Critical distance cut-off (km) GRPpc, 1995 Growth rates, ** (2.709 ) 0.308* (2.297) ** (3.224) 0.302** (2.600) ** (54.150) 0.520** (40.504) ** (56.158) 0.500** (41.445) ** (56.899) 0.483** (41.604) ** (56.903) ** (41.432) ** (56.486) 0.456** (41.093) ** (55.831) 0.444** (40.637) ** (55.110) 0.433** (40.137) ** (54.342) 0.424** (39.624) Note: ** significant at the 1%-level; * significant at the 5%-level; standardized z-values in parenthesis. The Moran s I-statistic is largest for the distance cut-off of 300 kilometers (before this not all regions in the dataset have neighbors) and decreases afterwards as the cut-off distance 16 The expected value of the Moran s I-statistic is given by. In this case,. Inference is based on the standardized z-value of the statistic, computed as, where is the standard deviation of the Moran s I-statistic. This follows the total randomizing assumption, which means that z follows (asymptotically) a normal distribution. Thus, the z-statisic s significance can be evaluated by means of the standard normal table. 37

39 increases, for both per-capita GRP and growth rates. However, looking at the standardized z- values these are maximized at a cut-off point of 600 and 500 km for per-capita GRP and growth rates, respectively. This indicates that after these distances regional dependence is less relevant in terms of spatial autocorrelation. In the subsequent analysis a spatial-weighting matrix with a distance cut-off point of 600 km will be employed Local spatial autocorrelation The Moran s I-test can detect global spatial autocorrelation, but the statistic can also be used to detect local clusters of spatial dependence. The occurrence of local associations of spatial dependence is commonly referred to as spatial heterogeneity. Following Anselin (1995), to identify and help visualize groups of regions of similar (dissimilar) value a Moran s scatterplot can be employed (Dall erba 2006: p.131f.). By plotting the mean-deviation of observations of some variable for each location (on the horizontal axis) against the spatially-weighted meandeviation of the variable (on the vertical axis) the Moran s I-statistic for each location can be plotted. The linear dependency between each location then corresponds to the global Moran s I- measure of spatial autocorrelation. Accordingly, local spatial autocorrelation corresponds to a particular quadrant in the scatterplot. That is to say, each quadrant corresponds to each form of local spatial association between a location and its neighbors. The quadrants are as follows: - High-high (H-H), regions with above average per-capita incomes surrounded by other regions with above average per-capita incomes. - Low-low (L-L), regions with below average per-capita incomes surrounded by other regions with below average per-capita incomes. - High-low (H-L), above average regions surrounded by regions with below average percapita incomes. - Low-high, below average per-capita income regions surrounded by regions with above average per-capita incomes. The H-H- and L-L-quadrants corresponds to positive spatial autocorrelation and the H-L- and L- H-quadrants corresponds to negative spatial autocorrelation. Of course the same applies to growth rates. The interpretation of the local statistic is similar to the interpretation of the global measure. Fig , below, plots the Moran s scatterplots of per-capita GRP in 1995 and average growth rates for the period, respectively, where. As is clear from looking 17 Even though this includes less significant dependence in growth rates, it is deemed better to include than to exclude, as would be the case if the spatial dependence of GRP was cut short. Moreover, the difference in both the statistic and the z-values between 900 and 800 km is not too large. 38

40 at the figures, a positive global spatial autocorrelation is evident in both plots. That is, most regions are either found in the H-H or the L-L quadrant. This means that most regions with relatively high (low) per-capita GRP are surrounded by other regions with relatively high (low) per-capita GRP. The same goes for growth rates: regions marked with high (low) growth rate are commonly found in the same neighborhood as other region with high (low) growth rate. Thus, two main modes of local clusters of positive spatial autocorrelation can be noted both for percapita GRP and growth rates. This implies spatial heterogeneity in European regional per-capita incomes and growth rates, in turn indicating clustering of both regional incomes and growth. Fig Moran scatterplot per-capita GRP 1995, EU28 39

41 Fig Moran scatterplot growth rates , EU28 Following Anselin (1995), to investigate the geography of the detected spatial heterogeneity the local Moran s I for each region s per-capita GRP in 1995 and average growth rate for the period is computed and the results are plotted on maps, see fig , below. The maps show significant clusters of local Moran s I-statistics at the 5%-level. First, in fig. 6.12, note the positive spatial correlation of high per-capita GRP in the geographical centre of the EU. That is, Austria, Germany, France, Northern Italy, Denmark and partly Great Britain and Sweden all show evidence of clustering of positive spatial autocorrelation of relatively high regional incomes. Conversely, among peripheral regions, the NMS as well as part of Spain, Portugal, Southern Italy and Greece, evidence points to clustering of positive spatial autocorrelation of relatively low values of relative per-capita GRP. Polish regions make up the only larger cluster of negative spatial autocorrelation, showing significant low-high clustering. The interpretation of this is straightforward, Poland, a relative low per-capita income country, is the neighbor of Germany, a relatively high per-capita income country. The divide between a core and periphery in Europe becomes even clearer when considering growth rates. Looking at figure with few exceptions, the regional neighborhoods that exhibited relatively high per-capita incomes in 1995 have exhibited relatively lower average growth rate in subsequent years. Figure is almost the inverse of figure A notable exception is the Netherlands that constitute a relatively high-income cluster that also appears to 40

42 be a spatial cluster of relatively high growth rates. Thus, generally it seems as high-income clusters also exhibit relatively lower growth rates. To summarize this section, ESDA shows that European regional per-capita incomes and growth rates are stricken by considerable spatial autocorrelation. Moreover, spatial heterogeneity of both per-capita GRP and growth rates are found. That is to say, the spatial distributions of these variables are both uneven and bounded into different clusters of similar values. In fact, the spatial distribution of per-capita GRP in the EU shows a striking core-periphery pattern, with a geographical centre with relatively high incomes and a periphery with relatively low. What is more, core regions tend to exhibit relatively slower growth rates than peripheral regions. Thus, only considering the overall spatial structure of per-capita income and growth rates sound evidence for the predictions of neoclassical convergence is found. That is, high-income regions generally grow slower than low-income regions. These findings are in line with what much of the prior work in this area have found (see e.g. Bräuninger and Niebuhr 2005; Ertur et al. 2006; Fischer and Stirböck 2006; Dall erba 2006; Dall erba and Le Gallo 2008; Battisti and Di Vaio 2008). Also note how the NMS seem to fall into the peripheral spatial cluster. The analysis now turns to estimate the speed of this convergence and to investigate some of the influencing factors. 41

43 6.3. Regression results The ESDA, above, revealed spatial autocorrelation in both per-capita GRP and average growth rates across Europe. Thus, as discussed in chapter 3, the assumption of observational independence in OLS-estimations is violated and the spatial dependence must be accounted for in the estimation. To distinguish between nuisance and substantive spatial dependence i.e., if the spatial error or spatial lag model should be estimated the decision rule of Anselin and Florax (1995) is followed. That is, first a β-convergence OLS-regression is estimated. Second, the residuals of this regression are tested for spatial dependence by means of a Moran s I-test. Third, if spatial dependence is found the type of dependence is tested for by means of Lagrange multiplier (LM-) tests. Lastly, depending on which kind of spatial dependence that is found either a spatial error model, as in equation (3.5) (to account for nuisance dependence), or a spatial lag model, as in equation (3.7) (to account for substantive dependence) is estimated. Moreover, to find if country-specific effects or integration -effects are mainly driving the spatial growth clusters found in the EU, estimations adding country-dummies are also performed. This analysis will reveal if countries economic policies, legislation and institutions are more important in creating spatial clusters than cross-border spatial spillovers and geographical neighborhood. One of the aims of the EU is lowering barriers to trade and factor mobility between the member states, which drawing from the theoretical predictions from chapter 2 42

Pushing for growth. Quasi-experimental evidence on the effect of regional transfers in the EU. John Källström. June, NEKP01, Master Thesis II

Pushing for growth. Quasi-experimental evidence on the effect of regional transfers in the EU. John Källström. June, NEKP01, Master Thesis II Pushing for growth Quasi-experimental evidence on the effect of regional transfers in the EU John Källström June, 2014 NEKP01, Master Thesis II Department of Economics, Lund University Supervisor: Joakim

More information

Measurement of the National and Regional Convergence in the EU Defining a More General Convergence Indicator

Measurement of the National and Regional Convergence in the EU Defining a More General Convergence Indicator Measurement of the National and Regional Convergence in the EU Defining a More General Convergence Indicator Krisztián KERTÉSZ Budapest College of Management, Budapest, Hungary kertesz.krisztian@avf.hu

More information

Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy

Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy G. Di Bartolomeo Index, EU-25 = 100 < 30 30-50 50-75 75-100 100-125 >= 125 Canarias (E) Guadeloupe Martinique RÈunion (F) (F) (F) Guyane

More information

Chapter 10: Location effects, economic geography and regional policy

Chapter 10: Location effects, economic geography and regional policy Chapter 10: Location effects, economic geography and regional policy the Community shall aim at reducing disparities between the levels of development of the various regions and the backwardness of the

More information

Regional Convergence and Growth Clusters in Central and Eastern Europe: An Examination of Sectoral-Level Data

Regional Convergence and Growth Clusters in Central and Eastern Europe: An Examination of Sectoral-Level Data Regional Convergence and Growth Clusters in Central and Eastern Europe: An Examination of Sectoral-Level Data Scott W. Hegerty Department of Economics, Northeastern Illinois University 5500 N. Saint Louis

More information

EU Enlargement and Convergence Does Market Access Matter?

EU Enlargement and Convergence Does Market Access Matter? EU Enlargement and Convergence Does Market Access Matter? Annekatrin Niebuhr, Friso Schlitte HWWI Research Paper 1-16 by the HWWI Research Programme Hamburg and Regional Development Hamburg Institute of

More information

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective Prepared within the framework of study Finland in the Global Economy, Prime Minister s Office, Helsinki

More information

REGIONAL INCOME INEQUALITY AND CONVERGENCE PROCESSES IN THE EU-25

REGIONAL INCOME INEQUALITY AND CONVERGENCE PROCESSES IN THE EU-25 REGIONAL INCOME INEQUALITY AND CONVERGENCE PROCESSES IN THE EU-25 Tiiu Paas* and Friso Schlitte** *University of Tartu, Estonia, ** Hamburg Institute of International Economics (HWWA), Germany Emails:

More information

Economic Growth in European City Regions A New Turn for Peripheral Regions in CEE Member States After the EU Enlargements of 2004/2007?

Economic Growth in European City Regions A New Turn for Peripheral Regions in CEE Member States After the EU Enlargements of 2004/2007? Economic Growth in European City Regions A New Turn for Peripheral Regions in CEE Member States After the EU Enlargements of /2007? SCORUS Conference A new urban agenda? Uwe Neumann, Rüdiger Budde, Christoph

More information

Spatial econometric analysis of regional income convergence: The case of North Carolina and Virginia

Spatial econometric analysis of regional income convergence: The case of North Carolina and Virginia Spatial econometric analysis of regional income convergence: The case of North Carolina and Virginia ABSTRACT Zachary Smith Saint Leo University Alan Harper South University The purpose of this study is

More information

EUROPEAN PATTERNS OF UNEMPLOYMENT

EUROPEAN PATTERNS OF UNEMPLOYMENT Lund University Department of Economics Bachelor s Thesis (NEKK01) EUROPEAN PATTERNS OF UNEMPLOYMENT - A Spatial Analysis of Regional Unemployment in Europe - Author: John Källström Supervisor: Joakim

More information

Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product

Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product Vitor João Pereira Domingues Martinho Unidade de I&D do Instituto Politécnico de Viseu Av. Cor. José Maria Vale de Andrade Campus Politécnico 354-51

More information

Detecting Convergence and Divergence Sub-Clubs: An Illustrative Analysis for Greek Regions

Detecting Convergence and Divergence Sub-Clubs: An Illustrative Analysis for Greek Regions The Empirical Economics Letters, 11(8): (August 2012) ISSN 1681 8997 Detecting Convergence and Divergence Sub-Clubs: An Illustrative Analysis for Greek Regions Artelaris Panagiotis * Department of Geography,

More information

The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis

The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis 14 The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis Burcu TÜRKCAN Utku AKSEKİ Abstract The aim of this study is to analyze spatially the main determinants of regional

More information

Institute of Economic Research Working Papers. No. 143/2017. Poland vs Spain in the First Decade After EU Accession. Parallel Convergence Patterns?

Institute of Economic Research Working Papers. No. 143/2017. Poland vs Spain in the First Decade After EU Accession. Parallel Convergence Patterns? Institute of Economic Research Working Papers No. 143/2017 Poland vs Spain in the First Decade After EU Accession. Parallel Convergence Patterns? Piotr Wójcik Article prepared and submitted for: 9 th International

More information

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Chapter 4 Explanation of the Model Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Toshitaka Gokan Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Ikumo Isono Bangkok Research Center, IDE-JETRO,

More information

Regional convergence of unemployment rate in Romania

Regional convergence of unemployment rate in Romania Article history: Received 25.01.2017; last revision 22.03.2017; accepted 01.04 2017 doi: 10.24984/iel.2017.6.2 Regional convergence of unemployment rate in Romania Mihaela Simionescu i Abstract: In this

More information

Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities?

Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities? Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities? Karen Helene Midelfart Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration and CEPR August 31, 2004 First draft Abstract This paper seeks

More information

Geography and Growth: The New Economic Geography (NEG) Perspective

Geography and Growth: The New Economic Geography (NEG) Perspective Geography and Growth: The New Economic Geography (NEG) Perspective Harry Garretsen DIMETIC Summer School, 30-6-2009, Pecs Nice timing for this lecture.. Right after Ron Boschma s lecture: is there life

More information

Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product

Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product Spatial Effects in Convergence of Portuguese Product Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho Instituto Politécnico de Viseu 2011 Working paper nº 79/2011 globadvantage Center of Research in International

More information

International Economic Geography- Introduction

International Economic Geography- Introduction International Economic Geography- Introduction dr hab. Bart Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and Foreign Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw Course structure Introduction LocationtheoryI

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Toward Sustainable Economic Growth: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis of Regional Income Convergence in US BEA Economic Areas

Toward Sustainable Economic Growth: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis of Regional Income Convergence in US BEA Economic Areas Sustainability 2015, 7, 9943-9959; doi:10.3390/su7089943 Article OPEN ACCESS sustainability ISSN 2071-1050 www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability Toward Sustainable Economic Growth: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis

More information

REVIEW ARTICLES AND REPORTS

REVIEW ARTICLES AND REPORTS EUROPEAN SPATIAL RESEARCH AND POLICY 10.2478/s10105-010-0013-5 Volume 17 2010 Number 2 REVIEW ARTICLES AND REPORTS Dimitris KALLIORAS REGIONAL INEQUALITIES IN THE NEW EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER-STATES: IS THERE

More information

ECONOMIC GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND INNOVATION IN THE EU REGIONS 1. Tiiu Paas, Triin Vahi University of Tartu

ECONOMIC GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND INNOVATION IN THE EU REGIONS 1. Tiiu Paas, Triin Vahi University of Tartu Abstract ECONOMIC GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND INNOVATION IN THE EU REGIONS 1 Tiiu Paas, Triin Vahi University of Tartu The paper focuses on quantitative assessment of the innovation s role in explaining regional

More information

European regional convergence revisited The role of intangible assets

European regional convergence revisited The role of intangible assets European regional convergence revisited The role of intangible assets Jesús Peiró-Palomino Department of Economics, University Jaume I (peiroj@uji.es) 9th IRIMA workshop on intangible investment for competitiveness

More information

DOES THE BUSINESS CYCLE MATTER FOR CONVERGENCE TESTING? EVIDENCE FROM U.S. COMMUTING ZONE LEVEL DATA, CHENXI YU THESIS

DOES THE BUSINESS CYCLE MATTER FOR CONVERGENCE TESTING? EVIDENCE FROM U.S. COMMUTING ZONE LEVEL DATA, CHENXI YU THESIS DOES THE BUSINESS CYCLE MATTER FOR CONVERGENCE TESTING? EVIDENCE FROM U.S. COMMUTING ZONE LEVEL DATA, 1973-2007 BY CHENXI YU THESIS Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

More information

Convergence, Spatial Interaction and Agglomeration Effects in the EU

Convergence, Spatial Interaction and Agglomeration Effects in the EU Convergence, Spatial Interaction and Agglomeration Effects in the EU Michael Bräuninger, Annekatrin Niebuhr Abstract We investigate the convergence process among EU regions between 1980-2002 taking into

More information

Interregional R&D spillovers and regional convergence: a spatial econometric evidence from the EU regions

Interregional R&D spillovers and regional convergence: a spatial econometric evidence from the EU regions EQUILIBRIUM Quarterly Journal of Economics and Economic Policy 2017 VOLUME 12 ISSUE 1, March pissn 1689765X, eissn 23533293 www.economicpolicy.pl ORIGINAL PAPER Citation: Furková, A., & Chocholatá, M.

More information

Modeling firms locational choice

Modeling firms locational choice Modeling firms locational choice Giulio Bottazzi DIMETIC School Pécs, 05 July 2010 Agglomeration derive from some form of externality. Drivers of agglomeration can be of two types: pecuniary and non-pecuniary.

More information

Does academic research affect the local growth pattern? Empirical evidence based on Swedish data. Johan Lundberg 1

Does academic research affect the local growth pattern? Empirical evidence based on Swedish data. Johan Lundberg 1 Does academic research affect the local growth pattern? Empirical evidence based on Swedish data Johan Lundberg 1 Department of Economics Umeå University, Sweden Abstract The main issue in this paper is

More information

SPILLOVER DIFFUSION AND REGIONAL CONVERGENCE: A GRAVITY APPROACH

SPILLOVER DIFFUSION AND REGIONAL CONVERGENCE: A GRAVITY APPROACH Giovanni Guastella and FrancescoTimpano, Regional Science Inquiry Journal, Vol. II (2), 2010, pp 71-82 71 SPILLOVER DIFFUSION AND REGIONAL CONVERGENCE: A GRAVITY APPROACH Guastella Giovanni Doctoral School

More information

Knowledge Spillovers, Spatial Dependence, and Regional Economic Growth in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. Up Lim, B.A., M.C.P.

Knowledge Spillovers, Spatial Dependence, and Regional Economic Growth in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. Up Lim, B.A., M.C.P. Knowledge Spillovers, Spatial Dependence, and Regional Economic Growth in U.S. Metropolitan Areas by Up Lim, B.A., M.C.P. DISSERTATION Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of The University

More information

Spatial heterogeneity in economic growth of European regions

Spatial heterogeneity in economic growth of European regions Spatial heterogeneity in economic growth of European regions Paolo Postiglione 1, M.Simona Andreano 2, Roberto Benedetti 3 Draft version (please do not cite) July 4, 2015 Abstract This paper describes

More information

Spatial Dimensions of Growth and Urbanization: Facts, Theories and Polices for Development

Spatial Dimensions of Growth and Urbanization: Facts, Theories and Polices for Development Spatial Dimensions of Growth and Urbanization: Facts, Theories and Polices for Development Sukkoo Kim Washington University in St. Louis and NBER March 2007 Growth and Spatial Inequality Does growth cause

More information

Regional Inequalities in the New European Union Member-States: Is There a Population Size Effect?

Regional Inequalities in the New European Union Member-States: Is There a Population Size Effect? Discussion Paper Series, 16(1): 1-12 Regional Inequalities in the New European Union Member-States: Is There a Population Size Effect? Dimitris Kallioras Economist (M.B.A., PhD), University of Thessaly

More information

Lessons for Regional Policy from the New Economic Geography and the Endogenous Growth Theory

Lessons for Regional Policy from the New Economic Geography and the Endogenous Growth Theory Helmut Karl; Ximena Fernanda Matus Velasco Lessons for Regional Policy from the New Economic Lessons for Regional Policy from the New Economic Contents 1. Introduction 2. New Economic Geography Theory

More information

The new economic geography and regional policy in Romania

The new economic geography and regional policy in Romania Theoretical and Applied Economics Volume XIX (2012), No. 8(573), pp. 5-18 The new economic geography and regional policy in Romania Raluca Irina CLIPA Gh. Zane University, Iaşi raluclipa@yahoo.com Ion

More information

Augmented and unconstrained: revisiting the Regional Knowledge Production Function

Augmented and unconstrained: revisiting the Regional Knowledge Production Function Augmented and unconstrained: revisiting the Regional Knowledge Production Function Sylvie Charlot (GAEL INRA, Grenoble) Riccardo Crescenzi (SERC LSE, London) Antonio Musolesi (University of Ferrara & SEEDS

More information

PUBLIC POLICIES AND ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY. Philippe Martin Université Paris-1 Panthéon Sorbonne, CERAS-ENPC and CEPR September 2002

PUBLIC POLICIES AND ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY. Philippe Martin Université Paris-1 Panthéon Sorbonne, CERAS-ENPC and CEPR September 2002 PUBLIC POLICIES AND ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY Philippe Martin Université Paris-1 Panthéon Sorbonne, CERAS-ENPC and CEPR September 2002 I. Introduction Regional inequalities are an inescapable fact of Europe s

More information

10. Empirical Study of Regional Innovation Capability and Economic Convergence in China

10. Empirical Study of Regional Innovation Capability and Economic Convergence in China 10. Empirical Study of Regional Innovation Capability and Economic Convergence in China Chaofeng Yang, Zhiyun Zhao and Zhijuan Zhang Introduction Given the correlation of economic activities between regions

More information

A Spatial Econometric Approach to Model the Growth of Tourism Flows to China Cities

A Spatial Econometric Approach to Model the Growth of Tourism Flows to China Cities April 15, 2010 AAG 2010 Conference, Washington DC A Spatial Econometric Approach to Model the Growth of Tourism Flows to China Cities Yang Yang University of Florida Kevin. K.F. Wong The Hong Kong Polytechnic

More information

Specialization versus spatial concentration: Which approach better defines the impact of economic integration? The case of the Romania s regions

Specialization versus spatial concentration: Which approach better defines the impact of economic integration? The case of the Romania s regions Specialization versus spatial concentration: Which approach better defines the impact of economic integration? The case of the Romania s regions Ceapraz Lucian, University of Burgundy, France The Strength

More information

Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach. Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli

Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach. Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli Outline Motivation The CEER model Simulation results Final

More information

The Analysis of Sustainability Development of Eastern and South Eastern Europe in the Post Socialist Period

The Analysis of Sustainability Development of Eastern and South Eastern Europe in the Post Socialist Period The Analysis of Sustainability Development of Eastern and South Eastern Europe in the Post Socialist Period Fatih Çelebioğlu Dumlupınar University, Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences, Department

More information

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model General motivation behind the augmented Solow model Empirical analysis suggests that the elasticity of output Y with respect to capital implied by the Solow model (α 0.3) is too low to reconcile the model

More information

Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future. J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium)

Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future. J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium) Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium) Economic geography seeks to explain the riddle of unequal spatial development (at different spatial

More information

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Luc Christiaensen and Ravi Kanbur World Bank Cornell Conference Washington, DC 18 19May, 2016 losure Authorized Public Disclosure

More information

Using Spatial Econometrics to Analyze Local Growth in Sweden

Using Spatial Econometrics to Analyze Local Growth in Sweden Using Spatial Econometrics to Analyze Local Growth in Sweden Johan Lundberg Centre for Regional Science (CERUM), University of Umeå, Sweden April 16, 2004 Abstract This paper investigates factors that

More information

Convergence and spatial interactions: evidence from Russian regions

Convergence and spatial interactions: evidence from Russian regions Convergence and spatial interactions: evidence from Russian regions Vera Ivanova NRU Higher School of Economics Vera Ivanova (NRU HSE) Convergence and spatial interactions September, 24th, 2012 1 / 37

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Cities and Trade: external trade and internal geography in developing economies.*

Cities and Trade: external trade and internal geography in developing economies.* Revised: 31/1/2000 Cities and Trade: external trade and internal geography in developing economies.* Anthony J. Venables London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Policy Research * Background

More information

Kumagai, Satoru, ed New Challenges in New Economic Geography. Chiba: Institute of

Kumagai, Satoru, ed New Challenges in New Economic Geography. Chiba: Institute of Kumagai, Satoru, ed. 2010. New Challenges in New Economic Geography. Chiba: Institute of Developing Economies. INTRODUCTION Satoru KUMAGAI New economic geography (NEG), or spatial economics, is one of

More information

Trade Integration and Industrial Specialization in Central Europe

Trade Integration and Industrial Specialization in Central Europe Trade Integration and Industrial Specialization in Central Europe Crabbé K., Beine M. and Vandenbussche H. Catholic University Leuven August 31, 2005 Abstract In this paper we study the impact of trade

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Total Factor Productivity Growth in Regions

Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Total Factor Productivity Growth in Regions Seminar in International Economics 17 September 2018 Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Total Factor Productivity Growth in Regions Anja Kukuvec Vienna University of Economics and Business (WU) This

More information

Regional convergence and divergence in the enlarged european union: a comparison of different spatial econometric approaches

Regional convergence and divergence in the enlarged european union: a comparison of different spatial econometric approaches Regional convergence and divergence in the enlarged european union: a comparison of different spatial econometric approaches Panagiotis Artelaris Lecturer (under appointment), Harokopio University, Department

More information

Introducing Railway Time in the Balkans

Introducing Railway Time in the Balkans June 23, 2016 Stefan Jestl (wiiw) Economic Effects of Railway Infrastructure June 23, 2016 1 / 19 Introducing Railway Time in the Balkans Economic effects of railway construction in Southeast Europe and

More information

Growth: Facts and Theories

Growth: Facts and Theories Notes on Growth: Facts and Theories Intermediate Macroeconomics Spring 2006 Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania Growth In the last part of the course we are going to study economic growth, i.e. the

More information

Convergence in per-capita GDP across European regions using panel data models extended to spatial autocorrelation effects.

Convergence in per-capita GDP across European regions using panel data models extended to spatial autocorrelation effects. Convergence in per-capita GDP across European regions using panel data models extended to spatial autocorrelation effects. Giuseppe Arbia University G.D Annunzio, Faculty of Economics Viale Pindaro. I-65100

More information

Global activity distribution patterns of top international Chinese contractors Chuan Chen1, a, Hongjiang Li1, b and Igor Martek2, c

Global activity distribution patterns of top international Chinese contractors Chuan Chen1, a, Hongjiang Li1, b and Igor Martek2, c International Conference on Management Science and Innovative Education (MSIE 2015) Global activity distribution patterns of top international Chinese contractors Chuan Chen1, a, Hongjiang Li1, b and Igor

More information

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION ONLINE APPENDIX CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION By ERIC BARTELSMAN, JOHN HALTIWANGER AND STEFANO SCARPETTA This appendix presents a detailed sensitivity

More information

Innovation and Regional Growth in the European Union

Innovation and Regional Growth in the European Union Riccardo Crescenzi Andres Rodriguez-Pose Innovation and Regional Growth in the European Union Springer Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Theoretical Framework: A Spatial Perspective On Innovation and the Genesis

More information

UNIKassel VERSITÄT. Convergence of EU-Regions. A Literature Report. von. Hans-Friedrich Eckey Matthias Türk. Nr. 80/06

UNIKassel VERSITÄT. Convergence of EU-Regions. A Literature Report. von. Hans-Friedrich Eckey Matthias Türk. Nr. 80/06 UNIKassel VERSITÄT Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre Convergence of EU-Regions. A Literature Report von Hans-Friedrich Eckey Matthias Türk Nr. 80/06 Volkswirtschaftliche Diskussionsbeiträge Convergence

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Knowledge Externalities, Agglomeration and Regional Development in the EU: Motivating Place-Based Regional Intervention

Knowledge Externalities, Agglomeration and Regional Development in the EU: Motivating Place-Based Regional Intervention Knowledge Externalities, Agglomeration and Regional Development in the EU: Motivating Place-Based Regional Intervention Gianni Guastella * Universistà Cattolica, Piacenza (IT) Francesco Timpano Università

More information

A Spatial Analysis of the Farm Structural Change: The Case Study of Tuscany Region

A Spatial Analysis of the Farm Structural Change: The Case Study of Tuscany Region A Spatial Analysis of the Farm Structural Change: The Case Study of Tuscany Region Chiara Landi 1, Fabio Bartolini 2, Massimo Rovai 3 1 University of Pisa, chiara.landi@for.unipi.it 2 University of Pisa,

More information

004: Macroeconomic Theory

004: Macroeconomic Theory 004: Macroeconomic Theory Lecture 22 Mausumi Das Lecture Notes, DSE November 11, 2014 Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Macro November 11, 2014 1 / 12 AK Production Technology: First Step Towards Endogenous Growth?

More information

On the Distribution Dynamics of Human Development: Evidence from the Metropolitan Regions of Bolivia

On the Distribution Dynamics of Human Development: Evidence from the Metropolitan Regions of Bolivia MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Distribution Dynamics of Human Development: Evidence from the Metropolitan Regions of Bolivia Carlos Mendez Kyushu University 24 June 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/87571/

More information

Expanded Barro Regression in Studying Convergence Problem

Expanded Barro Regression in Studying Convergence Problem American Journal of Operations Research, 4, 4, 3-3 Published Online September 4 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/ajor http://dx.doi.org/.436/ajor.4.459 Expanded Barro Regression in Studying Convergence

More information

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 Mid-1980s: dissatisfaction with exogenously driven explanations of long-run productivity growth. 2 It led to construction of models in

More information

Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development

Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development Ayele Gelan Socio-economic Research Program, The Macaulay Institute, Aberdeen, UK 003 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/903/

More information

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note Yannis M. Ioannides Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA 02155, USA (O): 1 617 627 3294 (F): 1 617

More information

Do clusters generate greater innovation and growth?

Do clusters generate greater innovation and growth? Do clusters generate greater innovation and growth? Andrés Rodríguez-Pose Department of Geography and Environment London School of Economics and IMDEA, Social Sciences, Madrid IRIS Stavanger, 14 September

More information

EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher

EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher Maria Perrotta April 4, 2013 SITE http://www.hhs.se/site/pages/default.aspx My contact: maria.perrotta@hhs.se Aim of this class There are many different

More information

Exploring the World of Growth and Development

Exploring the World of Growth and Development Exploring the World of Growth and Development Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis January 2018 1 Data source: Acemoglus (2009), Aghion-Howitt (2009), Jones (1998, 2015)

More information

Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics

Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics Chapter 2 - Lessons 1 & 2 Studying Geography, Economics How does geography influence the way people live? Why do people trade? Why do people form governments? Lesson 1 - How Does Geography Influence the

More information

Regional Income Inequality and Convergence Processes in the EU-25

Regional Income Inequality and Convergence Processes in the EU-25 Regional Income Inequality and Convergence Processes in the EU-25 Tiiu Paas, Friso Schlitte HWWI Research Paper 1-11 by the HWWI Research Programme Hamburg and Regional Development Hamburg Institute of

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Regional cooperation: evidence from European cooperative innovation networks

Regional cooperation: evidence from European cooperative innovation networks Regional cooperation: evidence from European cooperative innovation networks Sara Amoroso Alex Coad Nicola Grassano European Commission, JRC, B.3 September 29, 2016 Motivation of the study Regional innovation

More information

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Modern Urban and Regional Economics Modern Urban and Regional Economics SECOND EDITION Philip McCann OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents List of figures List of tables Introduction xii xiv xvii Part I Urban and Regional Economic Models and

More information

Financial Development and Economic Growth in Henan Province Based on Spatial Econometric Model

Financial Development and Economic Growth in Henan Province Based on Spatial Econometric Model International Journal of Contemporary Mathematical Sciences Vol. 12, 2017, no. 5, 209-216 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com https://doi.org/10.12988/ijcms.2017.7727 Financial Development and Economic Growth

More information

The Role of Public Policy in the Process of Regional Convergence

The Role of Public Policy in the Process of Regional Convergence The Role of Public Policy in the Process of Regional Convergence Philippe Martin CERAS-ENPC Paris and CEPR January 2000 Prepared for the Conference on Regional Development Policy and Convergence in the

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

A Bayesian Exploration of Growth and Convergence

A Bayesian Exploration of Growth and Convergence A Bayesian Exploration of Growth and Convergence John S. Landon-Lane and J. Arnold Quinn First Version: April 24, 1996 This Version: March 12, 1999 Abstract The topic of economic growth and convergence

More information

Johns Hopkins University Fall APPLIED ECONOMICS Regional Economics

Johns Hopkins University Fall APPLIED ECONOMICS Regional Economics Johns Hopkins University Fall 2017 Applied Economics Sally Kwak APPLIED ECONOMICS 440.666 Regional Economics In this course, we will develop a coherent framework of theories and models in the field of

More information

Introduction to Regression Analysis. Dr. Devlina Chatterjee 11 th August, 2017

Introduction to Regression Analysis. Dr. Devlina Chatterjee 11 th August, 2017 Introduction to Regression Analysis Dr. Devlina Chatterjee 11 th August, 2017 What is regression analysis? Regression analysis is a statistical technique for studying linear relationships. One dependent

More information

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems Robert Huggins Centre for Economic Geography, School of Planning and Geography, Cardiff University Divergent Cities Conference, University of Cambridge, Cambridge

More information

On beta and sigma convergence of Czech regions

On beta and sigma convergence of Czech regions MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On beta and sigma convergence of Czech regions Jiří Mazurek School of Business Administration in Karvina 1. July 2013 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/47940/

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras Department of Economics ngias@upatras.gr November 10, 2015 Nicholas Giannakopoulos (UPatras) MSc Applied Economics

More information

The spatial convergence of population aging in southern Europe

The spatial convergence of population aging in southern Europe The spatial convergence of population aging in southern Europe Yoann Doignon, Laurence Reboul, Sébastien Oliveau To cite this version: Yoann Doignon, Laurence Reboul, Sébastien Oliveau. The spatial convergence

More information

r10_summary.qxd :19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK

r10_summary.qxd :19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK r10_summary.qxd 2011-08-28 21:19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK The main strategic aim of most concepts of rural development is to improve the quality of life of rural residents through providing appropriate

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 China Shock

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 China Shock PubPol 201 Module 3: International Trade Policy Class 4 China s growth The The ADH analysis Other sources Class 4 Outline Lecture 4: China 2 China s growth The The ADH analysis Other sources Class 4 Outline

More information

Difference in regional productivity and unbalance in regional growth

Difference in regional productivity and unbalance in regional growth Difference in regional productivity and unbalance in regional growth Nino Javakhishvili-Larsen and Jie Zhang - CRT, Denmark, Presentation at 26 th International input-output conference in Brazil Aim of

More information

Deliverable 2.2. Complete report on patterns of economic interaction between the European Union and its neighboring countries

Deliverable 2.2. Complete report on patterns of economic interaction between the European Union and its neighboring countries ABSTRACT DELIVERABLE 2.2 Complete report on patterns of economic interaction between the European Union and its neighboring countries September 2013 ABSTRACT Deliverable 2.2. is a complete report on patterns

More information